SlideShare una empresa de Scribd logo
1 de 25
Descargar para leer sin conexión
Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal
Emerald Article: Value, profit and risk: accounting and the resource-based
view of the firm
Steven Toms



Article information:
To cite this document: Steven Toms, (2010),"Value, profit and risk: accounting and the resource-based view of the firm",
Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, Vol. 23 Iss: 5 pp. 647 - 670
Permanent link to this document:
http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/09513571011054927
Downloaded on: 07-12-2012
References: This document contains references to 102 other documents
Citations: This document has been cited by 3 other documents
To copy this document: permissions@emeraldinsight.com
This document has been downloaded 2401 times since 2010. *




Access to this document was granted through an Emerald subscription provided by UNIVERSITY OF THE ARTS LONDON

For Authors:
If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for Authors service.
Information about how to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines are available for all. Please visit
www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for more information.
About Emerald www.emeraldinsight.com
With over forty years' experience, Emerald Group Publishing is a leading independent publisher of global research with impact in
business, society, public policy and education. In total, Emerald publishes over 275 journals and more than 130 book series, as
well as an extensive range of online products and services. Emerald is both COUNTER 3 and TRANSFER compliant. The organization is
a partner of the Committee on Publication Ethics (COPE) and also works with Portico and the LOCKSS initiative for digital archive
preservation.
                                                                        *Related content and download information correct at time of download.
The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at
                                        www.emeraldinsight.com/0951-3574.htm




                                                                                                                           Value, profit
      Value, profit and risk:                                                                                                   and risk
        accounting and the
  resource-based view of the firm
                                                                                                                                           647
                                        Steven Toms
       The York Management School, University of York, Heslington, UK

Abstract
Purpose – This paper aims to argue that the principal components of the Resource-Based View
(RBV) as a theory of sustained competitive advantage are not a sufficient basis for a complete and
consistent theory of firm behaviour. Two missing elements are value theory and accountability
mechanisms.
Design/methodology/approach – The paper proposes a link between value theory and
accountability using a Resource Value-Resource Risk perspective as an alternative to the Capital
Asset Pricing Model. The link operates first from the labour process, where value is created but is
imperfectly observable by intra-firm mechanisms of organizational control and outside governance
arrangements without incurring monitoring costs. Second, it operates through contractual
arrangements which impose fixed cost structures on activities with variable revenues.
Findings – The paper thereby explains how value originates in risky and difficult to monitor
productive processes and is transmitted as rents to organizational and capital market constituents. It
then reviews recent contributions to the RBV, arguing that the proposed new approach overcomes
gaps inherent in the alternatives, and thus offers a more complete and integrated view of firm
behaviour.
Originality/value – The RBV can become a coherent theory of firm behaviour, if it adopts and can
integrate the labour theory of value, associated measures of risk arising from the labour process and
mechanisms of accountability.
Keywords Resources, Risk management, Labour, Competitive advantage
Paper type Research paper



1. Introduction
To what extent is strategy framed in accounting terms and what role do accounting
numbers and techniques play in setting strategy? In both cases the answer is probably
not enough, in view of the potential contribution on offer from accounting generally,
and from critical accounting in particular. In recent years, the resource-based view
(RBV) of the firm, has achieved widespread dissemination in academic literature and
management practice (Acedo et al., 2006). It explains competitive advantage, or
delivery of sustained above-normal returns (Peteraf, 1993) or economic profit (Barney,
2001), in terms of firms’ bundles of resources (Amit and Schoemaker, 1993; Rumelt,
1984), which are valuable, rare, inimitable and non-substitutable (VRIN) (Barney, 2001,
emphasis added). A theory linking asset value and abnormal returns is therefore
                                                                                                                             Accounting, Auditing &
                                                                                                                               Accountability Journal
The author would like to thank participants at the European Critical Accounting Studies                                           Vol. 23 No. 5, 2010
Conference, University of York, 2006 and the Institute of Chartered Accountants in Scotland,                                              pp. 647-670
                                                                                                                  q Emerald Group Publishing Limited
whose financial support helped develop the ideas in this paper. He would also like to thank Chris                                           0951-3574
Carter and two anonymous reviewers for their very helpful comments.                                                  DOI 10.1108/09513571011054927
AAAJ   required. Because the RBV literature has placed these issues at the centre of its agenda,
23,5   its neglect of the accounting literature all the more surprising.
           If the strategy literature has neglected accounting, it is also fair to say that
       accounting has neglected strategy. Where concerned with valuation, accountants often
       employ theoretical stances at variance with the Neo-classical mainstream strategy
       literature (Bryer, 1994, 1999; Macve, 1999; Mouck, 1994; Tinker, 1980, 2004; Toms,
648    2006a, 2009; Toms and Bowman, 2010)[1]. A common approach of critical accounting is
       to begin with the restrictive assumptions of marginalist Neo-classical economics and
       argue that they possess logical inconsistencies, for example the tautological approach
       to asset valuation implied by the Cambridge controversies (Tinker, 1980), privilege
       interest groups (Tinker et al. 1982), or are not useful because the total social product is
       either not recognised (Mayston, 1992) or ignored (Milne, 1991), and neglect the social
       “essence” beneath the surface of market relationships (Tinker, 1984, p. 61, 1980, p. 158).
       As a consequence, much of the critical accounting literature has abandoned economic
       discourse, including the Classical and Marxian Schools. With limited exceptions,
       deductive model building has become unfashionable, even though, as will be
       demonstrated below, it has the potential to overcome some weaknesses of the
       Neo-classical School and its accounting applications. As a consequence, there are
       unresolved questions in accounting and strategy. First, what is the nature of value, and
       a theoretically consistent measure of sustained competitive advantage (SCA)? Second,
       can an operationalisable theory of risk be developed for the purposes of managerial
       decision making?
           In addressing these questions the paper will advance an agenda for strategy, and
       accounting. It will address them by developing an integrated theory of value, profit,
       and risk. In section two the relevant literature is reviewed under three headings. First,
       the salient features of the RBV are analysed. Second classical theories of value are
       considered. Finally, the accounting literature is discussed, insofar as it reflects the
       former two aspects. Section three develops a new conceptual framework, linking profit,
       value and risk as a basis for a theory of SCA. It will be shown how the labour theory of
       value (LTV) can be extended to include risk and be used to modify the neo-classical
       capital asset pricing model (CAPM). It will do so by linking both to the underlying
       labour process. It will demonstrate how profit and asset value can be consistently
       linked by cost structures. It will show how value creation of value can be differentiated
       from the rent. In the fourth section, the implications are discussed, first for accounting
       theory, with particular reference to the Cambridge controversies, and second by
       comparison with similar approaches in the strategy literature. A final section draws
       conclusions.

       2. Strategy, value theory and accounting
       Strategy and the RBV as a theory of value
       The RBV is an important idea in strategy, because it offers the potential to explain
       SCA, or the process of delivering long run abnormal returns to shareholders. Such
       returns can be delivered through accessing resources, including for example by
       monopoly control, as in the theory of competitive heterogeneity, or the creation of
       difficult to replicate resources as in the RBV. It follows that the RBV needs a theory of
       value to be a convincing theory of SCA. As Priem (2001) therefore suggests, the RBV is
       incomplete because its explanation of value must be imported from outside literatures.
Further, as Priem and Butler (2001) propose, the RBV is tautological if the firm’s         Value, profit
possession of unique capabilities cannot be ascertained independently of their                    and risk
description (Carter et al., 2008). Accounting might break the tautology by providing
mechanisms for understanding resource creation, their valuation and reporting. It
therefore follows that the measurement of resource value and abnormal returns are
necessary components of the development of the RBV as a theory[2].
    Of course, this conclusion has not been fully accepted in the strategy literature,               649
which reflects more general disagreement about the RBV’s basic premises (Hoopes
et al., 2003). Indeed, participants in the debate have yet to reach a consensus on the
circumstances of where, why and when a resource is valuable (Miller and Shamsie,
1996, p. 539). Where recent strategy literature does acknowledge the requirement for a
theory of value, it has adopted two quite narrow and largely mutually exclusive
perspectives. One strand examines processes within the organization (Denrell et al.,
2003), which might be conceptualized in terms of production, transaction and
governance costs (Madhok, 2002). Another considers value, price and cost as market
interactions (Hoopes et al., 2003), and the market based division of value through
bargaining games (Lippman and Rumelt, 2003a, 2003b; MacDonald and Ryall, 2004;
see also Brandenburger and Stuart, 1996).
    In contrast with economic theory, which explains performance differentials in terms
of product and market structure, the RBV focuses on the internal characteristics of the
firm (Lockett and Thompson, 2001). However, the valuation of RBV assets also implies
relationships with a specific market environment (Amit and Schoemaker, 1993).
Similarly Barney (1991, p. 105) suggests that a resource is valuable to the extent that “it
exploits opportunities and/or neutralizes threats in a firm’s environment”. A connected
argument is that resources are valuable if they enable a firm to satisfy needs at lower
costs than competitors (Peteraf, 1993). Barney (1991, p. 106) also suggests that
resources are valuable “when they enable a firm to conceive of or implement strategies
that improve its efficiency and effectiveness”. A resource has been defined as valuable
if it enables customer needs to be better satisfied (Bogner and Thomas, 1994; Verdin
and Williamson, 1994).
    How the superior returns that arise from these activities are captured by specific
stakeholder groups through accountability processes has not been resolved in the
strategy literature. Coff (1999) addresses the question with the notion of “nexus rents”,
so that proceeds of superior performance are appropriated by competing stakeholder
groups. Although explaining their distribution, rents, and one assumes value, are
determined by market processes and do not arise from the productive process,
although Coff’s contribution importantly highlights the role of monitoring
relationships. Where the stakeholder approach is used, definitions of value are still
predicated on notions of utility. For example Collis and Montgomery (1997, pp. 30-1)
argue that a resource is valuable when demanded by customers, when it cannot be
replicated by competition, and when the profits it generates are captured by the firm
(emphasis added). The implied reification does not sit comfortably with a stakeholder
approach. However, the principal weakness here is that value depends upon defining
customer needs (including, tautologically, access to low priced goods) in utilitarian
terms. There is also the more fundamental question of whether utility in any case
constitutes the basis for a theory of value. It has been dismissed as a tautology by some
prominent economists (Robinson, 1963), and more importantly refuted as a theory of
AAAJ   capital value and the rate of profit (Harcourt, 1969). Neo-classical economics has
23,5   ignored rather than responded to these fundamental criticisms (Tinker, 1980), and any
       attempt to develop a resource based theory of the firm on neo-classical foundations
       necessarily faces the same problem, not least because capital values and profit rates are
       central to the RBV approach. To summarize these problems, the RBV requires a value
       theory independent of utility, or must specify a stakeholder group whose utility is to
650    take precedence.
          Strategic management researchers meanwhile are also interested in developing new
       risk measures that are theoretically consistent and useful for managerial decision
       making, achieving a suitable trade-off between concept complexity and computational
       simplicity (Ruefli et al., 1999, pp. 182-4). So far, this literature has relied on the CAPM,
       but has merely added to the critique in the finance literature. Bowman (1979) and
       Armour and Teece (1978) examined the implied CAPM relationship, finding a
       paradoxical negative slope between risk and return. Feigenbaum and Thomas (1986)
       and Singh (1986) find differing risk return relationships at different levels of
       organizational performance and capacity utilisation. These studies typically reflect
       Neo-classical approaches to modelling risky behaviour, so that they are potentially
       undermined by the weaknesses of the CAPM highlighted by financial researchers
       (Clare et al., 1998, Fama and French, 1992, Wang, 2000), and although address expected
       return, do not offer a theory of value.
          Summarizing much of the above, Priem (2001) argues that existing theories deal
       only with the value capture element but do not explain how value is created. For
       Makadok and Coff (2002) RBV works with value capture, but does not need a theory of
       value creation, especially not a theory based on consumer utility. Bowman and
       Ambrosini (2000) suggest conventional explanations of resource value (Makadok,
       2001; Makadok and Coff, 2002; Barney, 1986; Peteraf, 1993; Collis and Montgomery,
       1995) are insufficient and set out a framework incorporating value creation and value
       capture. These critics have built on Classical economists’ notion of use value, so that
       new use value derives from individuals’ actions within the organization (Bowman and
       Ambrosini, 2000; Bowman and Swart, 2007; Lado and Wilson, 1994; Pfeffer, 1995;
       Wright et al., 1994). These approaches potentially form the most useful starting point
       for the more formal integration of the LTV and theories of SCA.

       Classical value theory
       In the classical LTV, human action within the productive process is the source of value.
       Because commodities are systematically sold at higher prices on leaving the productive
       process in comparison to the prices at which they enter it, there must be some
       commodity within the process that adds value systematically. Without this condition
       aggregate profits are zero and the economy is a zero sum game. Further, labour time is
       priced in the market, but labour time is transferred to the product with a degree of
       intensity that is a function of physical effort and mental processes, which are not
       directly observable. Socially necessary labour time is that required to produce any use
       value under normal conditions of production with the average degree of skill and
       intensity prevalent in that society (Marx, 1984, p. 641).
           As far the RBV is concerned, it is not a theory of value, but a theory of rent. These
       rents are Ricardian (Peteraf, 1993, Teece et al., 1997, p. 513), since Schumpeterian rents
       (Foss and Knudsen, 2002), as synergies, or economies of scope are imitable, except in
the short run (Barney and Peteraf, 2003)[3]. However, none of the RBV literature has          Value, profit
seriously concerned itself with the nineteenth century literature on rent and associated          and risk
value theory. Marx modified Ricardo by varying the assumption of a fixed resource
supply, and allowing rents to arise as a function of different deployments of capital. He
also explained the proportion of profit manifested as rent as a function of the
regulating price, as determined socially necessary labour. Rent therefore is regulated
by the most efficient (or least efficient) combination of resources and their production               651
cost, depending on prevailing conditions of competition and the order in which
resources are brought into use. In other words, Marx’s theory of rent developed
Ricardo’s theory in directions of potential use to RBV theorists and accountants
concerned with asset valuation and rents. Whether useful or not, Marx’s theory of rent
is unlikely to be popular with RBV theorists or mainstream accountants.
    The same might be said for the LTV, although it is just as easily attributable to
Ricardo or Smith, or to classical economy in general. As Grant (1996, p. 112) puts it, “a
physiocratic approach”[4], locating value in a single production factor, is essential for a
knowledge-based theory of value. Bowman and Toms (2010) introduce the notions of
value and surplus value along with the distinctions between use value and exchange
value that have already contributed to the RBV conversation (Bowman and Ambrosini,
2000). Following the above definition of socially necessary labour, firms will vary in
efficiency and therefore through bankruptcy and innovation, socially necessary labour
is reduced to the most efficient firm (Mohun, 1996, p. 504). For these reasons Marx is
more specifically useful for the RBV as the notion of socially necessary labour
facilitates the determination of rent elements in abnormal profits. Even so, Marx is only
a point of departure for the further development of RBV discussed in section 3.

Accounting and the RBV
There has been limited research on the RBV in the accounting literature. Studies have
typically concentrated on testing managerial accounting applications. For example
Howorth and Westhead (2003) find that working capital management techniques differ
according to the scale and sophistication of the resource base in small firms. In another
study, managerial selection of performance measures mediates the relationship
between strategic RBV assets and financial performance in non-manufacturing firms
(Widener, 2006). Other research has examined the relationship between the
management control system (MCS), the creation of capabilities in an RBV sense and
performance (Henri, 2006). In general research of this kind has been limited, possibly
because as Barney et al. (2001) suggest, the MCS is not a VRIN asset due to its easy
transferability[5]. In general, where undertaken by mainstream accounting
researchers, RBV research has focused on accounting practice rather than
accounting theory.
   In contrast, critical accounting research has been more directly concerned with these
fundamentals. Toms (2002), Hasseldine et al. (2005) develop an integrated framework
for RBV intangible asset investment and stock market signalling. Bryer (1999) argues
that labour values are the basis of objective asset valuations. Tinker(1999, p. 655) on
the other hand suggests that Marx’s economic categories such as profit, wages and
rents should be seen as socially relative phenomena. For Abeysekera(2008) accounting
measurement is a response to commodification, or the economic logic of maximising
the market value of a firm while dealing with the contradiction of use of labour for
AAAJ   production by the firm. Another strand of critical literature has begun to address the
23,5   relationship between accounting profit, valuation and the competitive process by
       integrating the propositions of the RBV. Toms (2006b) integrates a knowledge based
       view of the firm with theories of entrepreneurship, and extends the CAPM to integrate
       social conceptions of risk (Toms, 2006a). He extends these arguments to show the
       possible objective valuation measures that might be computed if social and financial
652    risk are appropriately integrated (Toms, 2008, 2009). Bowman and Toms (2010) show
       how the RBV can be integrated with Marx’s model of the circuits of capital
       incorporating different classes of labour. These ideas are now extended further to
       produce a conceptual framework based on a common theory of accounting and
       competitive advantage.

       3. Conceptual framework
       Theoretical dimensions
       A theory of accounting and strategy is presented below, linking value theory and
       accountability, using what for shorthand will be referred to as the Resource
       Value-Resource Risk (RVRR) perspective. Value, in terms of labour effort transferred to
       the product, is best observable in the labour process by those most closely involved
       and the value capture process accordingly becomes progressively less observable (with
       increased monitoring cost) by those concerned with superintendence of valorization, or
       realization of use value into monetary value, and surplus appropriation. RVRR is thus
       concerned with accountability mechanisms, consisting of accounting controls and
       governance arrangements.
           There are several additional and important dimensions. First, is the firm’s cost
       structure, which refers to the degree of cost variability arising from the employment
       contract. If employee remuneration is not precisely linked to revenue, the expected (risk
       adjusted) rate of profit includes a rent element. Either revenue will fall and staff costs
       are paid anyway, in which case there is a “rent” accruing to the workforce (because
       they have produced less but are paid the same), or revenue will rise and staff costs
       remain fixed, in which case profit rises above normal as labour’s share in net output
       falls.
           Second, if the actions of people within organisations are the source of use values, it
       is necessary to define such values according to some Minimum Efficient Labour
       Requirement (MELR), otherwise any additional labour time, no matter how inefficient
       and regardless of consumer requirement could still be said to create value[6]. MELR
       specifically refers to the labour costs of the firm with the simplest processes and most
       easily replicable assets consistent with remaining in the market. It therefore regulates
       the market price and differential rents are set for other firms with less easily replicable
       assets according to the benchmark, as is analogous to the illustrations used by Marx
       (1984, chapters 39 [e.g. table 1], 40). The benchmark MELR firm establishes the
       underlying expected normal rate of return to shareholders and the discount rate
       applied in asset valuation. These relationships are developed further below to show
       that such returns are systematically related to cost structures embedded in the labour
       process.
           Third, there is the possibility of “rent” transfer between stakeholder groups. Rent is
       defined as above, but extended to include circumstances where knowledge is unevenly
       distributed within firms and between firms and their investors, so that rents accrue to
firm insiders or financial market insiders based on access to superior information. By          Value, profit
extension, where knowledge is unevenly distributed within firms and between firms                   and risk
and their investors, rents accrue to firm insiders or financial market insiders based on
access to superior information. Because firm insiders are employees and managers,
their realized wage is the MELR rate for the job plus or minus rent elements arising
from access to information asymmetries in the production process and contract related
cost structures. Conversely, realized returns accruing to shareholders in a financial                 653
market reflect both the underlying rate of profit plus or minus realizable managerial
and labour rents[7]. Unlike Ricardian rents in the standard RBV, these rents arise from
labour processes within organisations and markets that are set in process by capital,
and are accordingly consistent with Marx’s second category of differential rent, in
which realized rent depends on differential employments of capital.
   The fourth component is tacit knowledge. Employees hold their positions because
the perceived value of their tacit and other knowledge exceeds their market cost[8].
To develop a theory of SCA from a RVRR perspective, it is necessary to establish a
basic relationship between individual knowledge, the means whereby it is embedded
in the labour process, and subsequent monitoring and valorization. Physical effort
and readily quantifiable skills are resources most easily replicable. Such explicit skills
are those more easily generated through generic training and education processes
external to the firm. As labour processes become more deeply ingrained as tacit
skills, they become more difficult to replicate. As the firm invests in assets such as
specialized production facilities, trade secrets and engineering experience (Teece et al.
1997) over time (Dierickx and Cool, 1989), tacit knowledge is embedded in technically
complex routines[9]. According to the knowledge-based view SCA arises from such
routines (Spender, 1989, Nonaka, 1991), but recognition that individuals create the
knowledge, which firms can then apply (Grant, 1996) leads in the RVRR to tension
between rent appropriation by individuals and team-based profit appropriation as
SCA. RVRR places appropriate emphasis on the mental processes, so that senior
managers as well as junior staff spend time creating value, specifically where their
administrative activities are a necessary condition for productive activity to occur[10].
Productive activity is activity that adds value including service provision, not just
factory production. The supervision problem intensifies to the extent that
subordinates hold tacit knowledge. Tacit knowledge reflects value in use rather
than market exchange value and employees hold their positions precisely because the
perceived value of their tacit and other knowledge exceeds their market cost. In RBV
terms, the firm that employs such individuals has a basis for SCA because a
competing firm cannot replicate the asset base through straightforward market
exchange processes.
   Therefore a fifth component is that, as the labour process is not directly observable,
the employer of labour and the capital market investor are exposed to financial risk
arising from information asymmetry. Such problems lead to the sixth and final
component, which is the process of organizational control and the mix between
behaviour and output controls (Ouchi and Maguire, 1975) or action and results controls
(Bryer, 2006). The balance shifts from the former to the latter, to the extent that process
observation by supervisors is problematic, where accounting controls receive more
emphasis in the latter case. Each of these components is integrated in the following
framework.
AAAJ                          An integrated model
23,5                          Figure 1 uses the Ambrosini and Bowman (2001, p. 816) continuum to include tacit
                              knowledge as a starting point, but extends their analysis to include the additional
                              dimension of task complexity in the labour process, and cost behaviour, monitoring
                              costs, control mechanisms and appropriation in the valorization process. In other words,
                              to consider the relationship between knowledge location and value appropriation as part
654                           of a full description of the productive process, set out in Figure 1 as a horizontal
                              continuum of dimensions of value creation through to ultimate value capture.
                                  The valorization process comprises four elements: cost behaviour, control,
                              monitoring, and appropriation. Insofar as specific assets associated with SCA are
                              not valued in an external market, and are therefore illiquid and non-realizable, they
                              generate fixed costs rather than variable costs. Similarly hiring knowledge intensive
                              labour generates fixed cost. Therefore as tacit knowledge and the potential degree of
                              SCA rises under RBV assumptions, so does the fixity of cost. As suggested in Figure 1,
                              there is also a continuous relationship between the degree of tacitness and complexity
                              in the labour process and the ability of external stakeholders to monitor the separable
                              labour processes that make up the firm and their joint interactions. This follows from
                              the definition of tacit knowledge, because the process is less readily explainable and
                              understood by an outsider and, consistent with the RBV, tacit knowledge is implicated
                              in SCA. External stakeholders’ two methods of monitoring, behavioural (or action)
                              control and output control, are also implicated in the tacitness and complexity of the
                              labour process, and the extent of fixed production costs and monitoring costs in the
                              valorization process. Tasks that are simple to perform and replicate are more easily




Figure 1.
The production process,
knowledge location and
the distribution of surplus
controlled through the division of labour and repetition, and more easily flexed in             Value, profit
response to changes in demand, so there is greater emphasis on action control. Where               and risk
the process is complex, difficult to observe and dependent on embedded fixed costs,
rather than costly monitoring a process that is difficult to understand and
unresponsive to changes in demand, output control might be relied upon, so that the
producer has to account for actions in financial terms. In the latter case, there is an
additional element in the labour process, involving transformation of heterogeneous                   655
physical and mental inputs into homogeneous monetary outputs. Following Ouchi and
Maguire (1975), behaviour and output controls may not be direct substitutes, but may
be observable in independent contexts depending on understanding of means-ends
relationships and complex interdependencies respectively. Finally, as far as
appropriation is concerned, the more tacit labour processes create assets that are
unique and valuable, through processes that generate difficult to monitor fixed costs,
the more likely resulting abnormal profit will be appropriated by insiders. Inside
appropriation is at the expense of external capital providers or of other participants in
joint ventures and consortia.
   Several corollaries arise from these relationships. First is the conflict between the
managerial objective of achieving SCA and the objective of maximizing shareholder
value. Managers pursue rents rather than optimal growth (Rugman and Verbeke, 2004)
and these rents arise from their role in the labour process, as supervisors and
participants. If firms are identified as achieving competitive advantage by reference to
accounting ratios showing superior performance from a shareholder perspective (e.g.
Peters and Waterman, 1982), such performance is likely based on explicit and easily
replicable skills and that associated competitive advantage is short-term or illusory.
   A second and related point is that monitoring costs in Figure 1 also lie on a
continuum suggesting that as the degree of tacitness rises, the probability of surplus
appropriation by those closest to the labour process also rises. In other words the
monitoring problem is not simply confined to the providers of external capital but is
also faced directly by the line managers at each hierarchical level above the labour
process. Line managers have the incentive to externalize tacit knowledge embedded in
labour processes for which they are responsible, for example through the division of
labour, or spend organizational resources themselves on monitoring, so that rents
accrue at their level of the hierarchy[11]. Insofar as line management itself is part of the
labour process, for example where managerial action alters the product or service
delivered, further individually appropriable tacit knowledge arises and monitoring
costs are imposed from above on progressively senior levels of management.
Ultimately the imposition comes from the capital market to the top of the hierarchy,
creating a similar but separate set of monitoring issues discussed below.
   A third corollary is that under RVRR assumptions the RBV is made consistent with
labour process theory (LPT)[12]. Many labour process theorists (e.g. Knights, 1990,
Wilmott, 1990) stress the role of power rather than profit and, where applied to the RBV,
the role of power in appropriation (Scarborough, 1998). As Nicholls (1999) has pointed
out, the valorization stage of the productive process, concerned with transformation of
labour use values into realized profit, has been neglected in the labour process literature.
Figure 1 suggests an integrated approach, since labour rent originates in the productive
process, and a valorization stage is included. In terms of labour time, capital comprises
accumulated prior use values plus the labour time, at whatever intensity, transferred
AAAJ   into output through the labour process. Capital can be conceptualized in labour hours
23,5   without reference to valorization, but the valorization process is nonetheless the crucial
       link underpinning the relationship between tacit knowledge and monitoring costs.
       Valorization, under RVRR assumptions, depends on the effectiveness or otherwise of
       supervisory arrangements to moderate the effects of information asymmetry.
       Asymmetry arises because employees sell but usually retain some control over the
656    employment of their labour effort, which supervision arrangements are intended to
       counteract in order to achieve fuller valorization. Therefore the labour process leads to
       inventiveness on the one hand through the imagination of individual employees and
       alienation through the process of specialization on the other. In the RVRR extension, to
       the extent that inventiveness and knowledge can be individually appropriated by
       employees, the labour process itself becomes a risky set of activities for administering
       managers and outside financial stakeholders.
           Arising from these risks, a fourth corollary is their price impact capital markets. If
       SCA is measured in terms of shareholder returns, then realization through circulation in
       capital markets is part of the valorization process. At the top end of the continuum where
       all knowledge is tacit, it is impossible for the investor to understand the processes
       whereby use values are transformed into exchange values through realization and
       thereby generated into profits. Even so, where there is some degree of capital
       dependence (Prechel, 2000), for example in high growth sector firms, insiders will have
       an incentive to reserve some profit and signal its availability to outside investors instead
       of appropriating it for themselves. Insofar as the labour process within one firm is
       unrelated to labour processes governing the average firm’s realization of profits, which
       include many explicit processes, its variation in profit will appear random. Because the
       capital market by definition can only value explicit processes, that firm’s apparently
       random changes in profit corresponds to the firm-specific risk from an investor’s point of
       view[13]. In the limiting case where all knowledge is tacit, all share prices become
       random. Under such conditions, following Grossman and Stiglitz (1980), share prices
       would convey no information to investors. In the opposite case where all knowledge is
       explicit, information is symmetrical and markets become thin, as there are no abnormal
       returns (rents) and no incentive to trade (Grossman and Stiglitz, 1980). Also under these
       conditions with RBV assumptions all firms possess the same easily imitable resources
       for the same activities and there is no SCA.
           These intra-firm and firm-financial market interactions provide the possibility of
       theory of profit determination consistent with notions of SCA and the RVRR.
       Abstracting from the continua in Figure 1, a model showing the relationship between the
       labour cost characteristics of tacit knowledge, task complexity, valorization process
       characteristics, and expected profits required by external investors can be developed.
       Figure 2 shows the rate of return required by a risk-averse external investor as a function
       of the fixed cost labour ratio (FCLR). The FCLR is the proportion of fixed cost to total cost
       for firm i divided by the proportion of fixed cost to total cost for all firms.
           Some abstraction will assist interpretation of Figure 2. Suppose a firm with a single
       employee, w, and a single shareholder, s, and that the actions of w can be made totally
       observable or explicit to s through contractual/legal arrangements so w has no
       bargaining power. Suppose also that s pays w only for the output actually produced (as
       opposed to for the time w spends at work). Under these assumptions[14], s is able to
       appropriate profits from the labour process under risk free conditions. If fairly efficient
Value, profit
                                                                                                   and risk


                                                                                                       657




                                                                                                    Figure 2.


capital markets are also assumed, and other markets are perfect, the expected rate of
profit should resemble the rate of return from risk free investment (point A in Figure 2),
for example base interest rates[15]. It can also be seen that if these assumptions are
gradually relaxed, so that w is able, through the acquisition of bargaining power, to fix
wages in the face of varying demand conditions, then the rate of profit required to
compensate the investor will rise. Because rate of profit variability increases
proportionately to the degree of fixity in wage cost, even where diversified, investors
require, and should obtain where capital markets remain reasonably efficient, a
proportionate increase in compensation (for the average risk firm, to point B in
Figure 2). There is a systematic increase insofar as under conditions of aggregate
growth expected change in aggregate demand is positive in which case because wages
are fixed, the rate of realized profit rises.
   An important reason for the positive linear association between fixity of labour cost
and shareholder risk is implicit contract theory, in which employees are risk averse
(Rosen, 1985). In this model, the capital market absorbs the insurance element of implicit
labour contracts through a risk premium. Figure 2 is theoretically consistent with the
Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965) CAPM, in that stock return is proportionate to
systematic risk. The difference is that the risk source is related to value creation, labour
process and value appropriation, rather than mere share price and stock market index
co-variation.
AAAJ       Suppose next that w has tacit knowledge and can conceal value-creating or
23,5   value-destroying activities in the labour process, so that the effort bargain shifts in
       favour of w and the return to s corresponds to point C in Figure 2. Again, s faces
       increased risk, but the increase is specific to the labour process and s avoids this risk
       by incurring monitoring costs or shifting to output control, for example setting a target
       normal rate of profit based on observable rates elsewhere. These rates reflect, and are
658    reduced by, aggregate monitoring cost. Alternatively, s avoids risk through portfolio
       diversification, but in doing so reduces capacity further for monitoring performance of
       any one firm. Purchasers of other shares also run the risk of negative rents through
       premium prices charged by market makers, benefiting from inside or asymmetric
       information advantages (point D in Figure 2). In general, points C and D constitute
       examples of rents arising from non RBV sources, such as monopoly power, information
       asymmetry and other elements of competitive heterogeneity.
           The interactions between tacit knowledge and monitoring costs are suggestive of
       some interesting contradictions within the corporate economy. Alienation, through
       excessive specialization and associated removal of intellectual content, is traditionally
       viewed as a source of exploitation by unscrupulous profit maximizers. That said, in
       industries where such exploitation might occur, such as cotton textiles in the British
       industrial revolution or in modern China, although aggregate profit rates may be high,
       there is no basis for SCA at the level of any individual firm[16]. In contrast, where the
       labour process has significant intellectual content, thereby creating entry barriers for
       competitors, the accrued profit to individual profit maximizers may be still small and the
       rents accrued by intermediate producers and market-makers large, due to increased
       monitoring problems[17]. In short, because rent is the difference between realized price
       and underlying value, if labour is the source of value, information asymmetry is the source
       of rent. Interaction between the two tends to equalize the aggregate rate of profit[18].
           Figure 3(a) shows a formal decomposition of total observed profits into profit and
       rent elements. Following Figure 2, there is a risk free profit element, to which is added a
       labour rent based systematic premium equating to the FLCR. Further rents arise from
       knowledge-based asymmetries within the production process and as a residual
       category, from other non-labour based resources. Consistent with the economic theory
       advanced so far, total observed profit consists of normal profit plus rents. Normal
       profit, following Figure 2, corresponds to average levels of fixed labour cost,
       corresponding to point A in Figure 3(a). A firm operating here would be the regulator
       of market price and the benchmark for differential rents arising at points B and C. To
       the extent that the individual firm has an above average FLCR, it earns systematically
       higher rent, which forms the first component of RVRR-based abnormal return. The
       second component arises from knowledge-based production process asymmetries. SCA
       associated with the RVRR, consistent with the RBV, is the distance B – A. Further
       rents, accrued through heterogeneous access to other physical and informational assets
       (C – B), are not part of an RBV story of SCA, but are consistent with competitive
       heterogeneity and Ricardian rents. Where such rents are present, they will complement
       other categories of rent, thereby increasing total observed profit, or will increase profit
       in the absence of other categories. For the purposes of simplicity expected and realized
       profit are part of the same total observed surplus in Figure 3(a).
           In practice, expected and realized profits are in contradiction. Figure 3(b) shows how
       these interactions, including the consumption of rent by internal stakeholders, explain
Value, profit
          and risk


                  659




               Figure 3.
     The determinants of
    sustained competitive
advantage and observable
                  profits
AAAJ   the observed level of profit and when and how observed abnormal profits are
23,5   associated with SCA. Figure 3(b) shows the general case, in which profits and SCA are
       explained jointly by tacit knowledge VRIN assets in the resource base and the process
       of surplus appropriation. The framework shows the labour and valorization processes
       to be in direct and dynamic contradiction. In the top row of the table, consistent with
       the RBV, firms achieve SCA through their tacit knowledge resources. However,
660    observable profits differ, so that where accountability mechanisms are effective, profits
       from SCA are above normal and accrue to external stakeholders (quadrant 1). Where
       accountability mechanisms are ineffective, rents accrue to insiders (quadrant 2).
       Reported profits are normal, since insiders will report and distribute the level of profit
       required for minimally satisfying investors and preventing them from exiting their
       investment. Remaining surplus will be consumed as rents by insiders. On the bottom
       row, there are no VRIN assets and therefore no basis for SCA. Because there are no
       VRIN assets, rent appropriation by insiders is also impossible. Profits are therefore
       normal in both quadrants 3 and 4. In quadrant 4, losses (i.e. less than normal profits)
       are possible if managers are not well monitored and appropriate rents, but only in the
       very short-run. Because there are no VRIN knowledge assets, the normal rate of profit
       is well known and therefore deviations below are easy to police. Insofar as SCA and
       abnormal profits only occur consistently in quadrant 1, accountability mechanisms
       contribute to observable competitive advantage. Even here the trade-offs referred to in
       Figure 1 still apply, so that increased investment in VRIN assets also increases
       monitoring costs. Therefore abnormal profits and SCA are only concurrent where
       accountability mechanisms are cost-effective. In short, heterogeneous value creation
       processes and cost-effective accountability mechanisms are jointly necessary and
       sufficient conditions for SCA.
          There are relatively few devices available to outside investors to ensure that their
       firm operates in quadrant 1. An example might be to recruit outside directors with
       sufficient independence from the main board but who simultaneously possess the
       sector-specific expertise required to monitor knowledge based assets. However, in the
       general case, availability of such directors suggests inter-firm knowledge sharing
       which is in itself inconsistent with firm-level SCA. A possible solution is ideology, and
       notions such as “shareholder value maximization”. Arguably, such notions might be
       more easily shared between outside investors and the firm’s top management. Top
       management might therefore employ ideology to mitigate apparently selfish utilization
       of tacit knowledge-based wealth consumption by organizational insiders, consistent
       with Penrose’s view that firms and their managers are essentially profit-orientated, and
       that managerial opportunism and the agency problem constitute only a special case
       (Lockett and Thompson, 2004). However, there is little rational basis for managerial
       pursuit of abnormal profit, since it derives from a contradictory appeal to the selfish
       interests of another group, i.e. the shareholders, and because normal rather than
       abnormal profits are a sufficient basis for the firm’s survival. If ideology by itself is
       insufficient, the use of trust in limited measure down the hierarchy in combination with
       ideology based sanctions (Armstrong, 1991) may be necessary to achieve quadrant 1
       outcomes.
          The trade-offs in Figures 1 to 3 explain participants’ behaviour in a dynamic system
       operating within social and technically determined limits. There is an incentive to
       invest in knowledge assets insofar as the marginal product is positive net of
monitoring costs. Because tacitness can rise to the point of total opacity there is an      Value, profit
upward limit on the investment level. Similarly there is a downward limit to alienation,        and risk
since if all processes are explicit, although monitoring costs are zero, individual firms
cannot achieve SCA under RBV assumptions[19]. The realized rate of profit for the
firm, as an asset bundle, depends on the interaction of these contradictions, but is
unrelated to the competence or otherwise of the firm’s management, who, where
rational, will appropriate surpluses privately. The rate of surplus accruing to                    661
individual employees and managers depends on the possession of knowledge and
monitoring cost.

4. Discussion
Implications for accounting theory: the Cambridge controversies revisited
One of the most important potential implications of the model is for the problem of the
valuation of heterogeneous assets, or capital goods (Wicksell, 1934). Conventionally,
asset value is the present value of the future cash flows the asset is likely to generate,
presupposing a discount rate and therefore a rate of profit[20]. However in the RBV as
in neo-classical economics, the rate of profit follows from the possession of valuable
(scarce) assets. Wicksell effects and the associated Neo-Ricardian problems of capital
reversing and re-switching are important challenges to the RBV, since they imply
simultaneous equilibria where firms comprise different combinations of labour and
capital at different rates of profit. If either labour or capital is a VRIN asset, the
implication is that they are only likely to hold such status within a certain range of
profit rates. These issues were raised in the “Cambridge controversies”, but never
satisfactorily resolved (Cohen and Harcourt, 2003).
   An alternative approach is to value capital assets according to cost of production.
Wicksell effects also bedevil this approach, because there is a periodic need to revalue
the capital stock to reflect price and technology changes. However, from the RVRR
perspective, these problems are more tractable, and capitalization rates can be derived
from the internal contractual structure of the firm. As Figure 2 shows, the risk adjusted
required rate of return is a linear function of embedded fixed labour cost. Figure 2 is
also generalizable from labour to other classes of cost, using the same fixity of cost
approach[21]. Moreover, corporate boards can impose these expected returns on
business units using output controls. Although problems of asymmetric information,
possession of tacit knowledge and monitoring costs impact on individual valuations,
the associated risks are diversifiable by investors and have no systematic impact on
expected returns or required capitalization rates. In general therefore, rational
valuations for heterogeneous assets, for example RBV style intangibles, can be arrived
at by examining the underlying social relationships and associated cost structure
within the firm.

Implications for strategic management
Such a focus also addresses the need for theoretically consistent risk measures
identified in the earlier review of the strategy literature. Also, the RRVR approach to
some extent parallels Madhok’s (2002) response to Williamson’s (1991) call for an
integrated approach, albeit without the restrictions imposed by the reification of the
firm and absence of shareholder-based governance mechanisms that tend to occur in
such transaction cost RBV analyses. In reality, because outside shareholders can only
AAAJ   apply output controls to top management, they must rely on accounting
23,5   representations of results, leaving top management, crucially, in control of the
       process of transformation of heterogeneous capital resource into homogeneous cash
       flow equivalent representations. Therefore top management also have the ability to
       promote internal reinvestment of profits from innovation into perquisites at the
       expense of dividend payments to shareholders. Also the way in which the firm’s
662    managerial hierarchy exercises surveillance is potentially important, through access
       control or incentivization, respectively examples of action and output controls.
          There are other similarities between RVRR and Denrell et al. (2003), who assume
       that all stage transformations through intermediate to finished products require only
       labour cost and that labour is undifferentiated. They also assume that all prices are in
       present value terms. It follows that the discount rate, or more precisely, the
       risk-adjusted rate of profit, is presupposed. If it is necessary to assume wage rates,
       prices and profit rates a priori, in a model with two factors of production, labour and
       capital, it is difficult to see how this model rigorously adds to the theory of value.
          The Lippman and Rumelt (hereafter L&R) bargaining and payments perspectives
       also have similarities to the RVRR approach. Unlike RVRR, however, the L&R
       approach lacks an underlying theory of value creation. The bargaining approach
       assumes a surplus (Lippman and Rumelt, 2003b, p. 1071, emphasis added).
       Alternatively for the payments perspective, (Lippman and Rumelt, 2003a) economic
       profit is set at zero, presumably for all firms in aggregate, implying differences in price
       and cost sum to zero, or revenues 8 payments. At the aggregate level, these are merely
       wealth transfers. In contrast, RVRR offers an explanation as to why on aggregate the
       value of purchased outputs is systematically higher than purchased inputs.
          According to Lippman and Rumelt (2003b), value distribution depends on the
       structure of a bargaining game. A condition is that the game should have a core[22]
       otherwise the participants lack the incentive to work together for a co-operatively
       beneficial outcome. Where an innovative employee possesses tacit knowledge, it is
       unlikely that person will enter the game unless the firm’s incentive structure is such
       that the employee will appropriate a significant share of revenues. Where ex ante
       contracts of employment specify the ownership and rewards from innovation as
       proprietary to the firm, these incentives will not exist. Assets that achieve this, such as
       proprietary technology and large fixed asset bases, restrict access from the employees’
       point of view and prevent them setting up a competing firm. At the same time, they
       ensure inequality in bilateral bargaining gains, encouraging indirect rent
       appropriation. The appropriation process in this case, outlined in the RVRR, arises
       from non co-operation by the innovative employee and imperfect surveillance of effort
       by the employer, so that rent arising from innovation and greater efficiency is
       appropriated by firm insiders through equivalent shirking. An alternative contractual
       arrangement, which gives the employee incentive to share information, places a core in
       the game, but with the risk that the employee appropriates some monetary benefit.
          A further problematic aspect of Lippman and Rumelt’s (2003a, p. 924) analysis is
       their concluding objective function, that the firm should maximize its wealth and that
       competition will induce it to maximize payments for scarce resources (PSR). PSR is a
       residual category, once payments of commodity inputs (PCI) and payments for
       commodity resources (PCR) have been accounted for. Because the other two categories
       are defined as commodities, they are also defined to be in perfectly elastic supply. If
Revenue ¼ PCI þ PCR þ PSR and the firm is a price taker in two out of the three                Value, profit
categories, then changes in PSR can only be explained with reference to themselves,               and risk
which removes any analytic properties from the identity. If on the other hand, perfect
competition is as defined by Makowski and Ostroy (1995) and Lippman and Rumelt
(2003b, p. 1071), as a condition in which individuals fully appropriate the value they
create, then market imperfection implies transfer of surplus through rent (per classical
theory) rather than value. It also follows that if individuals do not fully appropriate the          663
value they create in a market relation other than in perfect competition, this will also be
the case in an employment relation. RVRR, which includes labour rents, does better
than Classical theory and the sections of the RBV literature that ignore the creation of
value through human action.
   The value price cost (VPC) framework approach differentiates between value,
defined as the price the customer is willing to pay; price, which is a function of supply
and demand; and cost, which is the cost of production. The framework assumes V . P
. C, which is likely to be true when individual cases of competitive advantage are
considered, and competitive advantage might arise in individual cases of V . P and P
. C (Hoopes et al., 2003). However, in the aggregate V ¼ P ¼ C, otherwise it is not
clear why customers would systematically value all products and services above their
cost of production. The equality of VPC in the aggregate is also consistent with the
payments perspective (Lippman and Rumelt, 2003a), but inconsistent with an
underlying theory of value creation. If V is systematically higher than C in the
aggregate in price terms, then firms must be acquiring a resource for a price below its
cost. The only resource all firms share common access to is human resource. As we
have seen, it is this resource in particular that not only creates value through
intellectual and physical effort, but such effort is also problematic to measure and
observe, unlike the costs of other inputs.
   In similar fashion to the VPC approach, MacDonald and Ryall (2004) attempt to
show that value arises from the presence of a willing buyer. In the case presented
(MacDonald and Ryall, 2004, p. 1321), the cost of production is normalized to zero and
the buyer’s utility is set at 1. To presuppose utility at a level greater than the cost of
production, is however, non-generalizable, since without equivalent payments to
production factors utility cannot constitute effective demand. If the case is merely
specific then the bargaining game is a question of rent sharing between firm and buyer,
rather than value creation. Consistent with M&R, the appropriation of value depends
on the number of firms and buyers. As in many interpretations that analyse at the level
of the firm, there is reification and no consideration of rent splits within the
organization. As with L&R, the M&R analysis could be extended to include the
employment relation, so that bargaining is represented as an interaction between
employee and employer as a buyer of labour.

5. Conclusion
A common theory of value for accounting and strategy is appealing for a number of
reasons. First, the strategy literature, and especially the RBV, places emphasis on the
role of human capital in the creation of competitive advantage, which at the same time
poses problems for accountants in terms of total business and intangible asset
valuation. Second, both disciplines have an interest in understanding the meaning of
normal profit and its adjustment for risk where it impacts on performance or
AAAJ   investment decisions. Third, both disciplines are interested in how, once made, profits
       are appropriated. A situation where a firm is more efficient than competitors, but
23,5   whose surplus is appropriated by insiders rather than distributed to shareholders
       would not necessarily meet the strategists’ understanding of SCA. Accountants
       similarly are concerned with controls which prevent misappropriation of resources
       that ultimately are shareholders’ property. Thus, a theory of value also needs to be one
664    of accountability.
           Accordingly, the theory developed above has attempted to integrate these elements
       to the mutual benefit of accounting and strategy. The contribution of the paper is a
       theory of SCA, asset valuation and accountability using a consistent theory of value.
       The argument above has accepted the main assumptions of the RBV. It has also argued
       for the inclusion of labour process theory, asymmetric information, extension of
       Ricardian rent using Marx’s two categories of differential rent, and the analysis of risk,
       in the proposed RVRR. The combination of these elements shows that a resource-based
       theory must unite the process and content elements of strategy, through simultaneous
       interaction of labour management, the determinants of SCA and relations with capital
       markets. It has shown that by utilising the RVRR as a substitute for the CAPM, so that
       the employment of human resource creates value, but the value creation process is
       itself risky from the perspective of the monitoring employer and outside investor, a
       consistent theory of value can be applied to explain SCA. The theory also explains that
       the roots of competitive advantage lie in the labour process, but with the corollary that
       maximizing the associated investment in tacit knowledge and associated difficult to
       replicate assets is potentially inconsistent with maximizing the value of shareholder’s
       investments. Without the links, advocated above, to LTV, labour process theory and
       mechanisms of accountability, the RBV remains merely a view and not a theory,
       because it lacks a consistent basis for asset valuation and cannot explain systematic
       variations in profit.

       Notes
        1. In similar vein, the RBV had been neglected in the industrial economics literature (Lockett
           and Thompson, 2001).
        2. Without measurement, the RBV might still operate, but only as a heuristic, or a means of
           understanding an organization as a knowledge system, such that the link with “value” is
           tangential, and not as a theory of SCA.
        3. Ricardian differential rent is “the difference between the produce obtained by the
           employment of two equal quantities of labour and capital” (Marx, 1984, p. 649).
        4. Such allusions to Classical theories of economics are rare in the strategic management
           literature notwithstanding the obvious parallels with the LTV and Ricardian rents. LTV, as
           the cornerstone of Classical economics (Mouck, 1994) has been discussed extensively in the
           accounting literature (for example Bryer, 1994, 2007; Toms, 2006a).
        5. Henri(2006, p.539) suggests that the performance measurement system (PMS) does create
           RBV capabilities.
        6. This definition goes beyond the debate in the accounting literature about how Marx’s
           socially necessary labour time might be in an accounting context (Bryer, 1999; Macve, 1999).
        7. Labour rents accrue to employees (and managers) where the wage rate exceeds the MELR.
           Where employees possess knowledge that is not easily replicable, particularly when
           routinized within the organization, possession of such knowledge provides workers with
opportunities to raise real wages, if they can avoid accountability and appropriate the             Value, profit
    efficiency benefits (c/f efficiency wage theories, Katz, 1987).
                                                                                                            and risk
 8. This is an oversimplification for the purposes of model development. It extends reasoning
    that stakeholders earn quasi-rents when a factor has a higher marginal product than is
    required to hold it in place (Klein et al., 1978).
 9. Investment in strategic human resource assets (Mueller, 1996; Wright et al., 1994) is a
    sufficient but not a necessary condition for realized super-normal profits, since the                        665
    employment of such assets simultaneously leads to the creation of internal rent
    appropriation possibilities.
10. As seniority increases managers may find more of their time allocated to non-productive
    monitoring activities.
11. Although there is an incentive, it is doubtful whether full externalisation is possible. Using
    Dewey’s notion of productive enquiry, Cook and Seely Brown (1999, p. 391) argue that
    possessed knowledge, whether individual or group, is a set of tools to guide action. Within
    organisations, genres, such as mission statements, are used (or misused) to communicate
    tacit knowledge in groups. Following this logic accounting controls must monitor how
    individuals and groups use knowledge.
12. RBV and LPT are from divergent backgrounds within the strategic management literature,
    reflecting context and process based approaches respectively.
13. Under the normal semi-strong market efficiency assumptions employed by capital market
    researchers and for which there is the most empirical evidence (Fama, 1991), explicit
    processes are public domain information and their value potential can accordingly be priced
    by the market. Tacit elements cannot be known and cannot be priced by reference to generic
    economy wide factors systematically affecting all firms and therefore appear as residual or
    unexplained risk in the empirical form of the CAPM.
14. It is assumed that labour is the only cost and that there is a single period capital turnover (ie
    all the assets purchased at the beginning of the period are used up by the end of the period).
    These assumptions are for brevity, but the model is generalizable when they are relaxed.
15. Because labour cost co-varies perfectly with revenue, the residual, profit, is a fixed ratio of
    revenue.
16. Assuming unlimited product imitation, as a form of Bertrand competition, MacDonald and
    Ryall (2004) reach a similar conclusion.
17. For example where abnormal returns from insider stock purchases rise as the firm’s R&D
    intensity increases (Coff and Lee, 2003).
18. The lack of a consistent theory of profit equalization has been a long-running problem for
    classical economics. In RVRR, differential risky profit rates arise in the productive process
    and are equalized through the capital market.
19. Or more precisely, removing the reification, individual capitalists or investors cannot make
    abnormal returns.
20. Tinker (2004, p. 458) points out that Sraffa’s critique built on the final works of Ricardo to
    expose this circular reasoning behind Neo-classical value theory.
21. See Modigliani and Miller’s (1958) example utilizing interest costs.
22. The core is defined as the set of pay-offs that ensure the sub-set of pay-offs to any sub-set of
    players is greater than the maximum value available to that group working on its own
    (Lippman and Rumelt, 2003b, p. 1072).
AAAJ   References
23,5   Abeysekera, I. (2008), “Intellectual capital practices of firms and the commodification of labour”,
             Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 36-48.
       Acedo, F.J., Barroso, C. and Galan, J.M. (2006), “The resource-based theory: dissemination and
             main trends”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 27 No. 7, pp. 621-36.
       Ambrosini, V. and Bowman, C. (2001), “Tacit knowledge: some suggestions for
666          operationalization”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 38 No. 6, pp. 811-29.
       Amit, R. and Shoemaker, P.J.H. (1993), “Strategic assets and organizational rents”, Strategic
             Management Journal, Vol. 14 No. 1, pp. 33-46.
       Armour, H.O. and Teece, D.J. (1978), “Organization structure and economic performance: a test of
             the multidivisional hypothesis”, Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 106-22.
       Armstrong, P. (1991), “Contradiction and social dynamics in the capitalist agency relationship”,
             Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 16 No. 1, pp. 1-25.
       Barney, J.B. (1986), “Strategic factor markets: expectations, luck and business strategy”,
             Management Science, Vol. 32 No. 10, pp. 1231-41.
       Barney, J.B. (1991), “Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage”, Journal of
             Management, Vol. 17, pp. 99-120.
       Barney, J.B. (2001), Gaining and Sustaining Competitive Advantage, 2nd ed., Addison-Wesley,
             Boston, MA.
       Barney, J.B. and Peteraf, M. (2003), “Unravelling the resource-based tangle”, Managerial and
             Decision Economics, Vol. 24 No. 4, pp. 309-23.
       Barney, J.B., Wright, M. and Ketchen, D.J. (2001), “The resource-based view of the firm: ten years
             after 1991”, Journal of Management, Vol. 27 No. 6, pp. 625-41.
       Bogner, W.C. and Thomas, H.H. (1994), “Core competence and competitive advantage: a model
             and illustrative evidence from the pharmaceutical industry”, in Hamel, G. and Heene, A.
             (Eds), Competence-based Competition, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, pp. 111-44.
       Bowman, C. and Ambrosini, V. (2000), “Value creation versus value capture: towards a coherent
             definition of value in strategy”, British Journal of Management, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 1-15.
       Bowman, R.G. (1979), “The theoretical relationship between systematic risk and financial
             (accounting) variables”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 34 No. 3, pp. 617-30.
       Bowman, C. and Swart, J. (2007), “Whose human capital? The challenge of value capture when
             capital is embedded”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 44 No. 4, pp. 488-505.
       Bowman, C. and Toms, S. (2010), “Accounting for competitive advantage: the resource-based
             view of the firm and the labour theory of value”, Critical Perspectives in Accounting, Vol. 21
             No. 3, pp. 183-94.
       Brandenburger, Z. and Stuart, G. (1996), “Value-based business strategy”, Journal of Economics
             and Management Strategy, Vol. 5 No. 1, pp. 5-24.
       Bryer, R.A. (1994), “Why Marx’s labour theory is superior to the marginalist theory of value:
             the case from modern financial reporting”, Critical Perspectives on Accounting., Vol. 5 No. 4,
             pp. 313-40.
       Bryer, R.A. (1999), “A Marxist critique of the FASB’s conceptual framework”, Critical
             Perspectives on Accounting, Vol. 10 No. 5, pp. 551-89.
       Bryer, R.A. (2006), “Accounting and control of the labour process”, Critical Perspectives on
             Accounting, Vol. 17 No. 5, pp. 551-98.
       Bryer, R. (2007), “Marx’s accounting solutions to the ‘transformation problem’”, unpublished
             working paper, Warwick Business School, Coventry.
       Carter, C., Clegg, S. and Kornberger, M. (2008), “Strategy as practice?”, Strategic Organization,
             Vol. 6 No. 1, pp. 83-99.
Clare, A.D., Priestley, R. and Thomas, S.H. (1998), “Reports of beta’s death are premature:           Value, profit
       evidence from the UK”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 22 No. 9, pp. 1207-29.
Coff, R.W. (1999), “When competitive advantage doesn’t lead to performance: the resource-based
                                                                                                          and risk
       view and stakeholder bargaining power”, Organization Science, Vol. 10 No. 2, pp. 119-33.
Coff, R. and Lee, P. (2003), “Insider trading as a vehicle to appropriate rent from R&D”, Strategic
       Management Journal, Vol. 24 No. 2, pp. 183-90.
Cohen, A.J. and Harcourt, G.C. (2003), “Whatever happened to the Cambridge capital theory                    667
       controversies?”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 199-214.
Collis, D.J. and Montgomery, C.A. (1995), “Competing on resources: strategy in the 1990s”,
       Harvard Business Review., Vol. 73 No. 4, pp. 118-29.
Collis, D.J. and Montgomery, C.A. (1997), Corporate Strategy: Resources and the Scope of the
       Firm, McGraw-Hill, Chicago, IL.
Cook, S.D.N. and Seely Brown, J. (1999), “Bridging epistemologies: the generative dance, between
       organizational knowledge and organizational knowing”, Organization Science, Vol. 10
       No. 4, pp. 381-400.
Denrell, J., Fang, C. and Winter, S.G. (2003), “The economics of strategic opportunity”, Strategic
       Management Journal, Vol. 24 No. 10, pp. 977-90.
Dierickx, I. and Cool, K. (1989), “Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive
       advantage”, Management Science, Vol. 35 No. 12, pp. 1504-11.
Fama, E. (1991), “Efficient markets II”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 46 No. 5, pp. 1575-617.
Fama, E.F. and French, K.R. (1992), “The cross-section of expected stock returns”, Journal of
       Finance, Vol. 47 No. 2, pp. 427-65.
Feigenbaum, A. and Thomas, H. (1986), “Dynamic and risk measurement perspectives on
       Bowman’s risk-return paradox for strategic management: an empirical study”, Strategic
       Management Journal, Vol. 7 No. 5, pp. 395-407.
Foss, N.J. and Knudsen, T. (2002), “The resource-based tangle: towards a sustainable explanation
       of competitive advantage”, Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 24 No. 4, pp. 291-307.
Grant, R.M. (1996), “Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm”, Strategic Management
       Journal, Vol. 17, special issue, pp. 109-22.
Grossman, S. and Stiglitz, J. (1980), “On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets”,
       American Economic Review, Vol. 70 No. 3, pp. 393-408.
Harcourt, G.C. (1969), “Some Cambridge controversies in the theory of capital”, Journal of
       Economic Literature, Vol. 7 No. 2, pp. 369-405.
Hasseldine, J., Salama, A. and Toms, S. (2005), “Quantity versus quality: the impact of
       environmental disclosures on the reputations of UK plcs”, British Accounting Review,
       Vol. 37 No. 2, pp. 231-48.
Henri, J.F. (2006), “Management control systems and strategy: a resource-based perspective”,
       Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 31 No. 6, pp. 529-58.
Hoopes, D.G., Madsen, T.L. and Walker, G. (2003), “Why is there a resource-based view? Toward
       a theory of competitive heterogeneity”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 24 No. 10,
       pp. 889-902.
Howorth, C. and Westhead, P. (2003), “The focus of working capital management in UK small
       firms”, Management Accounting Research, Vol. 14 No. 2, pp. 94-111.
Katz, L. (1987), “Efficiency wage theories: a partial evaluation”, in Fischer, S. (Ed.), NBER
       Macroeconomics Annual, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 235-75.
Klein, B., Crawford, R.G. and Alchian, A.A. (1978), “Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and
       the competitive contracting process”, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 21 No. 2,
       pp. 297-326.
AAAJ   Knights, D. (1990), “Subjectivity, power and the labour process”, in Knights, D. and Wilmott, H.
              (Eds), Labour Process Theory, Macmillan, London.
23,5   Lado, A.A. and Wilson, M.C. (1994), “Human resource systems and sustained competitive
              advantage”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 19 No. 4, pp. 699-727.
       Lintner, J. (1965), “The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock
              portfolios and capital budgets”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47 No. 1, pp. 13-37.
668    Lippman, S.A. and Rumelt, R.P. (2003a), “A bargaining perspective on resource advantage”,
              Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 24 No. 11, pp. 1069-86.
       Lippman, S.A. and Rumelt, R.P. (2003b), “The payments perspective: micro-foundations of
              resource analysis”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 24 No. 10, pp. 903-27.
       Lockett, A. and Thompson, R.S. (2001), “The resource-based view and economics”, Journal of
              Management, Vol. 27 No. 6, pp. 723-54.
       Lockett, A. and Thompson, R.S. (2004), “Edith Penrose’s contributions to the resource-based
              view: an alternative perspective”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 41 No. 1,
              pp. 193-204.
       MacDonald, G. and Ryall, M.D. (2004), “How do value creation and competition determine
              whether a firm appropriates value?”, Management Science, Vol. 50 No. 10, pp. 1319-33.
       Macve, R. (1999), “Capital and financial accounting: a commentary on Bryer’s ‘A Marxist critique
              of the FASB’s conceptual framework’”, Critical Perpectives on Accounting, Vol. 11 No. 5,
              pp. 591-613.
       Madhok, A. (2002), “Reassessing the fundamentals and beyond: Ronald Coase, the transaction
              cost and resource-based theories of the firm and the institutional structure of production”,
              Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 23 No. 6, pp. 535-50.
       Makadok, R. (2001), “Toward a synthesis of the resource-based and dynamic capability views of
              rent creation”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 22 No. 5, pp. 387-401.
       Makadok, R. and Coff, R. (2002), “The theory of value and the value of theory: breaking new
              ground versus reinventing the wheel”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 27 No. 1,
              pp. 10-13.
       Makowski, L. and Ostroy, J.M. (1995), “Appropriation and efficiency: a revision of the first
              theorem of welfare economics”, American Economic Review, Vol. 85 No. 4, pp. 808-27.
       Marx, K. (1984), Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, III, Lawrence & Wishart, London.
       Mayston, D. (1992), “Capital accounting, user needs and the foundations of a conceptual
              framework for public sector financial reporting”, Financial Accountability & Management,
              Vol. 84 No. 4, pp. 227-48.
       Miller, D. and Shamsie, J. (1996), “The resource-based view of the firm in two environments:
              the Hollywood film studios from 1936 to 1965”, Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 39
              No. 3, pp. 519-43.
       Milne, M. (1991), “Accounting, environmental resource values and non-market valuation
              techniques for environmental resources: a review”, Accounting, Auditing & Accountability
              Journal, Vol. 4 No. 3, pp. 81-109.
       Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (1958), “The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of
              investment”, American Economic Review, Vol. 48 No. 3, pp. 261-97.
       Mohun, S. (1996), “Socially necessary labour”, in Bottomore, T. (Ed.), A Dictionary of Marxist
              Thought, Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 503-4.
       Mouck, T. (1994), “Corporate accountability and Rorty’s Utopian liberalism”, Accounting,
              Auditing & Accountability Journal, Vol. 7 No. 1, pp. 6-30.
       Mueller, F. (1996), “Human resources as strategic assets: an evolutionary resource-based theory”,
              Journal of Management Studies., Vol. 33 No. 6, pp. 757-86.
Nicholls, T. (1999), “Industrial sociology and the labour process”, in Beynon, H. and Glavinis, P.      Value, profit
      (Eds), Patterns of Social Inequality: Essays for Richard Brown, Longman, London.
Nonaka, I. (1991), “The knowledge-creating company”, Harvard Business Review., Vol. 69,
                                                                                                            and risk
      pp. 96-104.
Ouchi, W.G. and Maguire, M.A. (1975), “Organizational control: two functions”, Administrative
      Science Quarterly, Vol. 20 No. 4, pp. 559-69.
Peteraf, M.A. (1993), “The corner-stone of competitive advantage: a resource-based view”,                      669
      Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 14 No. 3, pp. 179-91.
Peters, T.J. and Waterman, R.H. (1982), In Search of Excellence: Lessons from America’s Best-run
      Companies, Harper & Row, New York, NY.
Pfeffer, J. (1995), “Producing sustainable competitive advantage through the effective
      management of people”, Academy of Management Executive, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 55-69.
Prechel, H. (2000), Big Business and the State: Historical Transitions and Corporate
      Transformations, 1880s-1990s, SUNY Press, New York, NY.
Priem, R.L. (2001), “The business-level RBV: Great Wall or Berlin wall?”, Academy of
      Management Review, Vol. 26 No. 4, pp. 499-501.
Priem, R.L. and Butler, J.E. (2001), “Is the resource-based ‘view’ a useful perspective for strategic
      management research?”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 26 No. 1, pp. 22-40.
Robinson, J. (1963), Economic Philosophy, Penguin, London.
Rosen, S. (1985), “Implicit contracts: a survey”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 23,
      pp. 1144-75.
Ruefli, T., Collins, J.M. and LaCugna, J.R. (1999), “Risk measurement in strategic management
      research: Auld lang syne?”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 20 No. 2, pp. 167-94.
Rugman, A.M. and Verbeke, A. (2004), “A final word on Edith Penrose”, Journal of Management
      Studies., Vol. 41 No. 1, pp. 205-17.
Rumelt, R. (1984), “Toward a strategic theory of the firm”, in Lamb, R. (Ed.), Competitive
      Strategic Management, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, pp. 556-70.
Scarborough, H. (1998), “Path(ological) dependency? Core competencies from an organizational
      perspective”, British Journal of Management, Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 219-32.
Sharpe, W.F. (1964), “Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of
      risk”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 425-42.
Singh, J.V. (1986), “Performance, slack, and risk taking in organizational decision making”,
      Academy of Management, Vol. 29 No. 3, pp. 562-85.
Spender, J-C. (1989), Industry Recipes: The Nature and Sources of Managerial Judgement,
      Blackwell, Oxford.
Teece, D., Pisano, G. and Sheun, A. (1997), “Dynamic capabilities and strategic management”,
      Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 18 No. 7, pp. 509-33.
Tinker, A. (1980), “Towards a political economy of accounting: an empirical illustration of the
      Cambridge controversies”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 5 No. 1, pp. 147-60.
Tinker, A. (1984), “Theories of the state and the state of accounting: economic reductionism and
      political voluntarism in accounting regulation theory”, Journal of Accounting and Public
      Policy, Vol. 3 No. 1, pp. 55-74.
Tinker, T. (1999), “Mickey Marxism rides again!”, Critical Perspectives on Accounting, Vol. 10
      No. 5, pp. 643-70.
Tinker, T. (2004), “The enlightenment and its discontents: antinomies of Christianity, Islam and
      the calculative sciences”, Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, Vol. 17 No. 3,
      pp. 442-75.
AAAJ   Tinker, A., Merino, B. and Neimark, M. (1982), “The normative origins of positive theories:
             ideology and accounting thought”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 7 No. 2,
23,5         pp. 176-200.
       Toms, S. (2002), “Firm resources, quality signals and the determinants of corporate
             environmental reputation: some UK evidence”, British Accounting Review, Vol. 34 No. 2,
             pp. 257-82.
       Toms, S. (2006a), “Asset pricing models, the labour theory of value and their implications for
670          accounting”, Critical Perspectives on Accounting, Vol. 17 No. 7, pp. 947-65.
       Toms, S. (2006b), “Accounting for entrepreneurship: a knowledge-based view of the firm”,
             Critical Perspectives in Accounting, Vol. 17 Nos 2/3, pp. 336-57.
       Toms, S. (2008), “‘Immeasurability’: a critique of Hardt and Negri, ephemera”, Theory & Politics
             in Organization, Vol. 8 No. 4, pp. 433-46.
       Toms, S. (2009), “The labour theory of value, risk and the rate of profit”, Critical Perspectives in
             Accounting, in press.
       Toms, S. and Bowman, C. (2010), “Accounting for competitive advantage: the resource-based
             view of the firm and the labour theory of value”, Critical Perspectives in Accounting
             (forthcoming).
       Verdin, P.J. and Williamson, P.J. (1994), “Core competences, competitive advantage and market
             analysis: forging the links”, in Hamel, G. and Heene, A. (Eds), Competence-based
             Competition, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, pp. 77-110.
       Wang, X. (2000), “Size effect, book-to-market effect, and survival”, Journal of Multinational
             Financial Management, Vol. 10 Nos 3/4, pp. 257-73.
       Wicksell, K. (1934), Lectures on Political Economy, Vol. 1, Routledge, London.
       Widener, S. (2006), “Associations between strategic resource importance and performance
             measure use: the impact on firm performance”, Management Accounting Research, Vol. 17
             No. 4, pp. 433-57.
       Williamson, O. (1991), “Strategizing, economizing, and economic organization”, Strategic
             Management Journal, Vol. 12, special issue, pp. 75-94.
       Wilmott, H. (1990), “Subjectivity and the dialectics of praxis: opening up the core of the labour
             process analysis”, in Knights, D. and Wilmott, H. (Eds), Labour Process Theory,
             Macmillan, London.
       Wright, P.M., McMahan, G.C. and McWilliams, A. (1994), “Human resources and sustained
             competitive advantage: a resource-based perspective”, International Journal of Human
             Resource Management, Vol. 5 No. 2, pp. 301-26.

       About the author
       Steven Toms is Professor of Accounting and Finance at the University of York, UK. He is the
       inaugural Head of the York Management School and, with John Wilson, is Co-editor of Business
       History. Steven Toms can be contacted at: st27@york.ac.uk




       To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: reprints@emeraldinsight.com
       Or visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints

Más contenido relacionado

Similar a Value, profit and risk accounting and the resource-based view of the firm

Public And Private Sector Accounting
Public And Private Sector AccountingPublic And Private Sector Accounting
Public And Private Sector AccountingJill Lyons
 
Modelling: What’s next for Financial Services in Europe?
Modelling: What’s next for Financial Services in Europe?Modelling: What’s next for Financial Services in Europe?
Modelling: What’s next for Financial Services in Europe?GRATeam
 
Assessing Empirical Research In Managerial Accounting A Value-Based Manageme...
Assessing Empirical Research In Managerial Accounting  A Value-Based Manageme...Assessing Empirical Research In Managerial Accounting  A Value-Based Manageme...
Assessing Empirical Research In Managerial Accounting A Value-Based Manageme...Andrea Erdman
 
Gra wp modelling perspectives
Gra wp modelling perspectivesGra wp modelling perspectives
Gra wp modelling perspectivesGenest Benoit
 
Role of cm as in ifrs era library@imt dubai on www.gobookee
Role of cm as in ifrs era   library@imt dubai on www.gobookeeRole of cm as in ifrs era   library@imt dubai on www.gobookee
Role of cm as in ifrs era library@imt dubai on www.gobookeeRavi Pandya
 
Accounting Flexibility and Earnings Management: Evidence from Quoted Real Sec...
Accounting Flexibility and Earnings Management: Evidence from Quoted Real Sec...Accounting Flexibility and Earnings Management: Evidence from Quoted Real Sec...
Accounting Flexibility and Earnings Management: Evidence from Quoted Real Sec...QUESTJOURNAL
 
Accountability Papers From Master Theses 2008
Accountability  Papers From Master Theses 2008Accountability  Papers From Master Theses 2008
Accountability Papers From Master Theses 2008Leslie Schulte
 
CH&Cie - Fundamental Review of the Trading Book
CH&Cie - Fundamental Review of the Trading BookCH&Cie - Fundamental Review of the Trading Book
CH&Cie - Fundamental Review of the Trading BookC Louiza
 
tibu-published article10.11648.j.jfa.20160404.13
tibu-published article10.11648.j.jfa.20160404.13tibu-published article10.11648.j.jfa.20160404.13
tibu-published article10.11648.j.jfa.20160404.13Tibu Ngozi
 
Formulation of Predictive and Positive theory
Formulation of Predictive and Positive theoryFormulation of Predictive and Positive theory
Formulation of Predictive and Positive theoryAsmita Nagpal
 
Developing linkage among transactional value, acquisition value, relationship...
Developing linkage among transactional value, acquisition value, relationship...Developing linkage among transactional value, acquisition value, relationship...
Developing linkage among transactional value, acquisition value, relationship...Enamul Islam
 
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...ECTIJ
 
Advanced Petroleum Economics & Risk Analysis
Advanced Petroleum Economics & Risk AnalysisAdvanced Petroleum Economics & Risk Analysis
Advanced Petroleum Economics & Risk AnalysispetroEDGE
 
Blueprint Fossil Fuel Industry Transition From Carbon Tracker
Blueprint Fossil Fuel Industry Transition From Carbon TrackerBlueprint Fossil Fuel Industry Transition From Carbon Tracker
Blueprint Fossil Fuel Industry Transition From Carbon TrackerEnergy for One World
 
Service Quality At Univrsity Of Dar Es Salaam Business...
Service Quality At Univrsity Of Dar Es Salaam Business...Service Quality At Univrsity Of Dar Es Salaam Business...
Service Quality At Univrsity Of Dar Es Salaam Business...Jan Champagne
 
Resource consumption accounting
Resource consumption accountingResource consumption accounting
Resource consumption accountingShuvankar Dey
 
37267946 managing-costs-and-cost-structure-throughout-the-value-chain-researc...
37267946 managing-costs-and-cost-structure-throughout-the-value-chain-researc...37267946 managing-costs-and-cost-structure-throughout-the-value-chain-researc...
37267946 managing-costs-and-cost-structure-throughout-the-value-chain-researc...Adnan Sevim
 
Cooper & sherer political economy of acc
Cooper & sherer political economy of accCooper & sherer political economy of acc
Cooper & sherer political economy of accSri Apriyanti Husain
 
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...ECTIJ
 
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...ectijjournal
 

Similar a Value, profit and risk accounting and the resource-based view of the firm (20)

Public And Private Sector Accounting
Public And Private Sector AccountingPublic And Private Sector Accounting
Public And Private Sector Accounting
 
Modelling: What’s next for Financial Services in Europe?
Modelling: What’s next for Financial Services in Europe?Modelling: What’s next for Financial Services in Europe?
Modelling: What’s next for Financial Services in Europe?
 
Assessing Empirical Research In Managerial Accounting A Value-Based Manageme...
Assessing Empirical Research In Managerial Accounting  A Value-Based Manageme...Assessing Empirical Research In Managerial Accounting  A Value-Based Manageme...
Assessing Empirical Research In Managerial Accounting A Value-Based Manageme...
 
Gra wp modelling perspectives
Gra wp modelling perspectivesGra wp modelling perspectives
Gra wp modelling perspectives
 
Role of cm as in ifrs era library@imt dubai on www.gobookee
Role of cm as in ifrs era   library@imt dubai on www.gobookeeRole of cm as in ifrs era   library@imt dubai on www.gobookee
Role of cm as in ifrs era library@imt dubai on www.gobookee
 
Accounting Flexibility and Earnings Management: Evidence from Quoted Real Sec...
Accounting Flexibility and Earnings Management: Evidence from Quoted Real Sec...Accounting Flexibility and Earnings Management: Evidence from Quoted Real Sec...
Accounting Flexibility and Earnings Management: Evidence from Quoted Real Sec...
 
Accountability Papers From Master Theses 2008
Accountability  Papers From Master Theses 2008Accountability  Papers From Master Theses 2008
Accountability Papers From Master Theses 2008
 
CH&Cie - Fundamental Review of the Trading Book
CH&Cie - Fundamental Review of the Trading BookCH&Cie - Fundamental Review of the Trading Book
CH&Cie - Fundamental Review of the Trading Book
 
tibu-published article10.11648.j.jfa.20160404.13
tibu-published article10.11648.j.jfa.20160404.13tibu-published article10.11648.j.jfa.20160404.13
tibu-published article10.11648.j.jfa.20160404.13
 
Formulation of Predictive and Positive theory
Formulation of Predictive and Positive theoryFormulation of Predictive and Positive theory
Formulation of Predictive and Positive theory
 
Developing linkage among transactional value, acquisition value, relationship...
Developing linkage among transactional value, acquisition value, relationship...Developing linkage among transactional value, acquisition value, relationship...
Developing linkage among transactional value, acquisition value, relationship...
 
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
 
Advanced Petroleum Economics & Risk Analysis
Advanced Petroleum Economics & Risk AnalysisAdvanced Petroleum Economics & Risk Analysis
Advanced Petroleum Economics & Risk Analysis
 
Blueprint Fossil Fuel Industry Transition From Carbon Tracker
Blueprint Fossil Fuel Industry Transition From Carbon TrackerBlueprint Fossil Fuel Industry Transition From Carbon Tracker
Blueprint Fossil Fuel Industry Transition From Carbon Tracker
 
Service Quality At Univrsity Of Dar Es Salaam Business...
Service Quality At Univrsity Of Dar Es Salaam Business...Service Quality At Univrsity Of Dar Es Salaam Business...
Service Quality At Univrsity Of Dar Es Salaam Business...
 
Resource consumption accounting
Resource consumption accountingResource consumption accounting
Resource consumption accounting
 
37267946 managing-costs-and-cost-structure-throughout-the-value-chain-researc...
37267946 managing-costs-and-cost-structure-throughout-the-value-chain-researc...37267946 managing-costs-and-cost-structure-throughout-the-value-chain-researc...
37267946 managing-costs-and-cost-structure-throughout-the-value-chain-researc...
 
Cooper & sherer political economy of acc
Cooper & sherer political economy of accCooper & sherer political economy of acc
Cooper & sherer political economy of acc
 
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
 
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
AN EVALUATION OF THE TRADITIONAL HISTORICAL COST BASIS OF ACCOUNTING IN PROVI...
 

Más de tamoni

Use of resource based view in industrial cluster strategic analysis
Use of resource based view in industrial cluster strategic analysisUse of resource based view in industrial cluster strategic analysis
Use of resource based view in industrial cluster strategic analysistamoni
 
Understanding the influence of information systems competencies on process in...
Understanding the influence of information systems competencies on process in...Understanding the influence of information systems competencies on process in...
Understanding the influence of information systems competencies on process in...tamoni
 
The resource based view and value- the customer-based view of the firm
The resource based view and value- the customer-based view of the firmThe resource based view and value- the customer-based view of the firm
The resource based view and value- the customer-based view of the firmtamoni
 
Resource based view of the firm [lockett, morgenstern and thompson, internati...
Resource based view of the firm [lockett, morgenstern and thompson, internati...Resource based view of the firm [lockett, morgenstern and thompson, internati...
Resource based view of the firm [lockett, morgenstern and thompson, internati...tamoni
 
Resource based competitiveness
Resource based competitivenessResource based competitiveness
Resource based competitivenesstamoni
 
RBV and its value
RBV and its valueRBV and its value
RBV and its valuetamoni
 
RBV and competitive strategy
RBV and competitive strategyRBV and competitive strategy
RBV and competitive strategytamoni
 
Market pioneers, late movers, and the resource based view (rbv)- a conceptual...
Market pioneers, late movers, and the resource based view (rbv)- a conceptual...Market pioneers, late movers, and the resource based view (rbv)- a conceptual...
Market pioneers, late movers, and the resource based view (rbv)- a conceptual...tamoni
 
Constructing a definition for intangibles using the resource based view of th...
Constructing a definition for intangibles using the resource based view of th...Constructing a definition for intangibles using the resource based view of th...
Constructing a definition for intangibles using the resource based view of th...tamoni
 
Assessing the relationship between firm resources and product innovation perf...
Assessing the relationship between firm resources and product innovation perf...Assessing the relationship between firm resources and product innovation perf...
Assessing the relationship between firm resources and product innovation perf...tamoni
 
A resource based view of the small firm
A resource based view of the small firmA resource based view of the small firm
A resource based view of the small firmtamoni
 
A heterogeneous resource based view for exploring relationships between firm ...
A heterogeneous resource based view for exploring relationships between firm ...A heterogeneous resource based view for exploring relationships between firm ...
A heterogeneous resource based view for exploring relationships between firm ...tamoni
 
A resource based view of organizational knowledge management systems
A resource based view of organizational knowledge management systemsA resource based view of organizational knowledge management systems
A resource based view of organizational knowledge management systemstamoni
 
A resource based view of micro-firm management practice
A resource based view of micro-firm management practiceA resource based view of micro-firm management practice
A resource based view of micro-firm management practicetamoni
 

Más de tamoni (14)

Use of resource based view in industrial cluster strategic analysis
Use of resource based view in industrial cluster strategic analysisUse of resource based view in industrial cluster strategic analysis
Use of resource based view in industrial cluster strategic analysis
 
Understanding the influence of information systems competencies on process in...
Understanding the influence of information systems competencies on process in...Understanding the influence of information systems competencies on process in...
Understanding the influence of information systems competencies on process in...
 
The resource based view and value- the customer-based view of the firm
The resource based view and value- the customer-based view of the firmThe resource based view and value- the customer-based view of the firm
The resource based view and value- the customer-based view of the firm
 
Resource based view of the firm [lockett, morgenstern and thompson, internati...
Resource based view of the firm [lockett, morgenstern and thompson, internati...Resource based view of the firm [lockett, morgenstern and thompson, internati...
Resource based view of the firm [lockett, morgenstern and thompson, internati...
 
Resource based competitiveness
Resource based competitivenessResource based competitiveness
Resource based competitiveness
 
RBV and its value
RBV and its valueRBV and its value
RBV and its value
 
RBV and competitive strategy
RBV and competitive strategyRBV and competitive strategy
RBV and competitive strategy
 
Market pioneers, late movers, and the resource based view (rbv)- a conceptual...
Market pioneers, late movers, and the resource based view (rbv)- a conceptual...Market pioneers, late movers, and the resource based view (rbv)- a conceptual...
Market pioneers, late movers, and the resource based view (rbv)- a conceptual...
 
Constructing a definition for intangibles using the resource based view of th...
Constructing a definition for intangibles using the resource based view of th...Constructing a definition for intangibles using the resource based view of th...
Constructing a definition for intangibles using the resource based view of th...
 
Assessing the relationship between firm resources and product innovation perf...
Assessing the relationship between firm resources and product innovation perf...Assessing the relationship between firm resources and product innovation perf...
Assessing the relationship between firm resources and product innovation perf...
 
A resource based view of the small firm
A resource based view of the small firmA resource based view of the small firm
A resource based view of the small firm
 
A heterogeneous resource based view for exploring relationships between firm ...
A heterogeneous resource based view for exploring relationships between firm ...A heterogeneous resource based view for exploring relationships between firm ...
A heterogeneous resource based view for exploring relationships between firm ...
 
A resource based view of organizational knowledge management systems
A resource based view of organizational knowledge management systemsA resource based view of organizational knowledge management systems
A resource based view of organizational knowledge management systems
 
A resource based view of micro-firm management practice
A resource based view of micro-firm management practiceA resource based view of micro-firm management practice
A resource based view of micro-firm management practice
 

Último

Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan CommunicationsPharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communicationskarancommunications
 
Call Girls in Delhi, Escort Service Available 24x7 in Delhi 959961-/-3876
Call Girls in Delhi, Escort Service Available 24x7 in Delhi 959961-/-3876Call Girls in Delhi, Escort Service Available 24x7 in Delhi 959961-/-3876
Call Girls in Delhi, Escort Service Available 24x7 in Delhi 959961-/-3876dlhescort
 
Uneak White's Personal Brand Exploration Presentation
Uneak White's Personal Brand Exploration PresentationUneak White's Personal Brand Exploration Presentation
Uneak White's Personal Brand Exploration Presentationuneakwhite
 
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine ServiceCall Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Serviceritikaroy0888
 
Call Girls In DLf Gurgaon ➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genuine Escort In 24...
Call Girls In DLf Gurgaon ➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genuine Escort In 24...Call Girls In DLf Gurgaon ➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genuine Escort In 24...
Call Girls In DLf Gurgaon ➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genuine Escort In 24...lizamodels9
 
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptx
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptxCracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptx
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptxWorkforce Group
 
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best ServicesMysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best ServicesDipal Arora
 
Chandigarh Escorts Service 📞8868886958📞 Just📲 Call Nihal Chandigarh Call Girl...
Chandigarh Escorts Service 📞8868886958📞 Just📲 Call Nihal Chandigarh Call Girl...Chandigarh Escorts Service 📞8868886958📞 Just📲 Call Nihal Chandigarh Call Girl...
Chandigarh Escorts Service 📞8868886958📞 Just📲 Call Nihal Chandigarh Call Girl...Sheetaleventcompany
 
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usageInsurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usageMatteo Carbone
 
Call Girls From Pari Chowk Greater Noida ❤️8448577510 ⊹Best Escorts Service I...
Call Girls From Pari Chowk Greater Noida ❤️8448577510 ⊹Best Escorts Service I...Call Girls From Pari Chowk Greater Noida ❤️8448577510 ⊹Best Escorts Service I...
Call Girls From Pari Chowk Greater Noida ❤️8448577510 ⊹Best Escorts Service I...lizamodels9
 
Call Girls Hebbal Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Bangalore
Call Girls Hebbal Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service BangaloreCall Girls Hebbal Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Bangalore
Call Girls Hebbal Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Bangaloreamitlee9823
 
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noida
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service NoidaCall Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noida
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noidadlhescort
 
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Dipal Arora
 
Phases of Negotiation .pptx
 Phases of Negotiation .pptx Phases of Negotiation .pptx
Phases of Negotiation .pptxnandhinijagan9867
 
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...Dave Litwiller
 
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...daisycvs
 
How to Get Started in Social Media for Art League City
How to Get Started in Social Media for Art League CityHow to Get Started in Social Media for Art League City
How to Get Started in Social Media for Art League CityEric T. Tung
 
John Halpern sued for sexual assault.pdf
John Halpern sued for sexual assault.pdfJohn Halpern sued for sexual assault.pdf
John Halpern sued for sexual assault.pdfAmzadHosen3
 

Último (20)

Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan CommunicationsPharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
 
Call Girls in Delhi, Escort Service Available 24x7 in Delhi 959961-/-3876
Call Girls in Delhi, Escort Service Available 24x7 in Delhi 959961-/-3876Call Girls in Delhi, Escort Service Available 24x7 in Delhi 959961-/-3876
Call Girls in Delhi, Escort Service Available 24x7 in Delhi 959961-/-3876
 
Uneak White's Personal Brand Exploration Presentation
Uneak White's Personal Brand Exploration PresentationUneak White's Personal Brand Exploration Presentation
Uneak White's Personal Brand Exploration Presentation
 
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine ServiceCall Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
 
Call Girls In DLf Gurgaon ➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genuine Escort In 24...
Call Girls In DLf Gurgaon ➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genuine Escort In 24...Call Girls In DLf Gurgaon ➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genuine Escort In 24...
Call Girls In DLf Gurgaon ➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genuine Escort In 24...
 
VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...
VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...
VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...
 
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptx
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptxCracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptx
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptx
 
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best ServicesMysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
 
Chandigarh Escorts Service 📞8868886958📞 Just📲 Call Nihal Chandigarh Call Girl...
Chandigarh Escorts Service 📞8868886958📞 Just📲 Call Nihal Chandigarh Call Girl...Chandigarh Escorts Service 📞8868886958📞 Just📲 Call Nihal Chandigarh Call Girl...
Chandigarh Escorts Service 📞8868886958📞 Just📲 Call Nihal Chandigarh Call Girl...
 
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usageInsurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
 
Call Girls From Pari Chowk Greater Noida ❤️8448577510 ⊹Best Escorts Service I...
Call Girls From Pari Chowk Greater Noida ❤️8448577510 ⊹Best Escorts Service I...Call Girls From Pari Chowk Greater Noida ❤️8448577510 ⊹Best Escorts Service I...
Call Girls From Pari Chowk Greater Noida ❤️8448577510 ⊹Best Escorts Service I...
 
Call Girls Hebbal Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Bangalore
Call Girls Hebbal Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service BangaloreCall Girls Hebbal Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Bangalore
Call Girls Hebbal Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Bangalore
 
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noida
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service NoidaCall Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noida
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noida
 
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
 
Falcon Invoice Discounting platform in india
Falcon Invoice Discounting platform in indiaFalcon Invoice Discounting platform in india
Falcon Invoice Discounting platform in india
 
Phases of Negotiation .pptx
 Phases of Negotiation .pptx Phases of Negotiation .pptx
Phases of Negotiation .pptx
 
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
 
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...
 
How to Get Started in Social Media for Art League City
How to Get Started in Social Media for Art League CityHow to Get Started in Social Media for Art League City
How to Get Started in Social Media for Art League City
 
John Halpern sued for sexual assault.pdf
John Halpern sued for sexual assault.pdfJohn Halpern sued for sexual assault.pdf
John Halpern sued for sexual assault.pdf
 

Value, profit and risk accounting and the resource-based view of the firm

  • 1. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal Emerald Article: Value, profit and risk: accounting and the resource-based view of the firm Steven Toms Article information: To cite this document: Steven Toms, (2010),"Value, profit and risk: accounting and the resource-based view of the firm", Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, Vol. 23 Iss: 5 pp. 647 - 670 Permanent link to this document: http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/09513571011054927 Downloaded on: 07-12-2012 References: This document contains references to 102 other documents Citations: This document has been cited by 3 other documents To copy this document: permissions@emeraldinsight.com This document has been downloaded 2401 times since 2010. * Access to this document was granted through an Emerald subscription provided by UNIVERSITY OF THE ARTS LONDON For Authors: If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for Authors service. Information about how to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines are available for all. Please visit www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for more information. About Emerald www.emeraldinsight.com With over forty years' experience, Emerald Group Publishing is a leading independent publisher of global research with impact in business, society, public policy and education. In total, Emerald publishes over 275 journals and more than 130 book series, as well as an extensive range of online products and services. Emerald is both COUNTER 3 and TRANSFER compliant. The organization is a partner of the Committee on Publication Ethics (COPE) and also works with Portico and the LOCKSS initiative for digital archive preservation. *Related content and download information correct at time of download.
  • 2. The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at www.emeraldinsight.com/0951-3574.htm Value, profit Value, profit and risk: and risk accounting and the resource-based view of the firm 647 Steven Toms The York Management School, University of York, Heslington, UK Abstract Purpose – This paper aims to argue that the principal components of the Resource-Based View (RBV) as a theory of sustained competitive advantage are not a sufficient basis for a complete and consistent theory of firm behaviour. Two missing elements are value theory and accountability mechanisms. Design/methodology/approach – The paper proposes a link between value theory and accountability using a Resource Value-Resource Risk perspective as an alternative to the Capital Asset Pricing Model. The link operates first from the labour process, where value is created but is imperfectly observable by intra-firm mechanisms of organizational control and outside governance arrangements without incurring monitoring costs. Second, it operates through contractual arrangements which impose fixed cost structures on activities with variable revenues. Findings – The paper thereby explains how value originates in risky and difficult to monitor productive processes and is transmitted as rents to organizational and capital market constituents. It then reviews recent contributions to the RBV, arguing that the proposed new approach overcomes gaps inherent in the alternatives, and thus offers a more complete and integrated view of firm behaviour. Originality/value – The RBV can become a coherent theory of firm behaviour, if it adopts and can integrate the labour theory of value, associated measures of risk arising from the labour process and mechanisms of accountability. Keywords Resources, Risk management, Labour, Competitive advantage Paper type Research paper 1. Introduction To what extent is strategy framed in accounting terms and what role do accounting numbers and techniques play in setting strategy? In both cases the answer is probably not enough, in view of the potential contribution on offer from accounting generally, and from critical accounting in particular. In recent years, the resource-based view (RBV) of the firm, has achieved widespread dissemination in academic literature and management practice (Acedo et al., 2006). It explains competitive advantage, or delivery of sustained above-normal returns (Peteraf, 1993) or economic profit (Barney, 2001), in terms of firms’ bundles of resources (Amit and Schoemaker, 1993; Rumelt, 1984), which are valuable, rare, inimitable and non-substitutable (VRIN) (Barney, 2001, emphasis added). A theory linking asset value and abnormal returns is therefore Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal The author would like to thank participants at the European Critical Accounting Studies Vol. 23 No. 5, 2010 Conference, University of York, 2006 and the Institute of Chartered Accountants in Scotland, pp. 647-670 q Emerald Group Publishing Limited whose financial support helped develop the ideas in this paper. He would also like to thank Chris 0951-3574 Carter and two anonymous reviewers for their very helpful comments. DOI 10.1108/09513571011054927
  • 3. AAAJ required. Because the RBV literature has placed these issues at the centre of its agenda, 23,5 its neglect of the accounting literature all the more surprising. If the strategy literature has neglected accounting, it is also fair to say that accounting has neglected strategy. Where concerned with valuation, accountants often employ theoretical stances at variance with the Neo-classical mainstream strategy literature (Bryer, 1994, 1999; Macve, 1999; Mouck, 1994; Tinker, 1980, 2004; Toms, 648 2006a, 2009; Toms and Bowman, 2010)[1]. A common approach of critical accounting is to begin with the restrictive assumptions of marginalist Neo-classical economics and argue that they possess logical inconsistencies, for example the tautological approach to asset valuation implied by the Cambridge controversies (Tinker, 1980), privilege interest groups (Tinker et al. 1982), or are not useful because the total social product is either not recognised (Mayston, 1992) or ignored (Milne, 1991), and neglect the social “essence” beneath the surface of market relationships (Tinker, 1984, p. 61, 1980, p. 158). As a consequence, much of the critical accounting literature has abandoned economic discourse, including the Classical and Marxian Schools. With limited exceptions, deductive model building has become unfashionable, even though, as will be demonstrated below, it has the potential to overcome some weaknesses of the Neo-classical School and its accounting applications. As a consequence, there are unresolved questions in accounting and strategy. First, what is the nature of value, and a theoretically consistent measure of sustained competitive advantage (SCA)? Second, can an operationalisable theory of risk be developed for the purposes of managerial decision making? In addressing these questions the paper will advance an agenda for strategy, and accounting. It will address them by developing an integrated theory of value, profit, and risk. In section two the relevant literature is reviewed under three headings. First, the salient features of the RBV are analysed. Second classical theories of value are considered. Finally, the accounting literature is discussed, insofar as it reflects the former two aspects. Section three develops a new conceptual framework, linking profit, value and risk as a basis for a theory of SCA. It will be shown how the labour theory of value (LTV) can be extended to include risk and be used to modify the neo-classical capital asset pricing model (CAPM). It will do so by linking both to the underlying labour process. It will demonstrate how profit and asset value can be consistently linked by cost structures. It will show how value creation of value can be differentiated from the rent. In the fourth section, the implications are discussed, first for accounting theory, with particular reference to the Cambridge controversies, and second by comparison with similar approaches in the strategy literature. A final section draws conclusions. 2. Strategy, value theory and accounting Strategy and the RBV as a theory of value The RBV is an important idea in strategy, because it offers the potential to explain SCA, or the process of delivering long run abnormal returns to shareholders. Such returns can be delivered through accessing resources, including for example by monopoly control, as in the theory of competitive heterogeneity, or the creation of difficult to replicate resources as in the RBV. It follows that the RBV needs a theory of value to be a convincing theory of SCA. As Priem (2001) therefore suggests, the RBV is incomplete because its explanation of value must be imported from outside literatures.
  • 4. Further, as Priem and Butler (2001) propose, the RBV is tautological if the firm’s Value, profit possession of unique capabilities cannot be ascertained independently of their and risk description (Carter et al., 2008). Accounting might break the tautology by providing mechanisms for understanding resource creation, their valuation and reporting. It therefore follows that the measurement of resource value and abnormal returns are necessary components of the development of the RBV as a theory[2]. Of course, this conclusion has not been fully accepted in the strategy literature, 649 which reflects more general disagreement about the RBV’s basic premises (Hoopes et al., 2003). Indeed, participants in the debate have yet to reach a consensus on the circumstances of where, why and when a resource is valuable (Miller and Shamsie, 1996, p. 539). Where recent strategy literature does acknowledge the requirement for a theory of value, it has adopted two quite narrow and largely mutually exclusive perspectives. One strand examines processes within the organization (Denrell et al., 2003), which might be conceptualized in terms of production, transaction and governance costs (Madhok, 2002). Another considers value, price and cost as market interactions (Hoopes et al., 2003), and the market based division of value through bargaining games (Lippman and Rumelt, 2003a, 2003b; MacDonald and Ryall, 2004; see also Brandenburger and Stuart, 1996). In contrast with economic theory, which explains performance differentials in terms of product and market structure, the RBV focuses on the internal characteristics of the firm (Lockett and Thompson, 2001). However, the valuation of RBV assets also implies relationships with a specific market environment (Amit and Schoemaker, 1993). Similarly Barney (1991, p. 105) suggests that a resource is valuable to the extent that “it exploits opportunities and/or neutralizes threats in a firm’s environment”. A connected argument is that resources are valuable if they enable a firm to satisfy needs at lower costs than competitors (Peteraf, 1993). Barney (1991, p. 106) also suggests that resources are valuable “when they enable a firm to conceive of or implement strategies that improve its efficiency and effectiveness”. A resource has been defined as valuable if it enables customer needs to be better satisfied (Bogner and Thomas, 1994; Verdin and Williamson, 1994). How the superior returns that arise from these activities are captured by specific stakeholder groups through accountability processes has not been resolved in the strategy literature. Coff (1999) addresses the question with the notion of “nexus rents”, so that proceeds of superior performance are appropriated by competing stakeholder groups. Although explaining their distribution, rents, and one assumes value, are determined by market processes and do not arise from the productive process, although Coff’s contribution importantly highlights the role of monitoring relationships. Where the stakeholder approach is used, definitions of value are still predicated on notions of utility. For example Collis and Montgomery (1997, pp. 30-1) argue that a resource is valuable when demanded by customers, when it cannot be replicated by competition, and when the profits it generates are captured by the firm (emphasis added). The implied reification does not sit comfortably with a stakeholder approach. However, the principal weakness here is that value depends upon defining customer needs (including, tautologically, access to low priced goods) in utilitarian terms. There is also the more fundamental question of whether utility in any case constitutes the basis for a theory of value. It has been dismissed as a tautology by some prominent economists (Robinson, 1963), and more importantly refuted as a theory of
  • 5. AAAJ capital value and the rate of profit (Harcourt, 1969). Neo-classical economics has 23,5 ignored rather than responded to these fundamental criticisms (Tinker, 1980), and any attempt to develop a resource based theory of the firm on neo-classical foundations necessarily faces the same problem, not least because capital values and profit rates are central to the RBV approach. To summarize these problems, the RBV requires a value theory independent of utility, or must specify a stakeholder group whose utility is to 650 take precedence. Strategic management researchers meanwhile are also interested in developing new risk measures that are theoretically consistent and useful for managerial decision making, achieving a suitable trade-off between concept complexity and computational simplicity (Ruefli et al., 1999, pp. 182-4). So far, this literature has relied on the CAPM, but has merely added to the critique in the finance literature. Bowman (1979) and Armour and Teece (1978) examined the implied CAPM relationship, finding a paradoxical negative slope between risk and return. Feigenbaum and Thomas (1986) and Singh (1986) find differing risk return relationships at different levels of organizational performance and capacity utilisation. These studies typically reflect Neo-classical approaches to modelling risky behaviour, so that they are potentially undermined by the weaknesses of the CAPM highlighted by financial researchers (Clare et al., 1998, Fama and French, 1992, Wang, 2000), and although address expected return, do not offer a theory of value. Summarizing much of the above, Priem (2001) argues that existing theories deal only with the value capture element but do not explain how value is created. For Makadok and Coff (2002) RBV works with value capture, but does not need a theory of value creation, especially not a theory based on consumer utility. Bowman and Ambrosini (2000) suggest conventional explanations of resource value (Makadok, 2001; Makadok and Coff, 2002; Barney, 1986; Peteraf, 1993; Collis and Montgomery, 1995) are insufficient and set out a framework incorporating value creation and value capture. These critics have built on Classical economists’ notion of use value, so that new use value derives from individuals’ actions within the organization (Bowman and Ambrosini, 2000; Bowman and Swart, 2007; Lado and Wilson, 1994; Pfeffer, 1995; Wright et al., 1994). These approaches potentially form the most useful starting point for the more formal integration of the LTV and theories of SCA. Classical value theory In the classical LTV, human action within the productive process is the source of value. Because commodities are systematically sold at higher prices on leaving the productive process in comparison to the prices at which they enter it, there must be some commodity within the process that adds value systematically. Without this condition aggregate profits are zero and the economy is a zero sum game. Further, labour time is priced in the market, but labour time is transferred to the product with a degree of intensity that is a function of physical effort and mental processes, which are not directly observable. Socially necessary labour time is that required to produce any use value under normal conditions of production with the average degree of skill and intensity prevalent in that society (Marx, 1984, p. 641). As far the RBV is concerned, it is not a theory of value, but a theory of rent. These rents are Ricardian (Peteraf, 1993, Teece et al., 1997, p. 513), since Schumpeterian rents (Foss and Knudsen, 2002), as synergies, or economies of scope are imitable, except in
  • 6. the short run (Barney and Peteraf, 2003)[3]. However, none of the RBV literature has Value, profit seriously concerned itself with the nineteenth century literature on rent and associated and risk value theory. Marx modified Ricardo by varying the assumption of a fixed resource supply, and allowing rents to arise as a function of different deployments of capital. He also explained the proportion of profit manifested as rent as a function of the regulating price, as determined socially necessary labour. Rent therefore is regulated by the most efficient (or least efficient) combination of resources and their production 651 cost, depending on prevailing conditions of competition and the order in which resources are brought into use. In other words, Marx’s theory of rent developed Ricardo’s theory in directions of potential use to RBV theorists and accountants concerned with asset valuation and rents. Whether useful or not, Marx’s theory of rent is unlikely to be popular with RBV theorists or mainstream accountants. The same might be said for the LTV, although it is just as easily attributable to Ricardo or Smith, or to classical economy in general. As Grant (1996, p. 112) puts it, “a physiocratic approach”[4], locating value in a single production factor, is essential for a knowledge-based theory of value. Bowman and Toms (2010) introduce the notions of value and surplus value along with the distinctions between use value and exchange value that have already contributed to the RBV conversation (Bowman and Ambrosini, 2000). Following the above definition of socially necessary labour, firms will vary in efficiency and therefore through bankruptcy and innovation, socially necessary labour is reduced to the most efficient firm (Mohun, 1996, p. 504). For these reasons Marx is more specifically useful for the RBV as the notion of socially necessary labour facilitates the determination of rent elements in abnormal profits. Even so, Marx is only a point of departure for the further development of RBV discussed in section 3. Accounting and the RBV There has been limited research on the RBV in the accounting literature. Studies have typically concentrated on testing managerial accounting applications. For example Howorth and Westhead (2003) find that working capital management techniques differ according to the scale and sophistication of the resource base in small firms. In another study, managerial selection of performance measures mediates the relationship between strategic RBV assets and financial performance in non-manufacturing firms (Widener, 2006). Other research has examined the relationship between the management control system (MCS), the creation of capabilities in an RBV sense and performance (Henri, 2006). In general research of this kind has been limited, possibly because as Barney et al. (2001) suggest, the MCS is not a VRIN asset due to its easy transferability[5]. In general, where undertaken by mainstream accounting researchers, RBV research has focused on accounting practice rather than accounting theory. In contrast, critical accounting research has been more directly concerned with these fundamentals. Toms (2002), Hasseldine et al. (2005) develop an integrated framework for RBV intangible asset investment and stock market signalling. Bryer (1999) argues that labour values are the basis of objective asset valuations. Tinker(1999, p. 655) on the other hand suggests that Marx’s economic categories such as profit, wages and rents should be seen as socially relative phenomena. For Abeysekera(2008) accounting measurement is a response to commodification, or the economic logic of maximising the market value of a firm while dealing with the contradiction of use of labour for
  • 7. AAAJ production by the firm. Another strand of critical literature has begun to address the 23,5 relationship between accounting profit, valuation and the competitive process by integrating the propositions of the RBV. Toms (2006b) integrates a knowledge based view of the firm with theories of entrepreneurship, and extends the CAPM to integrate social conceptions of risk (Toms, 2006a). He extends these arguments to show the possible objective valuation measures that might be computed if social and financial 652 risk are appropriately integrated (Toms, 2008, 2009). Bowman and Toms (2010) show how the RBV can be integrated with Marx’s model of the circuits of capital incorporating different classes of labour. These ideas are now extended further to produce a conceptual framework based on a common theory of accounting and competitive advantage. 3. Conceptual framework Theoretical dimensions A theory of accounting and strategy is presented below, linking value theory and accountability, using what for shorthand will be referred to as the Resource Value-Resource Risk (RVRR) perspective. Value, in terms of labour effort transferred to the product, is best observable in the labour process by those most closely involved and the value capture process accordingly becomes progressively less observable (with increased monitoring cost) by those concerned with superintendence of valorization, or realization of use value into monetary value, and surplus appropriation. RVRR is thus concerned with accountability mechanisms, consisting of accounting controls and governance arrangements. There are several additional and important dimensions. First, is the firm’s cost structure, which refers to the degree of cost variability arising from the employment contract. If employee remuneration is not precisely linked to revenue, the expected (risk adjusted) rate of profit includes a rent element. Either revenue will fall and staff costs are paid anyway, in which case there is a “rent” accruing to the workforce (because they have produced less but are paid the same), or revenue will rise and staff costs remain fixed, in which case profit rises above normal as labour’s share in net output falls. Second, if the actions of people within organisations are the source of use values, it is necessary to define such values according to some Minimum Efficient Labour Requirement (MELR), otherwise any additional labour time, no matter how inefficient and regardless of consumer requirement could still be said to create value[6]. MELR specifically refers to the labour costs of the firm with the simplest processes and most easily replicable assets consistent with remaining in the market. It therefore regulates the market price and differential rents are set for other firms with less easily replicable assets according to the benchmark, as is analogous to the illustrations used by Marx (1984, chapters 39 [e.g. table 1], 40). The benchmark MELR firm establishes the underlying expected normal rate of return to shareholders and the discount rate applied in asset valuation. These relationships are developed further below to show that such returns are systematically related to cost structures embedded in the labour process. Third, there is the possibility of “rent” transfer between stakeholder groups. Rent is defined as above, but extended to include circumstances where knowledge is unevenly distributed within firms and between firms and their investors, so that rents accrue to
  • 8. firm insiders or financial market insiders based on access to superior information. By Value, profit extension, where knowledge is unevenly distributed within firms and between firms and risk and their investors, rents accrue to firm insiders or financial market insiders based on access to superior information. Because firm insiders are employees and managers, their realized wage is the MELR rate for the job plus or minus rent elements arising from access to information asymmetries in the production process and contract related cost structures. Conversely, realized returns accruing to shareholders in a financial 653 market reflect both the underlying rate of profit plus or minus realizable managerial and labour rents[7]. Unlike Ricardian rents in the standard RBV, these rents arise from labour processes within organisations and markets that are set in process by capital, and are accordingly consistent with Marx’s second category of differential rent, in which realized rent depends on differential employments of capital. The fourth component is tacit knowledge. Employees hold their positions because the perceived value of their tacit and other knowledge exceeds their market cost[8]. To develop a theory of SCA from a RVRR perspective, it is necessary to establish a basic relationship between individual knowledge, the means whereby it is embedded in the labour process, and subsequent monitoring and valorization. Physical effort and readily quantifiable skills are resources most easily replicable. Such explicit skills are those more easily generated through generic training and education processes external to the firm. As labour processes become more deeply ingrained as tacit skills, they become more difficult to replicate. As the firm invests in assets such as specialized production facilities, trade secrets and engineering experience (Teece et al. 1997) over time (Dierickx and Cool, 1989), tacit knowledge is embedded in technically complex routines[9]. According to the knowledge-based view SCA arises from such routines (Spender, 1989, Nonaka, 1991), but recognition that individuals create the knowledge, which firms can then apply (Grant, 1996) leads in the RVRR to tension between rent appropriation by individuals and team-based profit appropriation as SCA. RVRR places appropriate emphasis on the mental processes, so that senior managers as well as junior staff spend time creating value, specifically where their administrative activities are a necessary condition for productive activity to occur[10]. Productive activity is activity that adds value including service provision, not just factory production. The supervision problem intensifies to the extent that subordinates hold tacit knowledge. Tacit knowledge reflects value in use rather than market exchange value and employees hold their positions precisely because the perceived value of their tacit and other knowledge exceeds their market cost. In RBV terms, the firm that employs such individuals has a basis for SCA because a competing firm cannot replicate the asset base through straightforward market exchange processes. Therefore a fifth component is that, as the labour process is not directly observable, the employer of labour and the capital market investor are exposed to financial risk arising from information asymmetry. Such problems lead to the sixth and final component, which is the process of organizational control and the mix between behaviour and output controls (Ouchi and Maguire, 1975) or action and results controls (Bryer, 2006). The balance shifts from the former to the latter, to the extent that process observation by supervisors is problematic, where accounting controls receive more emphasis in the latter case. Each of these components is integrated in the following framework.
  • 9. AAAJ An integrated model 23,5 Figure 1 uses the Ambrosini and Bowman (2001, p. 816) continuum to include tacit knowledge as a starting point, but extends their analysis to include the additional dimension of task complexity in the labour process, and cost behaviour, monitoring costs, control mechanisms and appropriation in the valorization process. In other words, to consider the relationship between knowledge location and value appropriation as part 654 of a full description of the productive process, set out in Figure 1 as a horizontal continuum of dimensions of value creation through to ultimate value capture. The valorization process comprises four elements: cost behaviour, control, monitoring, and appropriation. Insofar as specific assets associated with SCA are not valued in an external market, and are therefore illiquid and non-realizable, they generate fixed costs rather than variable costs. Similarly hiring knowledge intensive labour generates fixed cost. Therefore as tacit knowledge and the potential degree of SCA rises under RBV assumptions, so does the fixity of cost. As suggested in Figure 1, there is also a continuous relationship between the degree of tacitness and complexity in the labour process and the ability of external stakeholders to monitor the separable labour processes that make up the firm and their joint interactions. This follows from the definition of tacit knowledge, because the process is less readily explainable and understood by an outsider and, consistent with the RBV, tacit knowledge is implicated in SCA. External stakeholders’ two methods of monitoring, behavioural (or action) control and output control, are also implicated in the tacitness and complexity of the labour process, and the extent of fixed production costs and monitoring costs in the valorization process. Tasks that are simple to perform and replicate are more easily Figure 1. The production process, knowledge location and the distribution of surplus
  • 10. controlled through the division of labour and repetition, and more easily flexed in Value, profit response to changes in demand, so there is greater emphasis on action control. Where and risk the process is complex, difficult to observe and dependent on embedded fixed costs, rather than costly monitoring a process that is difficult to understand and unresponsive to changes in demand, output control might be relied upon, so that the producer has to account for actions in financial terms. In the latter case, there is an additional element in the labour process, involving transformation of heterogeneous 655 physical and mental inputs into homogeneous monetary outputs. Following Ouchi and Maguire (1975), behaviour and output controls may not be direct substitutes, but may be observable in independent contexts depending on understanding of means-ends relationships and complex interdependencies respectively. Finally, as far as appropriation is concerned, the more tacit labour processes create assets that are unique and valuable, through processes that generate difficult to monitor fixed costs, the more likely resulting abnormal profit will be appropriated by insiders. Inside appropriation is at the expense of external capital providers or of other participants in joint ventures and consortia. Several corollaries arise from these relationships. First is the conflict between the managerial objective of achieving SCA and the objective of maximizing shareholder value. Managers pursue rents rather than optimal growth (Rugman and Verbeke, 2004) and these rents arise from their role in the labour process, as supervisors and participants. If firms are identified as achieving competitive advantage by reference to accounting ratios showing superior performance from a shareholder perspective (e.g. Peters and Waterman, 1982), such performance is likely based on explicit and easily replicable skills and that associated competitive advantage is short-term or illusory. A second and related point is that monitoring costs in Figure 1 also lie on a continuum suggesting that as the degree of tacitness rises, the probability of surplus appropriation by those closest to the labour process also rises. In other words the monitoring problem is not simply confined to the providers of external capital but is also faced directly by the line managers at each hierarchical level above the labour process. Line managers have the incentive to externalize tacit knowledge embedded in labour processes for which they are responsible, for example through the division of labour, or spend organizational resources themselves on monitoring, so that rents accrue at their level of the hierarchy[11]. Insofar as line management itself is part of the labour process, for example where managerial action alters the product or service delivered, further individually appropriable tacit knowledge arises and monitoring costs are imposed from above on progressively senior levels of management. Ultimately the imposition comes from the capital market to the top of the hierarchy, creating a similar but separate set of monitoring issues discussed below. A third corollary is that under RVRR assumptions the RBV is made consistent with labour process theory (LPT)[12]. Many labour process theorists (e.g. Knights, 1990, Wilmott, 1990) stress the role of power rather than profit and, where applied to the RBV, the role of power in appropriation (Scarborough, 1998). As Nicholls (1999) has pointed out, the valorization stage of the productive process, concerned with transformation of labour use values into realized profit, has been neglected in the labour process literature. Figure 1 suggests an integrated approach, since labour rent originates in the productive process, and a valorization stage is included. In terms of labour time, capital comprises accumulated prior use values plus the labour time, at whatever intensity, transferred
  • 11. AAAJ into output through the labour process. Capital can be conceptualized in labour hours 23,5 without reference to valorization, but the valorization process is nonetheless the crucial link underpinning the relationship between tacit knowledge and monitoring costs. Valorization, under RVRR assumptions, depends on the effectiveness or otherwise of supervisory arrangements to moderate the effects of information asymmetry. Asymmetry arises because employees sell but usually retain some control over the 656 employment of their labour effort, which supervision arrangements are intended to counteract in order to achieve fuller valorization. Therefore the labour process leads to inventiveness on the one hand through the imagination of individual employees and alienation through the process of specialization on the other. In the RVRR extension, to the extent that inventiveness and knowledge can be individually appropriated by employees, the labour process itself becomes a risky set of activities for administering managers and outside financial stakeholders. Arising from these risks, a fourth corollary is their price impact capital markets. If SCA is measured in terms of shareholder returns, then realization through circulation in capital markets is part of the valorization process. At the top end of the continuum where all knowledge is tacit, it is impossible for the investor to understand the processes whereby use values are transformed into exchange values through realization and thereby generated into profits. Even so, where there is some degree of capital dependence (Prechel, 2000), for example in high growth sector firms, insiders will have an incentive to reserve some profit and signal its availability to outside investors instead of appropriating it for themselves. Insofar as the labour process within one firm is unrelated to labour processes governing the average firm’s realization of profits, which include many explicit processes, its variation in profit will appear random. Because the capital market by definition can only value explicit processes, that firm’s apparently random changes in profit corresponds to the firm-specific risk from an investor’s point of view[13]. In the limiting case where all knowledge is tacit, all share prices become random. Under such conditions, following Grossman and Stiglitz (1980), share prices would convey no information to investors. In the opposite case where all knowledge is explicit, information is symmetrical and markets become thin, as there are no abnormal returns (rents) and no incentive to trade (Grossman and Stiglitz, 1980). Also under these conditions with RBV assumptions all firms possess the same easily imitable resources for the same activities and there is no SCA. These intra-firm and firm-financial market interactions provide the possibility of theory of profit determination consistent with notions of SCA and the RVRR. Abstracting from the continua in Figure 1, a model showing the relationship between the labour cost characteristics of tacit knowledge, task complexity, valorization process characteristics, and expected profits required by external investors can be developed. Figure 2 shows the rate of return required by a risk-averse external investor as a function of the fixed cost labour ratio (FCLR). The FCLR is the proportion of fixed cost to total cost for firm i divided by the proportion of fixed cost to total cost for all firms. Some abstraction will assist interpretation of Figure 2. Suppose a firm with a single employee, w, and a single shareholder, s, and that the actions of w can be made totally observable or explicit to s through contractual/legal arrangements so w has no bargaining power. Suppose also that s pays w only for the output actually produced (as opposed to for the time w spends at work). Under these assumptions[14], s is able to appropriate profits from the labour process under risk free conditions. If fairly efficient
  • 12. Value, profit and risk 657 Figure 2. capital markets are also assumed, and other markets are perfect, the expected rate of profit should resemble the rate of return from risk free investment (point A in Figure 2), for example base interest rates[15]. It can also be seen that if these assumptions are gradually relaxed, so that w is able, through the acquisition of bargaining power, to fix wages in the face of varying demand conditions, then the rate of profit required to compensate the investor will rise. Because rate of profit variability increases proportionately to the degree of fixity in wage cost, even where diversified, investors require, and should obtain where capital markets remain reasonably efficient, a proportionate increase in compensation (for the average risk firm, to point B in Figure 2). There is a systematic increase insofar as under conditions of aggregate growth expected change in aggregate demand is positive in which case because wages are fixed, the rate of realized profit rises. An important reason for the positive linear association between fixity of labour cost and shareholder risk is implicit contract theory, in which employees are risk averse (Rosen, 1985). In this model, the capital market absorbs the insurance element of implicit labour contracts through a risk premium. Figure 2 is theoretically consistent with the Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965) CAPM, in that stock return is proportionate to systematic risk. The difference is that the risk source is related to value creation, labour process and value appropriation, rather than mere share price and stock market index co-variation.
  • 13. AAAJ Suppose next that w has tacit knowledge and can conceal value-creating or 23,5 value-destroying activities in the labour process, so that the effort bargain shifts in favour of w and the return to s corresponds to point C in Figure 2. Again, s faces increased risk, but the increase is specific to the labour process and s avoids this risk by incurring monitoring costs or shifting to output control, for example setting a target normal rate of profit based on observable rates elsewhere. These rates reflect, and are 658 reduced by, aggregate monitoring cost. Alternatively, s avoids risk through portfolio diversification, but in doing so reduces capacity further for monitoring performance of any one firm. Purchasers of other shares also run the risk of negative rents through premium prices charged by market makers, benefiting from inside or asymmetric information advantages (point D in Figure 2). In general, points C and D constitute examples of rents arising from non RBV sources, such as monopoly power, information asymmetry and other elements of competitive heterogeneity. The interactions between tacit knowledge and monitoring costs are suggestive of some interesting contradictions within the corporate economy. Alienation, through excessive specialization and associated removal of intellectual content, is traditionally viewed as a source of exploitation by unscrupulous profit maximizers. That said, in industries where such exploitation might occur, such as cotton textiles in the British industrial revolution or in modern China, although aggregate profit rates may be high, there is no basis for SCA at the level of any individual firm[16]. In contrast, where the labour process has significant intellectual content, thereby creating entry barriers for competitors, the accrued profit to individual profit maximizers may be still small and the rents accrued by intermediate producers and market-makers large, due to increased monitoring problems[17]. In short, because rent is the difference between realized price and underlying value, if labour is the source of value, information asymmetry is the source of rent. Interaction between the two tends to equalize the aggregate rate of profit[18]. Figure 3(a) shows a formal decomposition of total observed profits into profit and rent elements. Following Figure 2, there is a risk free profit element, to which is added a labour rent based systematic premium equating to the FLCR. Further rents arise from knowledge-based asymmetries within the production process and as a residual category, from other non-labour based resources. Consistent with the economic theory advanced so far, total observed profit consists of normal profit plus rents. Normal profit, following Figure 2, corresponds to average levels of fixed labour cost, corresponding to point A in Figure 3(a). A firm operating here would be the regulator of market price and the benchmark for differential rents arising at points B and C. To the extent that the individual firm has an above average FLCR, it earns systematically higher rent, which forms the first component of RVRR-based abnormal return. The second component arises from knowledge-based production process asymmetries. SCA associated with the RVRR, consistent with the RBV, is the distance B – A. Further rents, accrued through heterogeneous access to other physical and informational assets (C – B), are not part of an RBV story of SCA, but are consistent with competitive heterogeneity and Ricardian rents. Where such rents are present, they will complement other categories of rent, thereby increasing total observed profit, or will increase profit in the absence of other categories. For the purposes of simplicity expected and realized profit are part of the same total observed surplus in Figure 3(a). In practice, expected and realized profits are in contradiction. Figure 3(b) shows how these interactions, including the consumption of rent by internal stakeholders, explain
  • 14. Value, profit and risk 659 Figure 3. The determinants of sustained competitive advantage and observable profits
  • 15. AAAJ the observed level of profit and when and how observed abnormal profits are 23,5 associated with SCA. Figure 3(b) shows the general case, in which profits and SCA are explained jointly by tacit knowledge VRIN assets in the resource base and the process of surplus appropriation. The framework shows the labour and valorization processes to be in direct and dynamic contradiction. In the top row of the table, consistent with the RBV, firms achieve SCA through their tacit knowledge resources. However, 660 observable profits differ, so that where accountability mechanisms are effective, profits from SCA are above normal and accrue to external stakeholders (quadrant 1). Where accountability mechanisms are ineffective, rents accrue to insiders (quadrant 2). Reported profits are normal, since insiders will report and distribute the level of profit required for minimally satisfying investors and preventing them from exiting their investment. Remaining surplus will be consumed as rents by insiders. On the bottom row, there are no VRIN assets and therefore no basis for SCA. Because there are no VRIN assets, rent appropriation by insiders is also impossible. Profits are therefore normal in both quadrants 3 and 4. In quadrant 4, losses (i.e. less than normal profits) are possible if managers are not well monitored and appropriate rents, but only in the very short-run. Because there are no VRIN knowledge assets, the normal rate of profit is well known and therefore deviations below are easy to police. Insofar as SCA and abnormal profits only occur consistently in quadrant 1, accountability mechanisms contribute to observable competitive advantage. Even here the trade-offs referred to in Figure 1 still apply, so that increased investment in VRIN assets also increases monitoring costs. Therefore abnormal profits and SCA are only concurrent where accountability mechanisms are cost-effective. In short, heterogeneous value creation processes and cost-effective accountability mechanisms are jointly necessary and sufficient conditions for SCA. There are relatively few devices available to outside investors to ensure that their firm operates in quadrant 1. An example might be to recruit outside directors with sufficient independence from the main board but who simultaneously possess the sector-specific expertise required to monitor knowledge based assets. However, in the general case, availability of such directors suggests inter-firm knowledge sharing which is in itself inconsistent with firm-level SCA. A possible solution is ideology, and notions such as “shareholder value maximization”. Arguably, such notions might be more easily shared between outside investors and the firm’s top management. Top management might therefore employ ideology to mitigate apparently selfish utilization of tacit knowledge-based wealth consumption by organizational insiders, consistent with Penrose’s view that firms and their managers are essentially profit-orientated, and that managerial opportunism and the agency problem constitute only a special case (Lockett and Thompson, 2004). However, there is little rational basis for managerial pursuit of abnormal profit, since it derives from a contradictory appeal to the selfish interests of another group, i.e. the shareholders, and because normal rather than abnormal profits are a sufficient basis for the firm’s survival. If ideology by itself is insufficient, the use of trust in limited measure down the hierarchy in combination with ideology based sanctions (Armstrong, 1991) may be necessary to achieve quadrant 1 outcomes. The trade-offs in Figures 1 to 3 explain participants’ behaviour in a dynamic system operating within social and technically determined limits. There is an incentive to invest in knowledge assets insofar as the marginal product is positive net of
  • 16. monitoring costs. Because tacitness can rise to the point of total opacity there is an Value, profit upward limit on the investment level. Similarly there is a downward limit to alienation, and risk since if all processes are explicit, although monitoring costs are zero, individual firms cannot achieve SCA under RBV assumptions[19]. The realized rate of profit for the firm, as an asset bundle, depends on the interaction of these contradictions, but is unrelated to the competence or otherwise of the firm’s management, who, where rational, will appropriate surpluses privately. The rate of surplus accruing to 661 individual employees and managers depends on the possession of knowledge and monitoring cost. 4. Discussion Implications for accounting theory: the Cambridge controversies revisited One of the most important potential implications of the model is for the problem of the valuation of heterogeneous assets, or capital goods (Wicksell, 1934). Conventionally, asset value is the present value of the future cash flows the asset is likely to generate, presupposing a discount rate and therefore a rate of profit[20]. However in the RBV as in neo-classical economics, the rate of profit follows from the possession of valuable (scarce) assets. Wicksell effects and the associated Neo-Ricardian problems of capital reversing and re-switching are important challenges to the RBV, since they imply simultaneous equilibria where firms comprise different combinations of labour and capital at different rates of profit. If either labour or capital is a VRIN asset, the implication is that they are only likely to hold such status within a certain range of profit rates. These issues were raised in the “Cambridge controversies”, but never satisfactorily resolved (Cohen and Harcourt, 2003). An alternative approach is to value capital assets according to cost of production. Wicksell effects also bedevil this approach, because there is a periodic need to revalue the capital stock to reflect price and technology changes. However, from the RVRR perspective, these problems are more tractable, and capitalization rates can be derived from the internal contractual structure of the firm. As Figure 2 shows, the risk adjusted required rate of return is a linear function of embedded fixed labour cost. Figure 2 is also generalizable from labour to other classes of cost, using the same fixity of cost approach[21]. Moreover, corporate boards can impose these expected returns on business units using output controls. Although problems of asymmetric information, possession of tacit knowledge and monitoring costs impact on individual valuations, the associated risks are diversifiable by investors and have no systematic impact on expected returns or required capitalization rates. In general therefore, rational valuations for heterogeneous assets, for example RBV style intangibles, can be arrived at by examining the underlying social relationships and associated cost structure within the firm. Implications for strategic management Such a focus also addresses the need for theoretically consistent risk measures identified in the earlier review of the strategy literature. Also, the RRVR approach to some extent parallels Madhok’s (2002) response to Williamson’s (1991) call for an integrated approach, albeit without the restrictions imposed by the reification of the firm and absence of shareholder-based governance mechanisms that tend to occur in such transaction cost RBV analyses. In reality, because outside shareholders can only
  • 17. AAAJ apply output controls to top management, they must rely on accounting 23,5 representations of results, leaving top management, crucially, in control of the process of transformation of heterogeneous capital resource into homogeneous cash flow equivalent representations. Therefore top management also have the ability to promote internal reinvestment of profits from innovation into perquisites at the expense of dividend payments to shareholders. Also the way in which the firm’s 662 managerial hierarchy exercises surveillance is potentially important, through access control or incentivization, respectively examples of action and output controls. There are other similarities between RVRR and Denrell et al. (2003), who assume that all stage transformations through intermediate to finished products require only labour cost and that labour is undifferentiated. They also assume that all prices are in present value terms. It follows that the discount rate, or more precisely, the risk-adjusted rate of profit, is presupposed. If it is necessary to assume wage rates, prices and profit rates a priori, in a model with two factors of production, labour and capital, it is difficult to see how this model rigorously adds to the theory of value. The Lippman and Rumelt (hereafter L&R) bargaining and payments perspectives also have similarities to the RVRR approach. Unlike RVRR, however, the L&R approach lacks an underlying theory of value creation. The bargaining approach assumes a surplus (Lippman and Rumelt, 2003b, p. 1071, emphasis added). Alternatively for the payments perspective, (Lippman and Rumelt, 2003a) economic profit is set at zero, presumably for all firms in aggregate, implying differences in price and cost sum to zero, or revenues 8 payments. At the aggregate level, these are merely wealth transfers. In contrast, RVRR offers an explanation as to why on aggregate the value of purchased outputs is systematically higher than purchased inputs. According to Lippman and Rumelt (2003b), value distribution depends on the structure of a bargaining game. A condition is that the game should have a core[22] otherwise the participants lack the incentive to work together for a co-operatively beneficial outcome. Where an innovative employee possesses tacit knowledge, it is unlikely that person will enter the game unless the firm’s incentive structure is such that the employee will appropriate a significant share of revenues. Where ex ante contracts of employment specify the ownership and rewards from innovation as proprietary to the firm, these incentives will not exist. Assets that achieve this, such as proprietary technology and large fixed asset bases, restrict access from the employees’ point of view and prevent them setting up a competing firm. At the same time, they ensure inequality in bilateral bargaining gains, encouraging indirect rent appropriation. The appropriation process in this case, outlined in the RVRR, arises from non co-operation by the innovative employee and imperfect surveillance of effort by the employer, so that rent arising from innovation and greater efficiency is appropriated by firm insiders through equivalent shirking. An alternative contractual arrangement, which gives the employee incentive to share information, places a core in the game, but with the risk that the employee appropriates some monetary benefit. A further problematic aspect of Lippman and Rumelt’s (2003a, p. 924) analysis is their concluding objective function, that the firm should maximize its wealth and that competition will induce it to maximize payments for scarce resources (PSR). PSR is a residual category, once payments of commodity inputs (PCI) and payments for commodity resources (PCR) have been accounted for. Because the other two categories are defined as commodities, they are also defined to be in perfectly elastic supply. If
  • 18. Revenue ¼ PCI þ PCR þ PSR and the firm is a price taker in two out of the three Value, profit categories, then changes in PSR can only be explained with reference to themselves, and risk which removes any analytic properties from the identity. If on the other hand, perfect competition is as defined by Makowski and Ostroy (1995) and Lippman and Rumelt (2003b, p. 1071), as a condition in which individuals fully appropriate the value they create, then market imperfection implies transfer of surplus through rent (per classical theory) rather than value. It also follows that if individuals do not fully appropriate the 663 value they create in a market relation other than in perfect competition, this will also be the case in an employment relation. RVRR, which includes labour rents, does better than Classical theory and the sections of the RBV literature that ignore the creation of value through human action. The value price cost (VPC) framework approach differentiates between value, defined as the price the customer is willing to pay; price, which is a function of supply and demand; and cost, which is the cost of production. The framework assumes V . P . C, which is likely to be true when individual cases of competitive advantage are considered, and competitive advantage might arise in individual cases of V . P and P . C (Hoopes et al., 2003). However, in the aggregate V ¼ P ¼ C, otherwise it is not clear why customers would systematically value all products and services above their cost of production. The equality of VPC in the aggregate is also consistent with the payments perspective (Lippman and Rumelt, 2003a), but inconsistent with an underlying theory of value creation. If V is systematically higher than C in the aggregate in price terms, then firms must be acquiring a resource for a price below its cost. The only resource all firms share common access to is human resource. As we have seen, it is this resource in particular that not only creates value through intellectual and physical effort, but such effort is also problematic to measure and observe, unlike the costs of other inputs. In similar fashion to the VPC approach, MacDonald and Ryall (2004) attempt to show that value arises from the presence of a willing buyer. In the case presented (MacDonald and Ryall, 2004, p. 1321), the cost of production is normalized to zero and the buyer’s utility is set at 1. To presuppose utility at a level greater than the cost of production, is however, non-generalizable, since without equivalent payments to production factors utility cannot constitute effective demand. If the case is merely specific then the bargaining game is a question of rent sharing between firm and buyer, rather than value creation. Consistent with M&R, the appropriation of value depends on the number of firms and buyers. As in many interpretations that analyse at the level of the firm, there is reification and no consideration of rent splits within the organization. As with L&R, the M&R analysis could be extended to include the employment relation, so that bargaining is represented as an interaction between employee and employer as a buyer of labour. 5. Conclusion A common theory of value for accounting and strategy is appealing for a number of reasons. First, the strategy literature, and especially the RBV, places emphasis on the role of human capital in the creation of competitive advantage, which at the same time poses problems for accountants in terms of total business and intangible asset valuation. Second, both disciplines have an interest in understanding the meaning of normal profit and its adjustment for risk where it impacts on performance or
  • 19. AAAJ investment decisions. Third, both disciplines are interested in how, once made, profits are appropriated. A situation where a firm is more efficient than competitors, but 23,5 whose surplus is appropriated by insiders rather than distributed to shareholders would not necessarily meet the strategists’ understanding of SCA. Accountants similarly are concerned with controls which prevent misappropriation of resources that ultimately are shareholders’ property. Thus, a theory of value also needs to be one 664 of accountability. Accordingly, the theory developed above has attempted to integrate these elements to the mutual benefit of accounting and strategy. The contribution of the paper is a theory of SCA, asset valuation and accountability using a consistent theory of value. The argument above has accepted the main assumptions of the RBV. It has also argued for the inclusion of labour process theory, asymmetric information, extension of Ricardian rent using Marx’s two categories of differential rent, and the analysis of risk, in the proposed RVRR. The combination of these elements shows that a resource-based theory must unite the process and content elements of strategy, through simultaneous interaction of labour management, the determinants of SCA and relations with capital markets. It has shown that by utilising the RVRR as a substitute for the CAPM, so that the employment of human resource creates value, but the value creation process is itself risky from the perspective of the monitoring employer and outside investor, a consistent theory of value can be applied to explain SCA. The theory also explains that the roots of competitive advantage lie in the labour process, but with the corollary that maximizing the associated investment in tacit knowledge and associated difficult to replicate assets is potentially inconsistent with maximizing the value of shareholder’s investments. Without the links, advocated above, to LTV, labour process theory and mechanisms of accountability, the RBV remains merely a view and not a theory, because it lacks a consistent basis for asset valuation and cannot explain systematic variations in profit. Notes 1. In similar vein, the RBV had been neglected in the industrial economics literature (Lockett and Thompson, 2001). 2. Without measurement, the RBV might still operate, but only as a heuristic, or a means of understanding an organization as a knowledge system, such that the link with “value” is tangential, and not as a theory of SCA. 3. Ricardian differential rent is “the difference between the produce obtained by the employment of two equal quantities of labour and capital” (Marx, 1984, p. 649). 4. Such allusions to Classical theories of economics are rare in the strategic management literature notwithstanding the obvious parallels with the LTV and Ricardian rents. LTV, as the cornerstone of Classical economics (Mouck, 1994) has been discussed extensively in the accounting literature (for example Bryer, 1994, 2007; Toms, 2006a). 5. Henri(2006, p.539) suggests that the performance measurement system (PMS) does create RBV capabilities. 6. This definition goes beyond the debate in the accounting literature about how Marx’s socially necessary labour time might be in an accounting context (Bryer, 1999; Macve, 1999). 7. Labour rents accrue to employees (and managers) where the wage rate exceeds the MELR. Where employees possess knowledge that is not easily replicable, particularly when routinized within the organization, possession of such knowledge provides workers with
  • 20. opportunities to raise real wages, if they can avoid accountability and appropriate the Value, profit efficiency benefits (c/f efficiency wage theories, Katz, 1987). and risk 8. This is an oversimplification for the purposes of model development. It extends reasoning that stakeholders earn quasi-rents when a factor has a higher marginal product than is required to hold it in place (Klein et al., 1978). 9. Investment in strategic human resource assets (Mueller, 1996; Wright et al., 1994) is a sufficient but not a necessary condition for realized super-normal profits, since the 665 employment of such assets simultaneously leads to the creation of internal rent appropriation possibilities. 10. As seniority increases managers may find more of their time allocated to non-productive monitoring activities. 11. Although there is an incentive, it is doubtful whether full externalisation is possible. Using Dewey’s notion of productive enquiry, Cook and Seely Brown (1999, p. 391) argue that possessed knowledge, whether individual or group, is a set of tools to guide action. Within organisations, genres, such as mission statements, are used (or misused) to communicate tacit knowledge in groups. Following this logic accounting controls must monitor how individuals and groups use knowledge. 12. RBV and LPT are from divergent backgrounds within the strategic management literature, reflecting context and process based approaches respectively. 13. Under the normal semi-strong market efficiency assumptions employed by capital market researchers and for which there is the most empirical evidence (Fama, 1991), explicit processes are public domain information and their value potential can accordingly be priced by the market. Tacit elements cannot be known and cannot be priced by reference to generic economy wide factors systematically affecting all firms and therefore appear as residual or unexplained risk in the empirical form of the CAPM. 14. It is assumed that labour is the only cost and that there is a single period capital turnover (ie all the assets purchased at the beginning of the period are used up by the end of the period). These assumptions are for brevity, but the model is generalizable when they are relaxed. 15. Because labour cost co-varies perfectly with revenue, the residual, profit, is a fixed ratio of revenue. 16. Assuming unlimited product imitation, as a form of Bertrand competition, MacDonald and Ryall (2004) reach a similar conclusion. 17. For example where abnormal returns from insider stock purchases rise as the firm’s R&D intensity increases (Coff and Lee, 2003). 18. The lack of a consistent theory of profit equalization has been a long-running problem for classical economics. In RVRR, differential risky profit rates arise in the productive process and are equalized through the capital market. 19. Or more precisely, removing the reification, individual capitalists or investors cannot make abnormal returns. 20. Tinker (2004, p. 458) points out that Sraffa’s critique built on the final works of Ricardo to expose this circular reasoning behind Neo-classical value theory. 21. See Modigliani and Miller’s (1958) example utilizing interest costs. 22. The core is defined as the set of pay-offs that ensure the sub-set of pay-offs to any sub-set of players is greater than the maximum value available to that group working on its own (Lippman and Rumelt, 2003b, p. 1072).
  • 21. AAAJ References 23,5 Abeysekera, I. (2008), “Intellectual capital practices of firms and the commodification of labour”, Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 36-48. Acedo, F.J., Barroso, C. and Galan, J.M. (2006), “The resource-based theory: dissemination and main trends”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 27 No. 7, pp. 621-36. Ambrosini, V. and Bowman, C. (2001), “Tacit knowledge: some suggestions for 666 operationalization”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 38 No. 6, pp. 811-29. Amit, R. and Shoemaker, P.J.H. (1993), “Strategic assets and organizational rents”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 14 No. 1, pp. 33-46. Armour, H.O. and Teece, D.J. (1978), “Organization structure and economic performance: a test of the multidivisional hypothesis”, Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 106-22. Armstrong, P. (1991), “Contradiction and social dynamics in the capitalist agency relationship”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 16 No. 1, pp. 1-25. Barney, J.B. (1986), “Strategic factor markets: expectations, luck and business strategy”, Management Science, Vol. 32 No. 10, pp. 1231-41. Barney, J.B. (1991), “Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage”, Journal of Management, Vol. 17, pp. 99-120. Barney, J.B. (2001), Gaining and Sustaining Competitive Advantage, 2nd ed., Addison-Wesley, Boston, MA. Barney, J.B. and Peteraf, M. (2003), “Unravelling the resource-based tangle”, Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 24 No. 4, pp. 309-23. Barney, J.B., Wright, M. and Ketchen, D.J. (2001), “The resource-based view of the firm: ten years after 1991”, Journal of Management, Vol. 27 No. 6, pp. 625-41. Bogner, W.C. and Thomas, H.H. (1994), “Core competence and competitive advantage: a model and illustrative evidence from the pharmaceutical industry”, in Hamel, G. and Heene, A. (Eds), Competence-based Competition, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, pp. 111-44. Bowman, C. and Ambrosini, V. (2000), “Value creation versus value capture: towards a coherent definition of value in strategy”, British Journal of Management, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 1-15. Bowman, R.G. (1979), “The theoretical relationship between systematic risk and financial (accounting) variables”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 34 No. 3, pp. 617-30. Bowman, C. and Swart, J. (2007), “Whose human capital? The challenge of value capture when capital is embedded”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 44 No. 4, pp. 488-505. Bowman, C. and Toms, S. (2010), “Accounting for competitive advantage: the resource-based view of the firm and the labour theory of value”, Critical Perspectives in Accounting, Vol. 21 No. 3, pp. 183-94. Brandenburger, Z. and Stuart, G. (1996), “Value-based business strategy”, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, Vol. 5 No. 1, pp. 5-24. Bryer, R.A. (1994), “Why Marx’s labour theory is superior to the marginalist theory of value: the case from modern financial reporting”, Critical Perspectives on Accounting., Vol. 5 No. 4, pp. 313-40. Bryer, R.A. (1999), “A Marxist critique of the FASB’s conceptual framework”, Critical Perspectives on Accounting, Vol. 10 No. 5, pp. 551-89. Bryer, R.A. (2006), “Accounting and control of the labour process”, Critical Perspectives on Accounting, Vol. 17 No. 5, pp. 551-98. Bryer, R. (2007), “Marx’s accounting solutions to the ‘transformation problem’”, unpublished working paper, Warwick Business School, Coventry. Carter, C., Clegg, S. and Kornberger, M. (2008), “Strategy as practice?”, Strategic Organization, Vol. 6 No. 1, pp. 83-99.
  • 22. Clare, A.D., Priestley, R. and Thomas, S.H. (1998), “Reports of beta’s death are premature: Value, profit evidence from the UK”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 22 No. 9, pp. 1207-29. Coff, R.W. (1999), “When competitive advantage doesn’t lead to performance: the resource-based and risk view and stakeholder bargaining power”, Organization Science, Vol. 10 No. 2, pp. 119-33. Coff, R. and Lee, P. (2003), “Insider trading as a vehicle to appropriate rent from R&D”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 24 No. 2, pp. 183-90. Cohen, A.J. and Harcourt, G.C. (2003), “Whatever happened to the Cambridge capital theory 667 controversies?”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 199-214. Collis, D.J. and Montgomery, C.A. (1995), “Competing on resources: strategy in the 1990s”, Harvard Business Review., Vol. 73 No. 4, pp. 118-29. Collis, D.J. and Montgomery, C.A. (1997), Corporate Strategy: Resources and the Scope of the Firm, McGraw-Hill, Chicago, IL. Cook, S.D.N. and Seely Brown, J. (1999), “Bridging epistemologies: the generative dance, between organizational knowledge and organizational knowing”, Organization Science, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 381-400. Denrell, J., Fang, C. and Winter, S.G. (2003), “The economics of strategic opportunity”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 24 No. 10, pp. 977-90. Dierickx, I. and Cool, K. (1989), “Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage”, Management Science, Vol. 35 No. 12, pp. 1504-11. Fama, E. (1991), “Efficient markets II”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 46 No. 5, pp. 1575-617. Fama, E.F. and French, K.R. (1992), “The cross-section of expected stock returns”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 47 No. 2, pp. 427-65. Feigenbaum, A. and Thomas, H. (1986), “Dynamic and risk measurement perspectives on Bowman’s risk-return paradox for strategic management: an empirical study”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 7 No. 5, pp. 395-407. Foss, N.J. and Knudsen, T. (2002), “The resource-based tangle: towards a sustainable explanation of competitive advantage”, Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 24 No. 4, pp. 291-307. Grant, R.M. (1996), “Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 17, special issue, pp. 109-22. Grossman, S. and Stiglitz, J. (1980), “On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets”, American Economic Review, Vol. 70 No. 3, pp. 393-408. Harcourt, G.C. (1969), “Some Cambridge controversies in the theory of capital”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 7 No. 2, pp. 369-405. Hasseldine, J., Salama, A. and Toms, S. (2005), “Quantity versus quality: the impact of environmental disclosures on the reputations of UK plcs”, British Accounting Review, Vol. 37 No. 2, pp. 231-48. Henri, J.F. (2006), “Management control systems and strategy: a resource-based perspective”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 31 No. 6, pp. 529-58. Hoopes, D.G., Madsen, T.L. and Walker, G. (2003), “Why is there a resource-based view? Toward a theory of competitive heterogeneity”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 24 No. 10, pp. 889-902. Howorth, C. and Westhead, P. (2003), “The focus of working capital management in UK small firms”, Management Accounting Research, Vol. 14 No. 2, pp. 94-111. Katz, L. (1987), “Efficiency wage theories: a partial evaluation”, in Fischer, S. (Ed.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 235-75. Klein, B., Crawford, R.G. and Alchian, A.A. (1978), “Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process”, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 297-326.
  • 23. AAAJ Knights, D. (1990), “Subjectivity, power and the labour process”, in Knights, D. and Wilmott, H. (Eds), Labour Process Theory, Macmillan, London. 23,5 Lado, A.A. and Wilson, M.C. (1994), “Human resource systems and sustained competitive advantage”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 19 No. 4, pp. 699-727. Lintner, J. (1965), “The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47 No. 1, pp. 13-37. 668 Lippman, S.A. and Rumelt, R.P. (2003a), “A bargaining perspective on resource advantage”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 24 No. 11, pp. 1069-86. Lippman, S.A. and Rumelt, R.P. (2003b), “The payments perspective: micro-foundations of resource analysis”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 24 No. 10, pp. 903-27. Lockett, A. and Thompson, R.S. (2001), “The resource-based view and economics”, Journal of Management, Vol. 27 No. 6, pp. 723-54. Lockett, A. and Thompson, R.S. (2004), “Edith Penrose’s contributions to the resource-based view: an alternative perspective”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 41 No. 1, pp. 193-204. MacDonald, G. and Ryall, M.D. (2004), “How do value creation and competition determine whether a firm appropriates value?”, Management Science, Vol. 50 No. 10, pp. 1319-33. Macve, R. (1999), “Capital and financial accounting: a commentary on Bryer’s ‘A Marxist critique of the FASB’s conceptual framework’”, Critical Perpectives on Accounting, Vol. 11 No. 5, pp. 591-613. Madhok, A. (2002), “Reassessing the fundamentals and beyond: Ronald Coase, the transaction cost and resource-based theories of the firm and the institutional structure of production”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 23 No. 6, pp. 535-50. Makadok, R. (2001), “Toward a synthesis of the resource-based and dynamic capability views of rent creation”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 22 No. 5, pp. 387-401. Makadok, R. and Coff, R. (2002), “The theory of value and the value of theory: breaking new ground versus reinventing the wheel”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 27 No. 1, pp. 10-13. Makowski, L. and Ostroy, J.M. (1995), “Appropriation and efficiency: a revision of the first theorem of welfare economics”, American Economic Review, Vol. 85 No. 4, pp. 808-27. Marx, K. (1984), Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, III, Lawrence & Wishart, London. Mayston, D. (1992), “Capital accounting, user needs and the foundations of a conceptual framework for public sector financial reporting”, Financial Accountability & Management, Vol. 84 No. 4, pp. 227-48. Miller, D. and Shamsie, J. (1996), “The resource-based view of the firm in two environments: the Hollywood film studios from 1936 to 1965”, Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 39 No. 3, pp. 519-43. Milne, M. (1991), “Accounting, environmental resource values and non-market valuation techniques for environmental resources: a review”, Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, Vol. 4 No. 3, pp. 81-109. Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (1958), “The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment”, American Economic Review, Vol. 48 No. 3, pp. 261-97. Mohun, S. (1996), “Socially necessary labour”, in Bottomore, T. (Ed.), A Dictionary of Marxist Thought, Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 503-4. Mouck, T. (1994), “Corporate accountability and Rorty’s Utopian liberalism”, Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, Vol. 7 No. 1, pp. 6-30. Mueller, F. (1996), “Human resources as strategic assets: an evolutionary resource-based theory”, Journal of Management Studies., Vol. 33 No. 6, pp. 757-86.
  • 24. Nicholls, T. (1999), “Industrial sociology and the labour process”, in Beynon, H. and Glavinis, P. Value, profit (Eds), Patterns of Social Inequality: Essays for Richard Brown, Longman, London. Nonaka, I. (1991), “The knowledge-creating company”, Harvard Business Review., Vol. 69, and risk pp. 96-104. Ouchi, W.G. and Maguire, M.A. (1975), “Organizational control: two functions”, Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 20 No. 4, pp. 559-69. Peteraf, M.A. (1993), “The corner-stone of competitive advantage: a resource-based view”, 669 Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 14 No. 3, pp. 179-91. Peters, T.J. and Waterman, R.H. (1982), In Search of Excellence: Lessons from America’s Best-run Companies, Harper & Row, New York, NY. Pfeffer, J. (1995), “Producing sustainable competitive advantage through the effective management of people”, Academy of Management Executive, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 55-69. Prechel, H. (2000), Big Business and the State: Historical Transitions and Corporate Transformations, 1880s-1990s, SUNY Press, New York, NY. Priem, R.L. (2001), “The business-level RBV: Great Wall or Berlin wall?”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 26 No. 4, pp. 499-501. Priem, R.L. and Butler, J.E. (2001), “Is the resource-based ‘view’ a useful perspective for strategic management research?”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 26 No. 1, pp. 22-40. Robinson, J. (1963), Economic Philosophy, Penguin, London. Rosen, S. (1985), “Implicit contracts: a survey”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 23, pp. 1144-75. Ruefli, T., Collins, J.M. and LaCugna, J.R. (1999), “Risk measurement in strategic management research: Auld lang syne?”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 20 No. 2, pp. 167-94. Rugman, A.M. and Verbeke, A. (2004), “A final word on Edith Penrose”, Journal of Management Studies., Vol. 41 No. 1, pp. 205-17. Rumelt, R. (1984), “Toward a strategic theory of the firm”, in Lamb, R. (Ed.), Competitive Strategic Management, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, pp. 556-70. Scarborough, H. (1998), “Path(ological) dependency? Core competencies from an organizational perspective”, British Journal of Management, Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 219-32. Sharpe, W.F. (1964), “Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 425-42. Singh, J.V. (1986), “Performance, slack, and risk taking in organizational decision making”, Academy of Management, Vol. 29 No. 3, pp. 562-85. Spender, J-C. (1989), Industry Recipes: The Nature and Sources of Managerial Judgement, Blackwell, Oxford. Teece, D., Pisano, G. and Sheun, A. (1997), “Dynamic capabilities and strategic management”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 18 No. 7, pp. 509-33. Tinker, A. (1980), “Towards a political economy of accounting: an empirical illustration of the Cambridge controversies”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 5 No. 1, pp. 147-60. Tinker, A. (1984), “Theories of the state and the state of accounting: economic reductionism and political voluntarism in accounting regulation theory”, Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, Vol. 3 No. 1, pp. 55-74. Tinker, T. (1999), “Mickey Marxism rides again!”, Critical Perspectives on Accounting, Vol. 10 No. 5, pp. 643-70. Tinker, T. (2004), “The enlightenment and its discontents: antinomies of Christianity, Islam and the calculative sciences”, Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, Vol. 17 No. 3, pp. 442-75.
  • 25. AAAJ Tinker, A., Merino, B. and Neimark, M. (1982), “The normative origins of positive theories: ideology and accounting thought”, Accounting, Organizations and Society, Vol. 7 No. 2, 23,5 pp. 176-200. Toms, S. (2002), “Firm resources, quality signals and the determinants of corporate environmental reputation: some UK evidence”, British Accounting Review, Vol. 34 No. 2, pp. 257-82. Toms, S. (2006a), “Asset pricing models, the labour theory of value and their implications for 670 accounting”, Critical Perspectives on Accounting, Vol. 17 No. 7, pp. 947-65. Toms, S. (2006b), “Accounting for entrepreneurship: a knowledge-based view of the firm”, Critical Perspectives in Accounting, Vol. 17 Nos 2/3, pp. 336-57. Toms, S. (2008), “‘Immeasurability’: a critique of Hardt and Negri, ephemera”, Theory & Politics in Organization, Vol. 8 No. 4, pp. 433-46. Toms, S. (2009), “The labour theory of value, risk and the rate of profit”, Critical Perspectives in Accounting, in press. Toms, S. and Bowman, C. (2010), “Accounting for competitive advantage: the resource-based view of the firm and the labour theory of value”, Critical Perspectives in Accounting (forthcoming). Verdin, P.J. and Williamson, P.J. (1994), “Core competences, competitive advantage and market analysis: forging the links”, in Hamel, G. and Heene, A. (Eds), Competence-based Competition, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, pp. 77-110. Wang, X. (2000), “Size effect, book-to-market effect, and survival”, Journal of Multinational Financial Management, Vol. 10 Nos 3/4, pp. 257-73. Wicksell, K. (1934), Lectures on Political Economy, Vol. 1, Routledge, London. Widener, S. (2006), “Associations between strategic resource importance and performance measure use: the impact on firm performance”, Management Accounting Research, Vol. 17 No. 4, pp. 433-57. Williamson, O. (1991), “Strategizing, economizing, and economic organization”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 12, special issue, pp. 75-94. Wilmott, H. (1990), “Subjectivity and the dialectics of praxis: opening up the core of the labour process analysis”, in Knights, D. and Wilmott, H. (Eds), Labour Process Theory, Macmillan, London. Wright, P.M., McMahan, G.C. and McWilliams, A. (1994), “Human resources and sustained competitive advantage: a resource-based perspective”, International Journal of Human Resource Management, Vol. 5 No. 2, pp. 301-26. About the author Steven Toms is Professor of Accounting and Finance at the University of York, UK. He is the inaugural Head of the York Management School and, with John Wilson, is Co-editor of Business History. Steven Toms can be contacted at: st27@york.ac.uk To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: reprints@emeraldinsight.com Or visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints