A Principle Governing The Success Of Populations.

Professional Writing Service http://StudyHub.vip/A-Principle-Governing-The-Success-Of-Po 👈

Principle p. 1
March 27, 2010
A principle governing the success of populations.
Marvin Chester
chester@physics.ucla.edu
Physics Department, University of California, Los Angeles
Keywords: population dynamics; evolution; ecology; eco-evolutionary
dynamics; population evolution; evolution theory; ecological development;
exponential growth; Verhulst equation; rK theory
Abstract:
The effect of a population's success on the environment is to
alter that environment so that it opposes the success. It is
proposed that this is the principle of nature that governs
population dynamics among living organisms. We cast this
principle in mathematical form so as to make it amenable to
quantitative comparison with empirical data. It is thus exposed
to refutation or validation. A second order differential equation
for population dynamics is deduced. One of its solutions is
compared to empirical data. Another solution generates a
prediction on possible population histories. Some unexpected
implications of the differential equation are explored. For
example, that population histories may exhibit oscillations even
under a steady, non-oscillatory environmental driving force.
The equation also offers insight into why the phenomenon of
'extinction debt' should exist and suggests a way to predict the
relaxation time for delayed extinction.
Principle p. 2
1. Historical Perspective
The acknowledged source of theories about population is the monograph by
the venerable Thomas Malthus. (Malthus 1798) His place in history rests
largely on these two sentences from page 4,
“Population, when unchecked, increases in a
geometrical ratio. Subsistence increases only
in an arithmetical ratio.”
The archaic terms ‘geometric ratio increase’ and ‘arithmetic ratio increase’
are today called ‘exponential growth’ and ‘linear growth’. In this quote he
takes pains to distinguish these because his thesis is based on the
distinction. Malthus was thinking only of human population. Darwin (Darwin
1859) took the idea to apply to populations in “the whole animal and
vegetable kingdoms.”
There is something profoundly fundamental about exponential growth. In
living systems growth is proportional to the population. The reason is that
each member (or pair of members) once produced, begin, themselves, to
reproduce. There are more reproducers in a larger population. So the
greater the number in the population, the greater the growth is. The same
for deaths. The rate is proportional to the number available to die.
Malthus didn’t offer equations to express these thoughts but it’s instructive
do so. Call the number of members in the population, n. At each moment of
time, t, there exist n individuals in the population. So we expect that n=n(t)
is a continuous function of time. We restrict ourselves to n=large>>1 so that
its integer nature is not pertinent to computations.
Principle p. 3
The rate of growth of the population is dn/dt; the increase in the number of
members per unit time. That this is proportional to population number, n, is
the substance of the idea. Call the constant of proportionality, R. Then the
differential equation that embodies the idea of ‘increase by geometrical ratio’
is:
dn / dt = Rn (1.1)
And, R being constant, its solution yields the archetypical equation of
exponential growth.
n(t) = n0
eRt
(1.2)
The n0 is simply the starting population, n0=n(0); the number of its
members at t=0.
Again taking R as a constant and n0 as defined above, linear growth is
expressed by this equation:
n(t) = n0
(1+ Rt) (1.3)
These formulas for n(t) exhibit starkly different behaviors. That is why they
were contrasted by Malthus.
Of course, common experience tells us that exponential growth cannot
proceed indefinitely. No population grows without end. Suppose the birth
rate declines. Maybe, instead, the death rate increases. Perhaps because the
weather got cold or food became scarce. Then this is accounted for by a new
exponent, say R’; a smaller one. So R is no longer viewed as being constant.
It may vary with time. R = R(t).
Principle p. 4
In describing living systems the idea has been to retain that fundamental
exponential-like form and seek to explain events by variations in R. “The
problem of explaining and predicting the dynamics of any particular
population boils down to defining how R deviates from the expectation of
uniform growth”. (Berryman 2003) The concept is that exponential growth is
always taking place but at a rate that varies with time. Put mathematically:
1
n
dn
dt
= R(t) (1.4)
Fisher endows R with its own name, the Malthusian Parameter. (Fisher
1930) Equation(1.4) is called Darwinian Dynamics by Michod. (Michod 1999)
In connection with his writing on genotype fitness Michod’s “Fisherian
Fitness” is exactly of this form. Equation (1.4) is a powerful analytical tool
for assessing population data.
Of course, any theory on how R might depend on n – rather than on t -
produces a theoretical R(t). This is because the differential equation:
dn
dt
= nR(n) (1.5)
is completely solvable for n as a function of t. Once we have n(t) we can
deduce R(t) via it’s definition in equation (1.4). This theoretical R(t) may be
compared to measurements of (1/n)dn/dt so as to assess whether the
theory is verified.
An object example of this process is provided by the celebrated Verhulst
equation.
dn
dt
= nR(n) = nr(1!
n
K
) (1.6)
Principle p. 5
A population history, n vs. t, resulting from this equation is the black one of
Figure 1.
What motivated Verhulst (Verhulst 1838) is the common observation that
nothing grows indefinitely. Here the constant, r, is the exponential growth
factor and K is the limiting value that n can have - “the carrying capacity of
the environment”.(Vainstein et al. 2007) The equation insures that n never
gets larger than nMAX = K. Because n is understood to be the number in a
given physical space it represents, in fact, a population density
(number/space). That this density has a limit is the reason for the
association of K with crowding. The name, r/K Selection Theory, derives
from the competing dynamics of exponential growth and of crowding – the r
and the K. The Verhulst equation is often embedded in research studies.
(Nowak 2006; Torres et al. 2009; Jones 1976; Ruokolainen et al. 2009;
Okada et al. 2005)
2. Limitations of the Structure
This very useful and appealing structure has some limitations.
Assigning all behavior to variations in R seems to preserve the pristine
Malthusian exponential growth idea. But, in fact, allowing R to vary with time
severs the connection to exponential growth.
The idea is dramatized in this example. Malthus makes it clear that if a
population is growing exponentially with time then it is certainly not growing
linearly with time. Linear growth is the antithesis of exponential growth.
Equations (1.2) and (1.3) display the difference. But suppose R varies as
R(n) = C/n. Using this in solving the Malthusian Equation, (1.5), produces
Principle p. 6
exactly linear growth! The constant C is n0r. Linear growth is variable-rate
exponential growth!
There is no more content in conjectures about R(t) than there is in
theorizing directly about how n might depend on t; n = n(t). The theory
offered in following sections is concerned with n(t) directly, rather than with
R(t).
Another limitation concerns extinction. A phenomenon well known to exist in
nature is the extinction of a species. “... over 99% of all species that ever
existed are extinct”. (Carroll 2006) But there exists no finite value of R -
positive or negative - that yields extinction. There is no mechanism for
portraying extinction. It cannot be represented by R except for the value -∞.
The mathematical conditions for extinction are n=0 and dn/dt<0. No
infinities enter computations founded on these statements. The Opposition
Principle computations, offered below, are so founded.
Next consider the eponymous Verhulst Equation. Verhulst’s K doesn’t derive
from some fundamental biological constraint. It’s motivated only by the
observation that populations never grow to infinity. There are other ways in
which population may be bounded. For example, n(t) may oscillate. Or, as in
Figure 1, a curve essentially the same as Verhulst’s may arise from an
entirely different theory where no K = nmax limit exists. One of the possible
population histories resulting from the Opposition Principle – which contains
no nMAX - is shown in blue.
The limited validity of r/K Selection Theory has been noted by researchers
over the years. (Parry 1981; Kuno 1991)
Principle p. 7
Figure 1. Two population histories: number vs. time. The black curve is the
Verhulst Equation. The blue curve is one of the solutions to the Opposition
Principle differential equation.
I have outlined what I see as limitations of the accepted Malthusian
Structure of population dynamics. An alternative structure is offered in what
follows.
3. Conceptual foundations for an alternative structure
We seek a mathematical equation to embrace all of the great variety of
population behaviors. The foundational axioms on which that equation is
built are the following:
First: Variations in population number, n, are due entirely to environment.
Principle p. 8
We assume that the environment drives population dynamics; that it is
entirely responsible for time variations in population number – whether
within a single lifetime or over many generations.
That the survival and reproductive success of any individual is influenced by
heredity as well as the environment is also true. There is no contradiction
here. Both the environment and the population come to the present moment
equipped with their capacities to influence each other; capacities derived
from their past histories. They come equipped with heredity to face the
environment.
That the environment molds the population within a lifetime is clear; think of
a tornado, a disease outbreak, or a meteor impact. That the environment
governs population dynamics over generations is precisely the substance of
‘natural selection’ in Darwinian evolution.
That principle may be summarized as follows: “... the small selective
advantage a trait confers on individuals that have it...” (Carroll 2006)
increases the population of those individuals. But what does ‘selective
advantage’ mean? It means that the favored population is ‘selected’ by the
environment to thrive. Ultimately it is the environment that governs a
population’s history. Findings in epigenetics that the environment can
produce changes transmitted across generations (Gilbert et al. 2009;
Jablonka et al. 2009) adds further support to this notion.
Much productive research looks at traits in the phenotype that correlate with
fitness or LRS (Lifetime Reproductive Success). (Clutton-Brock 1990;
Coulson et al. 2006) The focus is on how the organism fits into its
environment. So something called 'fitness' is viewed as a property of the
Principle p. 9
organism. There is an alternative focus: fitness, being a matter of selection
by the environment, is a property of the environment.
In this view birth rates and death rates are not the cause of population
dynamics; rather birth and death rates register the effect of the environment
on the population.
Second: An increasing growth rate is what measures a population's success.
The 'success' of a population is an assertion about a population’s time
development; it concerns the size and growth of the population. A
reasonable notion of success is that the population is flourishing. We want to
give quantitative voice to the notion that flourishing growth reveals a
population’s success.
Neither population number, n, nor population growth, dn/dt, are adequate to
represent ‘flourishing’. Population number may be large but it may be falling.
Such a population cannot be said to be flourishing. So we can’t use
population number as the measure of success. Growth seems a better
candidate. But, again, suppose growth is large but falling. Only a rising
growth rate would indicate ‘flourishing’. This is exactly the quantity we
propose to take as a measure of success; the growth in the growth rate. By
flourishing is meant growing faster each year.
The ‘success’ of a population over, say, one year is the increase in growth
over that year. A growth rate of 1000 new members per month at the
beginning increases, say, to 1500 new members per month at the end of
one year. This amounts to an adaptive success of 500 per month per year
(500/mo-yr). Should the growth rate decline in the next year from 1500/mo
Principle p. 10
to 1200/mo then, in that year the adaptive success would be negative, -300
per month per year. Figure 2 is a visual illustration of the relationship
between the three variables, population, its growth and its 'success' for a
hypothetical population history.
Figure 2. A hypothetical population history, n = n(t); black curve. The
population becomes extinct 350 years after it was first tracked from an initial
1300 members. It more than doubles in 200 years to reach a peak close to
5000 members. But its growth (purple curve) is zero at this population
apogee. Then the population plunges precipitously – negative growth - going
extinct after another 150 years. The success curve (blue) shows that the
population was flourishing only in the first 60 years. Success is positive in
those years. After that the seeds of decay appeared; the growth began to
decrease. The population increased ever less rapidly until it stopped
increasing altogether – at its apogee. At extinction, all of the parameters
shown are finite even though R, at this point, is -∞.
Principle p. 11
A corollary of these two foundational hypotheses is that change is perpetual.
Equilibrium is a temporary condition. What we call equilibrium is a stretch of
time during which dn/dt = 0. Hence ‘returning to equilibrium’ is not a feature
of analysis in this model.
Another corollary is this: The environment of one population is other
populations. It’s through this mechanism that interactions among
populations occur: via reciprocity - if A is in the environment of B, then B is
in the environment of A. So the structure offers a natural setting for
feedback. (Pelletier et al. 2009) It provides a framework for the analysis of
competition, of co-evolution and of predator-prey relations among
populations. These obey the same equation but differ only in the signs of
coefficients relating any pair of populations.
4. The Opposition Principle: quantitative formulation
Based on the understandings outlined above we propose that an overriding
principle governs the population dynamics of living things. It is this: The
effect on the environment of a population's success is to alter that
environment in a way that opposes the success. In order to refer to it, I call
it the Opposition Principle. It is a functional principle (McNamara et al. 2009)
operating irrespective of the mechanisms by which it's accomplished.
The Principle applies to a society of living organisms that share an
environment. The key feature of that society is that it consists of a number,
n, of members which have an inherent drive to survive and to produce
offspring with genetic variation. Their number varies with time: n = n(t).
Again we restrict ourselves to n=large>>1 so that its integer nature is not
Principle p. 12
pertinent to computations.
Because we don't know whether n, itself, or some monotonically increasing
function of n is the relevant parameter, we define a population strength,
N(n). Any population exhibits a certain strength in influencing its
environment. This population strength, N(n), expresses the potency of the
population in affecting the environment – its environmental impact. Perhaps
this strength, N, is just the number n, itself. The greater n is, the more the
environmental impact. But it takes a lot of fleas to have the same
environmental impact as one elephant. So we would expect that the
population strength is some function of n that depends upon the population
under consideration.
Two things about the population potency, N, are clear. First, N(n) must be a
monotonically increasing function of n; dN/dn > 0. This is because if the
population increases then, surely, its impact also increases. Albeit, perhaps
not linearly. Second, when n=0 so, too, is N=0. If the population is zero
then certainly its impact is zero. One candidate for N(n) might be n raised to
some positive power, p. If p=1 then N and n are the same thing. Another
candidate is the logarithm of (n+1).
We need not specify the precise relationship, N(n), in what follows. Via
experiment it can be coaxed from nature later. The only way that N
depends upon time is parametrically through its dependence on n. In what
follows we shall mean by N(t) the dependence N(n(t)). We may think of N
as a surrogate for the number of members in the population.
The population strength growth rate, g = g(t), is defined by
Principle p. 13
g :=
dN
dt
(4.1)
Like N, g too acquires its time dependence parametrically through n(t). g =
(dN/dn)(dn/dt)
To quantify how the environment affects the population we introduce the
notion of ‘environmental favorability’. We'll designate it by the symbol, f. It
represents the effect of the environment on the population.
A population flourishes when the environment is favorable. Environmental
favorability is what drives a population's success. But in the last section we
arrived at a quantitative measure of success. The rate of growth of the
population strength - 'the growth of growth' or dg/dt – measures success.
Hence, that a population's success is generated entirely by the environment
is expressed mathematically as:
dg
dt
= (4.2)
Since equation (4.2) says that success equals the favorability of the
environment, it follows that f measures not only environmental favorability
but also population success.
We’re now prepared to caste the Opposition Principle as a mathematical
statement. The Principle has two parts. 1. Any increase in population
strength decreases favorability; the more the population's presence is felt
the less favorable becomes the environment. 2. Any increase in the growth
of that strength also decreases favorability.
Principle p. 14
Put formally: That part of the change in f due to an increase in N is negative.
Likewise the change in f due to an increase in g is negative. Here is the
direct mathematical rendering of these two statements:
!f
!N
< 0 and
!f
!g
< 0 (4.3)
We can implement these statements by introducing two parameters. Both w
and α are non-negative real numbers and they have the dimensions of
reciprocal time. (Negative w values are permitted but are redundant.)
!
!N
=" 2
and
!
!g
="! (4.4)
These partial differential equations can be integrated. The result is:
f = !w2
N !!g + F(t) (4.5)
The 'constant' (with respect to N and g) of integration, F(t), has an evident
interpretation. It is the gratuitous favorability provided by nature; the gift of
nature. Equation (4.5) says that environmental favorability consists of two
parts.
One part depends on the number and growth of the population being
favored: the N and its time derivative, g. This part has two terms both of
which always act to decrease favorability. These terms express the
Opposition Principle.
Principle p. 15
The other part - F(t) - is independent of N and of g. It is the gift of nature.
There must be something in the environment that is favorable to population
success but external to that population else the population would not exist in
the first place. This gift of nature may depend cyclically on time. For
example, seasonal variations are cyclical changes in favorability. Or it may
remain relatively constant like the presence of air to breathe. It may also
exhibit random and sometimes violent fluctuations like a volcanic eruption or
unexpected rains on a parched earth. So it has a stochastic component. All
of these are quite independent of the population under consideration.
Inserting equations (4.1) and (4.2) into (4.5) we arrive at the promised
differential equation governing population dynamics under the Opposition
Principle. It is this.
d2
N
dt2
+ !
dN
dt
+w2
N = F(t) (4.6)
In the world of physical phenomena this equation is ubiquitous. Depending
upon the meaning assigned to N it describes electrical circuits, mechanical
systems, the production of sound in musical instruments and a host of other
phenomena. So it is very well studied. The exact analytical solution to (4.6),
yielding N(t) for any given F(t), is known.
To explore some of the consequences of this differential equation we
consider the easiest case; that the gift favorability is simply constant over an
extended period of time. Assume F(t) = c independent of time. Non-periodic
solutions arise if α ≥ 2w. One of these, displayed in Figure 1, produces
results similar to the Verhulst equation. If α < 2w the solutions to (4.6) are
periodic and are given by:
Principle p. 16
N(t) =
c
w2
+ Ae!!t/2
sin("t + a) (4.7)
where the amplitude, A, and the phase, a, depend upon the conditions of the
population at a designated time, say t=0. And the oscillation frequency, ω, is
given by:
! := w 1!(
"
2w
)2
"
#
$
$
$
%
&
'
'
'
'
(4.8)
Figure 3. Observational data on the population fluctuations of larch budmoth
density is shown as black diamonds and squares. The smooth orange curve
is a solution of Equation (4.7).
In Figure 3, equation (4.7) is compared to empirical data. The figure shows
the population fluctuations of larch budmoth density (Turchin et al. 2003)
assembled from records gathered over a period of 40 yrs. The data points
and lines connecting them are shown in black. The smooth orange curve in
the background is a graph of equation (4.7) for particular values of the
parameters.
Principle p. 17
We assumed α is negligibly small so it can be set equal to zero. The
frequency, ω, is taken to be 2π/(9yrs) = 0.7per year. The vertical axis
represents N. In the units chosen for N, the amplitude, A, is taken to be 0.6
and c is taken to be 0.6 per year2
. The phase, a, is chosen so as to insure a
peak in the population in the year 1963; a=3.49 radians.
Because the fluctuations are so large the authors plotted n0.1
as the ordinate
for their data presentation. The ordinate for the smooth orange theoretical
curve is N. Looking at the fit in Figure 3, one might be led to conclude that
the population strength, N(n), for the budmoth varies as the 0.1 power of n.
But the precision of fit may not warrant this conclusion.
The conclusions that may be warranted are these:
Considering that no information about the details of budmoth life have gone
into the computation the graphical correspondence is noteworthy. It
suggests that those details of budmoth life are nature's way of implementing
an overriding principle. The graphical correspondence means that, under a
constant external environmental favorability, a population should behave not
unlike that of the budmoth.
Equation (4.7) admits of circumstances in which population extinction can
occur. If A > c/w2
then N can drop to zero. Societies with zero population
are extinct ones. (On attaining zero, N remains zero. The governing
differential equation, (4.6), doesn't apply when N<0.)
But the value of A derives from initial conditions; from N(t=0) and g(t=0).
So depending upon the seed population and its initial growth rate the society
may thrive or become extinct even in the presence of gift favorability, c. This
Principle p. 18
result offers an explanation for the existence of the phenomenon of
'extinction debt' (Kuussaari et al. 2009) and a way to compute the relaxation
time for delayed extinction.
The case explored reveals that periodic population oscillations can occur
without a periodic driving force. Even a steady favorability can produce
population oscillations.
5. Conclusion
What has been proposed and argued here is this: Regardless of the details
by which it is accomplished, there may be a general principle operative in
determining population dynamics among living things – the Opposition
Principle. Its mathematical expression is realized in a differential equation
which governs the evolution of any population. A solution of this equation
compares favorably to empirical data on the larch budmoth.
Figure 4. A theoretical population history that can result from the Opposition
Principle differential equation.
Among the plethora of solutions to the governing differential equation, (4.6),
is this one: Upon a step increase in environmental favorability – say, in food
Principle p. 19
abundance – the population may overshoot what the new environment can
accommodate and then settle down after a few cycles. Figure 4 illustrates
this behavior. That there are such solutions amounts to a prediction that
population histories like that of Figure 4 will be found in nature.
Having the Opposition Principle in mathematical form allows quantitative
comparisons with empirical data. Observational evidence will support or
refute the theory.
References:
Berryman, A. 2003 On principles, laws and theory in population ecology.
Oikos 103, 695-701
Carroll, S. B. 2006 The Making of the Fittest. New York, NY: W.W. Norton
Clutton-Brock, T. H. (editor) 1990 Reproductive Success : Studies of
Individual Variation in Contrasting Breeding Systems. Chicago, IL: University
of Chicago Press
Coulson, T., Benton, T. G., Lundberg, P., Dall, S.R.X., Kendall, B.E. and Gaillard, J.-M.
2006 Estimating individual contributions to population growth: evolutionary
fitness in ecological time. Proc. R. Soc. B 273, 547-555
Darwin, C. 1859 On The Origin of Species by Means of Natural Selection.
London: John Murray
Fisher, R. A. 1930 The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Principle p. 20
Gilbert, S.F. and Epel, D. 2009 Ecological Developmental Biology.
Sunderland, MA: Sinauer
Jablonka, E. and Raz, G. 2009 Transgenerational Epigenetic Inheritance:
Prevalence, Mechanisms and implications for the study of heredity and
evolution. Quarterly Review of Biology 84, 131-176
Jones, J. M. 1976 The r-K-Selection Continuum. The American Naturalist
110, 320-323
Kuussaari, M., Bommarco, R., Heikkinen, R.K., Helm, A., Krauss, J.,
Lindborg, R., Öckinger, E., Pärtel, M., Pino, J., Rodà, F., Stefanescu, C.,
Teder, T., Zobel, M. and Ingolf Steffan-Dewenter, I. 2009 Extinction debt: a
challenge for biodiversity conservation. Trends Ecol. Evol. 24, 564-571
Kuno, E. 1991 Some strange properties of the logistic equation defined with
r and K - inherent defects or artifacts. Researches on Population Ecology 33,
33-39
Malthus, T. 1798 An essay on the Principle of Population. London: J. Johnson
McNamara, J.M. and Houston, A.I. 2009 Integrating function and
mechanism. Trends Ecol. Evol. 24, 670-675
Michod, R. E. 1999 Darwinian Dynamics: Evolutionary Transitions in Fitness
and Individuality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
Nowak, M. A. 2006 Evolutionary Dynamics: Exploring the Equations of Life.
Canada: Harvard Press
Principle p. 21
Okada, H., Harada, H., Tsukiboshi, T., Araki, M. 2005 Characteristics of
Tylencholaimus parvus (Nematoda: Dorylaimida) as a fungivorus nematode.
Nematology 7, 843-849
Parry, G.D. 1981 The meanings of r- and K-selection. Oecologia 48, 260-264
Pelletier, F., Garant, D., and Hendry, A. P. 2009 Eco-evolutionary dynamics.
Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 364, 1483-1489
Ruokolainen, L., Lindéna, A., Kaitalaa, V. and Fowler, M. S. 2009 Ecological
and evolutionary dynamics under coloured environmental variation Trends
Ecol. Evol. 24, 555-563
Torres, J.-L., Pérez-Maqueo, O., Equihua, M., and Torres, L. 2009
Quantitative assessment of organism–environment couplings. Biol Philos. 24,
107–117
Turchin, P., Wood, S. N., Ellner, S.P., Kendall, B.E., Murdoch, W. W.,
Fischlin, A., Casas, J., McCauley, E. and Briggs, C. J. 2003 Dynamical effects
of plant quality and parasitism on population cycles of larch budmoth.
Ecology 84, 1207–1214
Vainstein, J.H., Rube J.M. and Vilar, J.M.G., 2007 Stochastic population
dynamics in turbulent fields. Eur. Phys. J. Special Topics 146, 177-187
Verhulst, P-F., 1838 Notice sur la loi que la population poursuit dans son
accroissement. Correspondance mathématique et physique 10, 113-121

Recomendados

popgrowth.ppt por
popgrowth.pptpopgrowth.ppt
popgrowth.pptVivekChauhan516259
5 vistas40 diapositivas
Leslie Matrices por
Leslie MatricesLeslie Matrices
Leslie MatricesLorisha Riley
2.7K vistas39 diapositivas
Theoretical ecology por
Theoretical ecologyTheoretical ecology
Theoretical ecologyMai Ngoc Duc
734 vistas12 diapositivas
Population ecology por
Population ecologyPopulation ecology
Population ecologyAmna Jalil
108.2K vistas55 diapositivas
Poster_PingPong por
Poster_PingPongPoster_PingPong
Poster_PingPongAlexa Aucoin
259 vistas1 diapositiva
STATISTICAL TESTS TO COMPARE k SURVIVAL ANALYSIS FUNCTIONS INVOLVING RECURREN... por
STATISTICAL TESTS TO COMPARE k SURVIVAL ANALYSIS FUNCTIONS INVOLVING RECURREN...STATISTICAL TESTS TO COMPARE k SURVIVAL ANALYSIS FUNCTIONS INVOLVING RECURREN...
STATISTICAL TESTS TO COMPARE k SURVIVAL ANALYSIS FUNCTIONS INVOLVING RECURREN...Carlos M Martínez M
1.9K vistas6 diapositivas

Más contenido relacionado

Similar a A Principle Governing The Success Of Populations.

Matlab Code for Logistic Growth Model por
Matlab Code for Logistic Growth Model Matlab Code for Logistic Growth Model
Matlab Code for Logistic Growth Model RevathyPraba
2.4K vistas18 diapositivas
Ecological study design multiple group study and statistical analysis por
Ecological study design multiple group study and statistical analysisEcological study design multiple group study and statistical analysis
Ecological study design multiple group study and statistical analysissirjana Tiwari
3.7K vistas26 diapositivas
Descriptive statistics-Skewness-Kurtosis-Correlation.ppt por
Descriptive statistics-Skewness-Kurtosis-Correlation.pptDescriptive statistics-Skewness-Kurtosis-Correlation.ppt
Descriptive statistics-Skewness-Kurtosis-Correlation.pptRama Krishna
11 vistas36 diapositivas
Form, function, and evolution of living organisms por
Form, function, and evolution of living organismsForm, function, and evolution of living organisms
Form, function, and evolution of living organismsJosé Luis Moreno Garvayo
848 vistas6 diapositivas
The Impact of Allee Effect on a Predator-Prey Model with Holling Type II Func... por
The Impact of Allee Effect on a Predator-Prey Model with Holling Type II Func...The Impact of Allee Effect on a Predator-Prey Model with Holling Type II Func...
The Impact of Allee Effect on a Predator-Prey Model with Holling Type II Func...mathsjournal
26 vistas21 diapositivas
Environmental Science-4.pptx por
Environmental Science-4.pptxEnvironmental Science-4.pptx
Environmental Science-4.pptxGavin Malala
4 vistas22 diapositivas

Similar a A Principle Governing The Success Of Populations.(20)

Matlab Code for Logistic Growth Model por RevathyPraba
Matlab Code for Logistic Growth Model Matlab Code for Logistic Growth Model
Matlab Code for Logistic Growth Model
RevathyPraba2.4K vistas
Ecological study design multiple group study and statistical analysis por sirjana Tiwari
Ecological study design multiple group study and statistical analysisEcological study design multiple group study and statistical analysis
Ecological study design multiple group study and statistical analysis
sirjana Tiwari3.7K vistas
Descriptive statistics-Skewness-Kurtosis-Correlation.ppt por Rama Krishna
Descriptive statistics-Skewness-Kurtosis-Correlation.pptDescriptive statistics-Skewness-Kurtosis-Correlation.ppt
Descriptive statistics-Skewness-Kurtosis-Correlation.ppt
Rama Krishna11 vistas
The Impact of Allee Effect on a Predator-Prey Model with Holling Type II Func... por mathsjournal
The Impact of Allee Effect on a Predator-Prey Model with Holling Type II Func...The Impact of Allee Effect on a Predator-Prey Model with Holling Type II Func...
The Impact of Allee Effect on a Predator-Prey Model with Holling Type II Func...
mathsjournal26 vistas
Environmental Science-4.pptx por Gavin Malala
Environmental Science-4.pptxEnvironmental Science-4.pptx
Environmental Science-4.pptx
Gavin Malala4 vistas
populationecology-120221024008-phpapp02.pdf por Jaipal51
populationecology-120221024008-phpapp02.pdfpopulationecology-120221024008-phpapp02.pdf
populationecology-120221024008-phpapp02.pdf
Jaipal517 vistas
Ecology Report:Niche, Basic Theories and Debates por Tony Yen
Ecology Report:Niche, Basic Theories and DebatesEcology Report:Niche, Basic Theories and Debates
Ecology Report:Niche, Basic Theories and Debates
Tony Yen514 vistas
Freckleton &amp; witkinson 2002 por Klaudia Llano
Freckleton &amp; witkinson 2002Freckleton &amp; witkinson 2002
Freckleton &amp; witkinson 2002
Klaudia Llano141 vistas
Using STELLA to Explore Dynamic Single Species Models: The Magic of Making Hu... por Lisa Jensen
Using STELLA to Explore Dynamic Single Species Models: The Magic of Making Hu...Using STELLA to Explore Dynamic Single Species Models: The Magic of Making Hu...
Using STELLA to Explore Dynamic Single Species Models: The Magic of Making Hu...
Lisa Jensen395 vistas
SThAR_corporate_presentation_19-09-2009 por Ricardo Hernando
SThAR_corporate_presentation_19-09-2009SThAR_corporate_presentation_19-09-2009
SThAR_corporate_presentation_19-09-2009
Ricardo Hernando469 vistas
Population dynamics por EmaSushan
Population dynamicsPopulation dynamics
Population dynamics
EmaSushan844 vistas
1979 Optimal diffusions in a random environment por Bob Marcus
1979 Optimal diffusions in a random environment1979 Optimal diffusions in a random environment
1979 Optimal diffusions in a random environment
Bob Marcus152 vistas
PopulationEcology52.ppt por Jake933493
PopulationEcology52.pptPopulationEcology52.ppt
PopulationEcology52.ppt
Jake9334939 vistas
Characterization of Distribution of insects- Indices of Dispersion, Taylor's ... por Aaliya Afroz
Characterization of Distribution of insects- Indices of Dispersion, Taylor's ...Characterization of Distribution of insects- Indices of Dispersion, Taylor's ...
Characterization of Distribution of insects- Indices of Dispersion, Taylor's ...
Aaliya Afroz1.3K vistas
Punctuated equilibrium theory represents shifting balance theory (of macro an... por MdAbdulAhad26
Punctuated equilibrium theory represents shifting balance theory (of macro an...Punctuated equilibrium theory represents shifting balance theory (of macro an...
Punctuated equilibrium theory represents shifting balance theory (of macro an...
MdAbdulAhad2613 vistas

Más de Daphne Smith

Action Research final project.pdf.pdf por
Action Research final project.pdf.pdfAction Research final project.pdf.pdf
Action Research final project.pdf.pdfDaphne Smith
84 vistas21 diapositivas
A Bibliography on the Book of Ruth.pdf por
A Bibliography on the Book of Ruth.pdfA Bibliography on the Book of Ruth.pdf
A Bibliography on the Book of Ruth.pdfDaphne Smith
6 vistas2 diapositivas
A STUDY ON STRADDLE OPTIONS STRATEGY, A GUIDE TO THE EQUITY DERIVATIVES INVES... por
A STUDY ON STRADDLE OPTIONS STRATEGY, A GUIDE TO THE EQUITY DERIVATIVES INVES...A STUDY ON STRADDLE OPTIONS STRATEGY, A GUIDE TO THE EQUITY DERIVATIVES INVES...
A STUDY ON STRADDLE OPTIONS STRATEGY, A GUIDE TO THE EQUITY DERIVATIVES INVES...Daphne Smith
3 vistas8 diapositivas
Anatoli Podoksik Pablo Picasso.pdf por
Anatoli Podoksik Pablo Picasso.pdfAnatoli Podoksik Pablo Picasso.pdf
Anatoli Podoksik Pablo Picasso.pdfDaphne Smith
8 vistas160 diapositivas
An overview of the political economy of South Africa.pdf por
An overview of the political economy of South Africa.pdfAn overview of the political economy of South Africa.pdf
An overview of the political economy of South Africa.pdfDaphne Smith
3 vistas34 diapositivas
2. Against the Right to Die.pdf por
2. Against the Right to Die.pdf2. Against the Right to Die.pdf
2. Against the Right to Die.pdfDaphne Smith
4 vistas234 diapositivas

Más de Daphne Smith(20)

Action Research final project.pdf.pdf por Daphne Smith
Action Research final project.pdf.pdfAction Research final project.pdf.pdf
Action Research final project.pdf.pdf
Daphne Smith84 vistas
A Bibliography on the Book of Ruth.pdf por Daphne Smith
A Bibliography on the Book of Ruth.pdfA Bibliography on the Book of Ruth.pdf
A Bibliography on the Book of Ruth.pdf
Daphne Smith6 vistas
A STUDY ON STRADDLE OPTIONS STRATEGY, A GUIDE TO THE EQUITY DERIVATIVES INVES... por Daphne Smith
A STUDY ON STRADDLE OPTIONS STRATEGY, A GUIDE TO THE EQUITY DERIVATIVES INVES...A STUDY ON STRADDLE OPTIONS STRATEGY, A GUIDE TO THE EQUITY DERIVATIVES INVES...
A STUDY ON STRADDLE OPTIONS STRATEGY, A GUIDE TO THE EQUITY DERIVATIVES INVES...
Daphne Smith3 vistas
Anatoli Podoksik Pablo Picasso.pdf por Daphne Smith
Anatoli Podoksik Pablo Picasso.pdfAnatoli Podoksik Pablo Picasso.pdf
Anatoli Podoksik Pablo Picasso.pdf
Daphne Smith8 vistas
An overview of the political economy of South Africa.pdf por Daphne Smith
An overview of the political economy of South Africa.pdfAn overview of the political economy of South Africa.pdf
An overview of the political economy of South Africa.pdf
Daphne Smith3 vistas
2. Against the Right to Die.pdf por Daphne Smith
2. Against the Right to Die.pdf2. Against the Right to Die.pdf
2. Against the Right to Die.pdf
Daphne Smith4 vistas
A Concise Introduction to Logic.pdf por Daphne Smith
A Concise Introduction to Logic.pdfA Concise Introduction to Logic.pdf
A Concise Introduction to Logic.pdf
Daphne Smith24 vistas
Assessing The Quality Of Scientific Articles Using Artificial Neural Networks por Daphne Smith
Assessing The Quality Of Scientific Articles Using Artificial Neural NetworksAssessing The Quality Of Scientific Articles Using Artificial Neural Networks
Assessing The Quality Of Scientific Articles Using Artificial Neural Networks
Daphne Smith3 vistas
Abolition Of Death Penalty por Daphne Smith
Abolition Of Death PenaltyAbolition Of Death Penalty
Abolition Of Death Penalty
Daphne Smith2 vistas
Assessing The Impact Of Global Variables On Program Dependence And Dependence... por Daphne Smith
Assessing The Impact Of Global Variables On Program Dependence And Dependence...Assessing The Impact Of Global Variables On Program Dependence And Dependence...
Assessing The Impact Of Global Variables On Program Dependence And Dependence...
Daphne Smith3 vistas
Asking The Quot Right Quot Questions por Daphne Smith
Asking The  Quot  Right  Quot  QuestionsAsking The  Quot  Right  Quot  Questions
Asking The Quot Right Quot Questions
Daphne Smith2 vistas
A COMPARATIVE STUDY ON SERVICES PROVIDED BY PUBLIC SECTOR BANKS AND PRIVATE S... por Daphne Smith
A COMPARATIVE STUDY ON SERVICES PROVIDED BY PUBLIC SECTOR BANKS AND PRIVATE S...A COMPARATIVE STUDY ON SERVICES PROVIDED BY PUBLIC SECTOR BANKS AND PRIVATE S...
A COMPARATIVE STUDY ON SERVICES PROVIDED BY PUBLIC SECTOR BANKS AND PRIVATE S...
Daphne Smith4 vistas
72 Character Education And Personal Social Guidance Counseling And Its Effect... por Daphne Smith
72 Character Education And Personal Social Guidance Counseling And Its Effect...72 Character Education And Personal Social Guidance Counseling And Its Effect...
72 Character Education And Personal Social Guidance Counseling And Its Effect...
Daphne Smith2 vistas
2007. Book Review Words And Other Wonders By Dirk Geeraerts por Daphne Smith
2007. Book Review   Words And Other Wonders  By Dirk Geeraerts2007. Book Review   Words And Other Wonders  By Dirk Geeraerts
2007. Book Review Words And Other Wonders By Dirk Geeraerts
Daphne Smith2 vistas
5 Tips For Proofreading Your Dissertation por Daphne Smith
5 Tips For Proofreading Your Dissertation5 Tips For Proofreading Your Dissertation
5 Tips For Proofreading Your Dissertation
Daphne Smith2 vistas
Assisted Suicide And Euthanasia In Switzerland Allowing A Role For Non-Physi... por Daphne Smith
Assisted Suicide And Euthanasia In Switzerland  Allowing A Role For Non-Physi...Assisted Suicide And Euthanasia In Switzerland  Allowing A Role For Non-Physi...
Assisted Suicide And Euthanasia In Switzerland Allowing A Role For Non-Physi...
Daphne Smith3 vistas
Academic Literacy The Analysis Of First-Year Ukrainian University Students ... por Daphne Smith
Academic Literacy  The Analysis Of First-Year Ukrainian University Students  ...Academic Literacy  The Analysis Of First-Year Ukrainian University Students  ...
Academic Literacy The Analysis Of First-Year Ukrainian University Students ...
Daphne Smith2 vistas
681 - Refugee And Special Humanitarian Proposal por Daphne Smith
681 - Refugee And Special Humanitarian Proposal681 - Refugee And Special Humanitarian Proposal
681 - Refugee And Special Humanitarian Proposal
Daphne Smith2 vistas
Automated Voice Based Braille Script Teaching Aid Using por Daphne Smith
Automated Voice Based Braille Script Teaching Aid UsingAutomated Voice Based Braille Script Teaching Aid Using
Automated Voice Based Braille Script Teaching Aid Using
Daphne Smith2 vistas

Último

INT-244 Topic 6b Confucianism por
INT-244 Topic 6b ConfucianismINT-244 Topic 6b Confucianism
INT-244 Topic 6b ConfucianismS Meyer
45 vistas77 diapositivas
Nelson_RecordStore.pdf por
Nelson_RecordStore.pdfNelson_RecordStore.pdf
Nelson_RecordStore.pdfBrynNelson5
46 vistas10 diapositivas
UNIT NO 13 ORGANISMS AND POPULATION.pptx por
UNIT NO 13 ORGANISMS AND POPULATION.pptxUNIT NO 13 ORGANISMS AND POPULATION.pptx
UNIT NO 13 ORGANISMS AND POPULATION.pptxMadhuri Bhande
42 vistas33 diapositivas
Introduction to AERO Supply Chain - #BEAERO Trainning program por
Introduction to AERO Supply Chain  - #BEAERO Trainning programIntroduction to AERO Supply Chain  - #BEAERO Trainning program
Introduction to AERO Supply Chain - #BEAERO Trainning programGuennoun Wajih
95 vistas78 diapositivas
Volf work.pdf por
Volf work.pdfVolf work.pdf
Volf work.pdfMariaKenney3
89 vistas43 diapositivas
MercerJesse3.0.pdf por
MercerJesse3.0.pdfMercerJesse3.0.pdf
MercerJesse3.0.pdfjessemercerail
152 vistas6 diapositivas

Último(20)

INT-244 Topic 6b Confucianism por S Meyer
INT-244 Topic 6b ConfucianismINT-244 Topic 6b Confucianism
INT-244 Topic 6b Confucianism
S Meyer45 vistas
Nelson_RecordStore.pdf por BrynNelson5
Nelson_RecordStore.pdfNelson_RecordStore.pdf
Nelson_RecordStore.pdf
BrynNelson546 vistas
UNIT NO 13 ORGANISMS AND POPULATION.pptx por Madhuri Bhande
UNIT NO 13 ORGANISMS AND POPULATION.pptxUNIT NO 13 ORGANISMS AND POPULATION.pptx
UNIT NO 13 ORGANISMS AND POPULATION.pptx
Madhuri Bhande42 vistas
Introduction to AERO Supply Chain - #BEAERO Trainning program por Guennoun Wajih
Introduction to AERO Supply Chain  - #BEAERO Trainning programIntroduction to AERO Supply Chain  - #BEAERO Trainning program
Introduction to AERO Supply Chain - #BEAERO Trainning program
Guennoun Wajih95 vistas
Guess Papers ADC 1, Karachi University por Khalid Aziz
Guess Papers ADC 1, Karachi UniversityGuess Papers ADC 1, Karachi University
Guess Papers ADC 1, Karachi University
Khalid Aziz99 vistas
Creative Restart 2023: Leonard Savage - The Permanent Brief: Unearthing unobv... por Taste
Creative Restart 2023: Leonard Savage - The Permanent Brief: Unearthing unobv...Creative Restart 2023: Leonard Savage - The Permanent Brief: Unearthing unobv...
Creative Restart 2023: Leonard Savage - The Permanent Brief: Unearthing unobv...
Taste55 vistas
Six Sigma Concept by Sahil Srivastava.pptx por Sahil Srivastava
Six Sigma Concept by Sahil Srivastava.pptxSix Sigma Concept by Sahil Srivastava.pptx
Six Sigma Concept by Sahil Srivastava.pptx
Sahil Srivastava44 vistas
Payment Integration using Braintree Connector | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #37 por MysoreMuleSoftMeetup
Payment Integration using Braintree Connector | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #37Payment Integration using Braintree Connector | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #37
Payment Integration using Braintree Connector | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #37
Career Building in AI - Technologies, Trends and Opportunities por WebStackAcademy
Career Building in AI - Technologies, Trends and OpportunitiesCareer Building in AI - Technologies, Trends and Opportunities
Career Building in AI - Technologies, Trends and Opportunities
WebStackAcademy45 vistas
12.5.23 Poverty and Precarity.pptx por mary850239
12.5.23 Poverty and Precarity.pptx12.5.23 Poverty and Precarity.pptx
12.5.23 Poverty and Precarity.pptx
mary850239381 vistas

A Principle Governing The Success Of Populations.

  • 1. Principle p. 1 March 27, 2010 A principle governing the success of populations. Marvin Chester chester@physics.ucla.edu Physics Department, University of California, Los Angeles Keywords: population dynamics; evolution; ecology; eco-evolutionary dynamics; population evolution; evolution theory; ecological development; exponential growth; Verhulst equation; rK theory Abstract: The effect of a population's success on the environment is to alter that environment so that it opposes the success. It is proposed that this is the principle of nature that governs population dynamics among living organisms. We cast this principle in mathematical form so as to make it amenable to quantitative comparison with empirical data. It is thus exposed to refutation or validation. A second order differential equation for population dynamics is deduced. One of its solutions is compared to empirical data. Another solution generates a prediction on possible population histories. Some unexpected implications of the differential equation are explored. For example, that population histories may exhibit oscillations even under a steady, non-oscillatory environmental driving force. The equation also offers insight into why the phenomenon of 'extinction debt' should exist and suggests a way to predict the relaxation time for delayed extinction.
  • 2. Principle p. 2 1. Historical Perspective The acknowledged source of theories about population is the monograph by the venerable Thomas Malthus. (Malthus 1798) His place in history rests largely on these two sentences from page 4, “Population, when unchecked, increases in a geometrical ratio. Subsistence increases only in an arithmetical ratio.” The archaic terms ‘geometric ratio increase’ and ‘arithmetic ratio increase’ are today called ‘exponential growth’ and ‘linear growth’. In this quote he takes pains to distinguish these because his thesis is based on the distinction. Malthus was thinking only of human population. Darwin (Darwin 1859) took the idea to apply to populations in “the whole animal and vegetable kingdoms.” There is something profoundly fundamental about exponential growth. In living systems growth is proportional to the population. The reason is that each member (or pair of members) once produced, begin, themselves, to reproduce. There are more reproducers in a larger population. So the greater the number in the population, the greater the growth is. The same for deaths. The rate is proportional to the number available to die. Malthus didn’t offer equations to express these thoughts but it’s instructive do so. Call the number of members in the population, n. At each moment of time, t, there exist n individuals in the population. So we expect that n=n(t) is a continuous function of time. We restrict ourselves to n=large>>1 so that its integer nature is not pertinent to computations.
  • 3. Principle p. 3 The rate of growth of the population is dn/dt; the increase in the number of members per unit time. That this is proportional to population number, n, is the substance of the idea. Call the constant of proportionality, R. Then the differential equation that embodies the idea of ‘increase by geometrical ratio’ is: dn / dt = Rn (1.1) And, R being constant, its solution yields the archetypical equation of exponential growth. n(t) = n0 eRt (1.2) The n0 is simply the starting population, n0=n(0); the number of its members at t=0. Again taking R as a constant and n0 as defined above, linear growth is expressed by this equation: n(t) = n0 (1+ Rt) (1.3) These formulas for n(t) exhibit starkly different behaviors. That is why they were contrasted by Malthus. Of course, common experience tells us that exponential growth cannot proceed indefinitely. No population grows without end. Suppose the birth rate declines. Maybe, instead, the death rate increases. Perhaps because the weather got cold or food became scarce. Then this is accounted for by a new exponent, say R’; a smaller one. So R is no longer viewed as being constant. It may vary with time. R = R(t).
  • 4. Principle p. 4 In describing living systems the idea has been to retain that fundamental exponential-like form and seek to explain events by variations in R. “The problem of explaining and predicting the dynamics of any particular population boils down to defining how R deviates from the expectation of uniform growth”. (Berryman 2003) The concept is that exponential growth is always taking place but at a rate that varies with time. Put mathematically: 1 n dn dt = R(t) (1.4) Fisher endows R with its own name, the Malthusian Parameter. (Fisher 1930) Equation(1.4) is called Darwinian Dynamics by Michod. (Michod 1999) In connection with his writing on genotype fitness Michod’s “Fisherian Fitness” is exactly of this form. Equation (1.4) is a powerful analytical tool for assessing population data. Of course, any theory on how R might depend on n – rather than on t - produces a theoretical R(t). This is because the differential equation: dn dt = nR(n) (1.5) is completely solvable for n as a function of t. Once we have n(t) we can deduce R(t) via it’s definition in equation (1.4). This theoretical R(t) may be compared to measurements of (1/n)dn/dt so as to assess whether the theory is verified. An object example of this process is provided by the celebrated Verhulst equation. dn dt = nR(n) = nr(1! n K ) (1.6)
  • 5. Principle p. 5 A population history, n vs. t, resulting from this equation is the black one of Figure 1. What motivated Verhulst (Verhulst 1838) is the common observation that nothing grows indefinitely. Here the constant, r, is the exponential growth factor and K is the limiting value that n can have - “the carrying capacity of the environment”.(Vainstein et al. 2007) The equation insures that n never gets larger than nMAX = K. Because n is understood to be the number in a given physical space it represents, in fact, a population density (number/space). That this density has a limit is the reason for the association of K with crowding. The name, r/K Selection Theory, derives from the competing dynamics of exponential growth and of crowding – the r and the K. The Verhulst equation is often embedded in research studies. (Nowak 2006; Torres et al. 2009; Jones 1976; Ruokolainen et al. 2009; Okada et al. 2005) 2. Limitations of the Structure This very useful and appealing structure has some limitations. Assigning all behavior to variations in R seems to preserve the pristine Malthusian exponential growth idea. But, in fact, allowing R to vary with time severs the connection to exponential growth. The idea is dramatized in this example. Malthus makes it clear that if a population is growing exponentially with time then it is certainly not growing linearly with time. Linear growth is the antithesis of exponential growth. Equations (1.2) and (1.3) display the difference. But suppose R varies as R(n) = C/n. Using this in solving the Malthusian Equation, (1.5), produces
  • 6. Principle p. 6 exactly linear growth! The constant C is n0r. Linear growth is variable-rate exponential growth! There is no more content in conjectures about R(t) than there is in theorizing directly about how n might depend on t; n = n(t). The theory offered in following sections is concerned with n(t) directly, rather than with R(t). Another limitation concerns extinction. A phenomenon well known to exist in nature is the extinction of a species. “... over 99% of all species that ever existed are extinct”. (Carroll 2006) But there exists no finite value of R - positive or negative - that yields extinction. There is no mechanism for portraying extinction. It cannot be represented by R except for the value -∞. The mathematical conditions for extinction are n=0 and dn/dt<0. No infinities enter computations founded on these statements. The Opposition Principle computations, offered below, are so founded. Next consider the eponymous Verhulst Equation. Verhulst’s K doesn’t derive from some fundamental biological constraint. It’s motivated only by the observation that populations never grow to infinity. There are other ways in which population may be bounded. For example, n(t) may oscillate. Or, as in Figure 1, a curve essentially the same as Verhulst’s may arise from an entirely different theory where no K = nmax limit exists. One of the possible population histories resulting from the Opposition Principle – which contains no nMAX - is shown in blue. The limited validity of r/K Selection Theory has been noted by researchers over the years. (Parry 1981; Kuno 1991)
  • 7. Principle p. 7 Figure 1. Two population histories: number vs. time. The black curve is the Verhulst Equation. The blue curve is one of the solutions to the Opposition Principle differential equation. I have outlined what I see as limitations of the accepted Malthusian Structure of population dynamics. An alternative structure is offered in what follows. 3. Conceptual foundations for an alternative structure We seek a mathematical equation to embrace all of the great variety of population behaviors. The foundational axioms on which that equation is built are the following: First: Variations in population number, n, are due entirely to environment.
  • 8. Principle p. 8 We assume that the environment drives population dynamics; that it is entirely responsible for time variations in population number – whether within a single lifetime or over many generations. That the survival and reproductive success of any individual is influenced by heredity as well as the environment is also true. There is no contradiction here. Both the environment and the population come to the present moment equipped with their capacities to influence each other; capacities derived from their past histories. They come equipped with heredity to face the environment. That the environment molds the population within a lifetime is clear; think of a tornado, a disease outbreak, or a meteor impact. That the environment governs population dynamics over generations is precisely the substance of ‘natural selection’ in Darwinian evolution. That principle may be summarized as follows: “... the small selective advantage a trait confers on individuals that have it...” (Carroll 2006) increases the population of those individuals. But what does ‘selective advantage’ mean? It means that the favored population is ‘selected’ by the environment to thrive. Ultimately it is the environment that governs a population’s history. Findings in epigenetics that the environment can produce changes transmitted across generations (Gilbert et al. 2009; Jablonka et al. 2009) adds further support to this notion. Much productive research looks at traits in the phenotype that correlate with fitness or LRS (Lifetime Reproductive Success). (Clutton-Brock 1990; Coulson et al. 2006) The focus is on how the organism fits into its environment. So something called 'fitness' is viewed as a property of the
  • 9. Principle p. 9 organism. There is an alternative focus: fitness, being a matter of selection by the environment, is a property of the environment. In this view birth rates and death rates are not the cause of population dynamics; rather birth and death rates register the effect of the environment on the population. Second: An increasing growth rate is what measures a population's success. The 'success' of a population is an assertion about a population’s time development; it concerns the size and growth of the population. A reasonable notion of success is that the population is flourishing. We want to give quantitative voice to the notion that flourishing growth reveals a population’s success. Neither population number, n, nor population growth, dn/dt, are adequate to represent ‘flourishing’. Population number may be large but it may be falling. Such a population cannot be said to be flourishing. So we can’t use population number as the measure of success. Growth seems a better candidate. But, again, suppose growth is large but falling. Only a rising growth rate would indicate ‘flourishing’. This is exactly the quantity we propose to take as a measure of success; the growth in the growth rate. By flourishing is meant growing faster each year. The ‘success’ of a population over, say, one year is the increase in growth over that year. A growth rate of 1000 new members per month at the beginning increases, say, to 1500 new members per month at the end of one year. This amounts to an adaptive success of 500 per month per year (500/mo-yr). Should the growth rate decline in the next year from 1500/mo
  • 10. Principle p. 10 to 1200/mo then, in that year the adaptive success would be negative, -300 per month per year. Figure 2 is a visual illustration of the relationship between the three variables, population, its growth and its 'success' for a hypothetical population history. Figure 2. A hypothetical population history, n = n(t); black curve. The population becomes extinct 350 years after it was first tracked from an initial 1300 members. It more than doubles in 200 years to reach a peak close to 5000 members. But its growth (purple curve) is zero at this population apogee. Then the population plunges precipitously – negative growth - going extinct after another 150 years. The success curve (blue) shows that the population was flourishing only in the first 60 years. Success is positive in those years. After that the seeds of decay appeared; the growth began to decrease. The population increased ever less rapidly until it stopped increasing altogether – at its apogee. At extinction, all of the parameters shown are finite even though R, at this point, is -∞.
  • 11. Principle p. 11 A corollary of these two foundational hypotheses is that change is perpetual. Equilibrium is a temporary condition. What we call equilibrium is a stretch of time during which dn/dt = 0. Hence ‘returning to equilibrium’ is not a feature of analysis in this model. Another corollary is this: The environment of one population is other populations. It’s through this mechanism that interactions among populations occur: via reciprocity - if A is in the environment of B, then B is in the environment of A. So the structure offers a natural setting for feedback. (Pelletier et al. 2009) It provides a framework for the analysis of competition, of co-evolution and of predator-prey relations among populations. These obey the same equation but differ only in the signs of coefficients relating any pair of populations. 4. The Opposition Principle: quantitative formulation Based on the understandings outlined above we propose that an overriding principle governs the population dynamics of living things. It is this: The effect on the environment of a population's success is to alter that environment in a way that opposes the success. In order to refer to it, I call it the Opposition Principle. It is a functional principle (McNamara et al. 2009) operating irrespective of the mechanisms by which it's accomplished. The Principle applies to a society of living organisms that share an environment. The key feature of that society is that it consists of a number, n, of members which have an inherent drive to survive and to produce offspring with genetic variation. Their number varies with time: n = n(t). Again we restrict ourselves to n=large>>1 so that its integer nature is not
  • 12. Principle p. 12 pertinent to computations. Because we don't know whether n, itself, or some monotonically increasing function of n is the relevant parameter, we define a population strength, N(n). Any population exhibits a certain strength in influencing its environment. This population strength, N(n), expresses the potency of the population in affecting the environment – its environmental impact. Perhaps this strength, N, is just the number n, itself. The greater n is, the more the environmental impact. But it takes a lot of fleas to have the same environmental impact as one elephant. So we would expect that the population strength is some function of n that depends upon the population under consideration. Two things about the population potency, N, are clear. First, N(n) must be a monotonically increasing function of n; dN/dn > 0. This is because if the population increases then, surely, its impact also increases. Albeit, perhaps not linearly. Second, when n=0 so, too, is N=0. If the population is zero then certainly its impact is zero. One candidate for N(n) might be n raised to some positive power, p. If p=1 then N and n are the same thing. Another candidate is the logarithm of (n+1). We need not specify the precise relationship, N(n), in what follows. Via experiment it can be coaxed from nature later. The only way that N depends upon time is parametrically through its dependence on n. In what follows we shall mean by N(t) the dependence N(n(t)). We may think of N as a surrogate for the number of members in the population. The population strength growth rate, g = g(t), is defined by
  • 13. Principle p. 13 g := dN dt (4.1) Like N, g too acquires its time dependence parametrically through n(t). g = (dN/dn)(dn/dt) To quantify how the environment affects the population we introduce the notion of ‘environmental favorability’. We'll designate it by the symbol, f. It represents the effect of the environment on the population. A population flourishes when the environment is favorable. Environmental favorability is what drives a population's success. But in the last section we arrived at a quantitative measure of success. The rate of growth of the population strength - 'the growth of growth' or dg/dt – measures success. Hence, that a population's success is generated entirely by the environment is expressed mathematically as: dg dt = (4.2) Since equation (4.2) says that success equals the favorability of the environment, it follows that f measures not only environmental favorability but also population success. We’re now prepared to caste the Opposition Principle as a mathematical statement. The Principle has two parts. 1. Any increase in population strength decreases favorability; the more the population's presence is felt the less favorable becomes the environment. 2. Any increase in the growth of that strength also decreases favorability.
  • 14. Principle p. 14 Put formally: That part of the change in f due to an increase in N is negative. Likewise the change in f due to an increase in g is negative. Here is the direct mathematical rendering of these two statements: !f !N < 0 and !f !g < 0 (4.3) We can implement these statements by introducing two parameters. Both w and α are non-negative real numbers and they have the dimensions of reciprocal time. (Negative w values are permitted but are redundant.) ! !N =" 2 and ! !g ="! (4.4) These partial differential equations can be integrated. The result is: f = !w2 N !!g + F(t) (4.5) The 'constant' (with respect to N and g) of integration, F(t), has an evident interpretation. It is the gratuitous favorability provided by nature; the gift of nature. Equation (4.5) says that environmental favorability consists of two parts. One part depends on the number and growth of the population being favored: the N and its time derivative, g. This part has two terms both of which always act to decrease favorability. These terms express the Opposition Principle.
  • 15. Principle p. 15 The other part - F(t) - is independent of N and of g. It is the gift of nature. There must be something in the environment that is favorable to population success but external to that population else the population would not exist in the first place. This gift of nature may depend cyclically on time. For example, seasonal variations are cyclical changes in favorability. Or it may remain relatively constant like the presence of air to breathe. It may also exhibit random and sometimes violent fluctuations like a volcanic eruption or unexpected rains on a parched earth. So it has a stochastic component. All of these are quite independent of the population under consideration. Inserting equations (4.1) and (4.2) into (4.5) we arrive at the promised differential equation governing population dynamics under the Opposition Principle. It is this. d2 N dt2 + ! dN dt +w2 N = F(t) (4.6) In the world of physical phenomena this equation is ubiquitous. Depending upon the meaning assigned to N it describes electrical circuits, mechanical systems, the production of sound in musical instruments and a host of other phenomena. So it is very well studied. The exact analytical solution to (4.6), yielding N(t) for any given F(t), is known. To explore some of the consequences of this differential equation we consider the easiest case; that the gift favorability is simply constant over an extended period of time. Assume F(t) = c independent of time. Non-periodic solutions arise if α ≥ 2w. One of these, displayed in Figure 1, produces results similar to the Verhulst equation. If α < 2w the solutions to (4.6) are periodic and are given by:
  • 16. Principle p. 16 N(t) = c w2 + Ae!!t/2 sin("t + a) (4.7) where the amplitude, A, and the phase, a, depend upon the conditions of the population at a designated time, say t=0. And the oscillation frequency, ω, is given by: ! := w 1!( " 2w )2 " # $ $ $ % & ' ' ' ' (4.8) Figure 3. Observational data on the population fluctuations of larch budmoth density is shown as black diamonds and squares. The smooth orange curve is a solution of Equation (4.7). In Figure 3, equation (4.7) is compared to empirical data. The figure shows the population fluctuations of larch budmoth density (Turchin et al. 2003) assembled from records gathered over a period of 40 yrs. The data points and lines connecting them are shown in black. The smooth orange curve in the background is a graph of equation (4.7) for particular values of the parameters.
  • 17. Principle p. 17 We assumed α is negligibly small so it can be set equal to zero. The frequency, ω, is taken to be 2π/(9yrs) = 0.7per year. The vertical axis represents N. In the units chosen for N, the amplitude, A, is taken to be 0.6 and c is taken to be 0.6 per year2 . The phase, a, is chosen so as to insure a peak in the population in the year 1963; a=3.49 radians. Because the fluctuations are so large the authors plotted n0.1 as the ordinate for their data presentation. The ordinate for the smooth orange theoretical curve is N. Looking at the fit in Figure 3, one might be led to conclude that the population strength, N(n), for the budmoth varies as the 0.1 power of n. But the precision of fit may not warrant this conclusion. The conclusions that may be warranted are these: Considering that no information about the details of budmoth life have gone into the computation the graphical correspondence is noteworthy. It suggests that those details of budmoth life are nature's way of implementing an overriding principle. The graphical correspondence means that, under a constant external environmental favorability, a population should behave not unlike that of the budmoth. Equation (4.7) admits of circumstances in which population extinction can occur. If A > c/w2 then N can drop to zero. Societies with zero population are extinct ones. (On attaining zero, N remains zero. The governing differential equation, (4.6), doesn't apply when N<0.) But the value of A derives from initial conditions; from N(t=0) and g(t=0). So depending upon the seed population and its initial growth rate the society may thrive or become extinct even in the presence of gift favorability, c. This
  • 18. Principle p. 18 result offers an explanation for the existence of the phenomenon of 'extinction debt' (Kuussaari et al. 2009) and a way to compute the relaxation time for delayed extinction. The case explored reveals that periodic population oscillations can occur without a periodic driving force. Even a steady favorability can produce population oscillations. 5. Conclusion What has been proposed and argued here is this: Regardless of the details by which it is accomplished, there may be a general principle operative in determining population dynamics among living things – the Opposition Principle. Its mathematical expression is realized in a differential equation which governs the evolution of any population. A solution of this equation compares favorably to empirical data on the larch budmoth. Figure 4. A theoretical population history that can result from the Opposition Principle differential equation. Among the plethora of solutions to the governing differential equation, (4.6), is this one: Upon a step increase in environmental favorability – say, in food
  • 19. Principle p. 19 abundance – the population may overshoot what the new environment can accommodate and then settle down after a few cycles. Figure 4 illustrates this behavior. That there are such solutions amounts to a prediction that population histories like that of Figure 4 will be found in nature. Having the Opposition Principle in mathematical form allows quantitative comparisons with empirical data. Observational evidence will support or refute the theory. References: Berryman, A. 2003 On principles, laws and theory in population ecology. Oikos 103, 695-701 Carroll, S. B. 2006 The Making of the Fittest. New York, NY: W.W. Norton Clutton-Brock, T. H. (editor) 1990 Reproductive Success : Studies of Individual Variation in Contrasting Breeding Systems. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press Coulson, T., Benton, T. G., Lundberg, P., Dall, S.R.X., Kendall, B.E. and Gaillard, J.-M. 2006 Estimating individual contributions to population growth: evolutionary fitness in ecological time. Proc. R. Soc. B 273, 547-555 Darwin, C. 1859 On The Origin of Species by Means of Natural Selection. London: John Murray Fisher, R. A. 1930 The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • 20. Principle p. 20 Gilbert, S.F. and Epel, D. 2009 Ecological Developmental Biology. Sunderland, MA: Sinauer Jablonka, E. and Raz, G. 2009 Transgenerational Epigenetic Inheritance: Prevalence, Mechanisms and implications for the study of heredity and evolution. Quarterly Review of Biology 84, 131-176 Jones, J. M. 1976 The r-K-Selection Continuum. The American Naturalist 110, 320-323 Kuussaari, M., Bommarco, R., Heikkinen, R.K., Helm, A., Krauss, J., Lindborg, R., Öckinger, E., Pärtel, M., Pino, J., Rodà, F., Stefanescu, C., Teder, T., Zobel, M. and Ingolf Steffan-Dewenter, I. 2009 Extinction debt: a challenge for biodiversity conservation. Trends Ecol. Evol. 24, 564-571 Kuno, E. 1991 Some strange properties of the logistic equation defined with r and K - inherent defects or artifacts. Researches on Population Ecology 33, 33-39 Malthus, T. 1798 An essay on the Principle of Population. London: J. Johnson McNamara, J.M. and Houston, A.I. 2009 Integrating function and mechanism. Trends Ecol. Evol. 24, 670-675 Michod, R. E. 1999 Darwinian Dynamics: Evolutionary Transitions in Fitness and Individuality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Nowak, M. A. 2006 Evolutionary Dynamics: Exploring the Equations of Life. Canada: Harvard Press
  • 21. Principle p. 21 Okada, H., Harada, H., Tsukiboshi, T., Araki, M. 2005 Characteristics of Tylencholaimus parvus (Nematoda: Dorylaimida) as a fungivorus nematode. Nematology 7, 843-849 Parry, G.D. 1981 The meanings of r- and K-selection. Oecologia 48, 260-264 Pelletier, F., Garant, D., and Hendry, A. P. 2009 Eco-evolutionary dynamics. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 364, 1483-1489 Ruokolainen, L., Lindéna, A., Kaitalaa, V. and Fowler, M. S. 2009 Ecological and evolutionary dynamics under coloured environmental variation Trends Ecol. Evol. 24, 555-563 Torres, J.-L., Pérez-Maqueo, O., Equihua, M., and Torres, L. 2009 Quantitative assessment of organism–environment couplings. Biol Philos. 24, 107–117 Turchin, P., Wood, S. N., Ellner, S.P., Kendall, B.E., Murdoch, W. W., Fischlin, A., Casas, J., McCauley, E. and Briggs, C. J. 2003 Dynamical effects of plant quality and parasitism on population cycles of larch budmoth. Ecology 84, 1207–1214 Vainstein, J.H., Rube J.M. and Vilar, J.M.G., 2007 Stochastic population dynamics in turbulent fields. Eur. Phys. J. Special Topics 146, 177-187 Verhulst, P-F., 1838 Notice sur la loi que la population poursuit dans son accroissement. Correspondance mathématique et physique 10, 113-121