SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 30
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 1
1
Can We Regulate Human Nature?
A Study of Financial Fraud, Government Regulation, and
The Principal-Agent Dilemma
Marketa Kreuzingerova
Brescia University
Dr. Rohnn Sanderson
Business Administration
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 2
2
Introduction
In recent years, corporate fraud has seemed to permeate the workings of the private
financial markets where dishonest accounting practices and extensive financial misstatements
led to the demise of America´s brightest and most promising enterprises. As a result of these
scandals, many Americans have been materially harmed. Thousands of jobs and retirement
savings in pension funds have been lost. Because of this, investor confidence has eroded
substantially. However, the greatest impact these crises have had on the world is that they
instilled fear in the average American citizen that private markets should not, and no longer
will, be trusted. Currently, they are seen as breeding ground for greedy, dishonest
businessmen.
The Enron debacle, which unfolded in the late months of 200119, seemed to be the
trigger for an avalanche of corporate scandals to come. In 2000, Enron reported over a 1.41
billion dollars in pretax profit and a share price of 90.56 dollars20. America´s favorite
company appeared to be in great financial shape and thriving. Positioning itself in the 7th
highest ranking on the Fortune 500 List in the same year, Enron was thought to be one of the
most successful innovators in the country, and the entire market was cheering it on as
investors were realizing capital gains on stock prices they otherwise wouldn’t have dreamed
of24.
After placing so much confidence in the company, it is easy to understand why
Enron´s collapse had such a devastating and profound impact on American financial markets.
Specifically, there were around 4,500 jobs lost directly related to Enron’s failure, with all
pension accounts frozen and never recovered2. While loyal employees found themselves
struggling to recover from the shock, investors lost 64.2 billion dollars, all in a matter of a few
days2. Through the practices of mark-to-market accounting, extensive off-balance-sheet debt
financing, and organization-wide internal control overrides, Enron transformed itself from a
promising new-industry business to the largest corporate bankruptcy to that date in the United
States of America10.
In the aftermath of the scandal, many began to question the trust placed in top
executives and the checks and balances present at those positions. Absorbing the losses
resulting from Enron´s failure, the public began, naturally, calling for more extensive
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 3
3
regulation. While CEO and CFO fraudulent activities within the company were at question,
the more disturbing factor was the complete failure of all external “watchdogs” to prevent, or
detect and correct, the fraud that was taking place. Indeed, none of the investor analysts, bond
rating agencies, independent auditors, or SEC oversight managed to uncover the
misstatements that some claim they simply did not want to be seen.
In either case, these failures have had grave impacts on the accounting profession,
which has lost most of its credibility, as well as American financial markets, whose
trustworthiness people stopped believing. Yet Enron was only the first of many
disappointments to come.
Tyco International, the next in line in the domino effect of failing corporations
following Enron´s collapse, did not come to its breaking point until a year later, when
substantial misappropriation of funds by Tyco’s CEO, Dennis Kozlowski, was discovered12.
Up to that point, Tyco appeared to be in perfect condition as it was constantly expanding its
market reach, from security to healthcare services, and disclosed revenues of over 36 billion
dollars in 20011.
However, when Kozlowski´s activities came to light in early 2002, additional issues
concerning the company´s honest practices started to surface. Later that year, it became clear
that the embezzlement of hundreds of millions of dollars in cash and other assets on
Kozlowski´s part was accompanied by 56 million dollars given out to employees to pay off
inter-company loans, related-party transactions that never appeared on the financial
statements, and false appreciation(insider trading) of the company stock1. After the start of the
investigation, other executives, including the CFO and the Chairman of the Board of
Directors, were accused of participating in the embezzlements and placed on trial12.
Again, the signals leading to the fraud discovery were overlooked and the very few
who saw what was coming were silenced, as in the case of Enron. The reason was simple;
Tyco International, then conducting operations in over 100 countries, reported profits that
were too good to jeopardize by unnecessary questioning1. However, in Tyco’s case, the
annual revenue growth of 48.7 percent from 1997 to 2001 was backed by real value created
through successful operation of the company12. Unlike Enron, Tyco International did not have
to face bankruptcy and managed to preserve most jobs as well as retirement funds12. While its
stock price decreased immensely, this did not prevent the company from eventual recovery.
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 4
4
In fact, Tyco has made extensive changes to its internal control environment as well as
ethical standards promoted within the company. This has allowed it to reclaim its success in
recent years. Despite a 2 billion-dollar write-off in the financial statements following the
scandal, Tyco continued to grow and now operates as three separate entities, each of which
became global leaders in their respective industry. This includes Tyco Healthcare, Tyco
Electronics, and Tyco Fire and Security12.
However, the recovery of Tyco International was a unique case of corporate fraud. As
other “too big to fail” corporations, including Sunbeam, WorldCom, and Duke Energy, began
collapsing, people all over the country were on the edge of their seats calling for more
regulation to prevent these situations in the future. Consequently, this continuous pressure
from the public led to a fast adoption of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, which appeared to
have dealt with the issues of fraud taking place at that time. Following the enactment of the
law, there was a period of time during which the public came to believe that the problems
inherent to financial markets had been solved.
Then, in the late 2000s, the “financial wizard” and genius investment fund broker
Bernie Madoff came around. He offered double-digit returns when other investor groups were
only generating single. Clients flooded to Bernard L. Madoff Investment Securities, LLC
(BLMIS) seeking greater capital gains as well as increases in annual incomes23. As in the
previous cases, many failed to question the workings behind such returns as long as their
appetite for additional funds was being satisfied. Among others, his clients included large not-
for-profit organizations, usually charitable funds, formed by affluent couples and designated
for donation purposes15.
While the clients entrusted their savings with Madoff and were enjoying the unreal
returns, the former NASDAQ Chairman was very well aware that the entire system was but a
well-orchestrated show15. In fact, the profits generated by BLMIS were nothing but numbers
printed on paper, and consequently, his clients ended up with double-digit paper profits.
Unlike the other cases, where internal control and organizational checks and balances failed to
function properly, in the Madoff scenario, there were none5.
Madoff, being the owner as well as President of the company, had unlimited access
and control over the financial statements and their issuance. In fact, Madoff himself was
responsible for creating these financial statements by selecting stock prices that would
complement his earnings projections15. While a simple confirmation of quoted prices would
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 5
5
have uncovered such fraudulent practices, none dared to question a company headed by a
former NASDAQ chairman, especially when he was generating such “magical” profits5.
As a result, it took several years before Madoff´s Ponzi Scheme turned into a public
scandal and BLMIS came crashing down with it. Naturally, as in the previous cases, the
consequences were grave. In the aftermath of the scandal, it was estimated that Madoff´s
clients lost approximately 50 billion dollars in their investments, even though the actual losses
incurred may be higher6. Overall, about 12,000 individual investors were affected. Many of
these found their hedge funds liquidated to absorb the impacts of the fraud5. In fact, Madoff´s
Ponzi Scheme had a much more profound effect on the American economy as many funds
dedicated to medical and other scientific research were frozen and funding for these programs
disappeared4.
In response to the scandal, Congress drafted and adopted the Dodd-Frank Act, also
known as the Wall-Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, in an effort to calm the
increasing pressures from the voting public5. While it will be discussed in more detail later in
the paper, this law was aimed at decreasing the probability of loss to financial market
consumers5. In the meantime, many started questioning the credibility of the financial markets
again and what followed we came to know as the Great Recession.
While the case studies discussed above are undoubtedly unique in their nature, we can
identify certain attributes that all of them, and many others, share. First, the uncovering of
every fraud had some negative consequences, even though the extent varied from scenario to
scenario depending on the condition of the company. As illustrated by Tyco’s case, we could
see that fraud did not necessarily cause collapse if the entity had been backed by some
intrinsic value.
Second, each fraud case ignited a public outrage that eroded much of the investor
confidence and trust in the financial markets. Moreover, many started to despise the financial
community as businessmen came to be portrayed as evil profit-seekers rather than value-
creators. In fact, some have even started questioning human nature itself as a result of these
scandals; in recent years, we have seen the emergence of the field of behavioral finance,
which attempts to describe management behavior in psychological terms.
Third, this fear and questioning of human nature instilled in much of the public the
sense that the average citizen needs to be protected from corporate executives and their
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 6
6
“dirty” tricks by regulation. As we can see, each case resulted in some form of regulation,
usually called for by the general public that was meant to prevent the next case from
happening. However, it was never so.
Therefore, this paper takes a different approach to analyzing fraud; it starts by an
introduction to the economic phenomenon also known as the principal-agent problem, then
introduces the specific impacts this concept had in each one of our scenarios, and concludes
by examining the benefits and costs of the regulation that was adopted in response to these
scandals. Finally, an argument for continued trust in the credibility of the financial markets
will be made. However, as with any other market analysis, this will not be done without a call
for ever-present caution and questioning.
Analysis
In private markets, we experience several phenomena that most would refer to as
market failures, which are instances when the markets do not generate optimal results, and
inefficiencies are generated. One of these phenomena is the so-called moral hazard, in which
one market participant transfers part of the possibility of loss to another party, effectively
reduces their cost of transacting, and therefore takes actions of greater risk. Often, because of
this greater risk, the likelihood of loss increases, and these losses are partially borne by
outside parties25.
Moral hazard occurs when there is incomplete or imperfect information, meaning that
one of the parties involved in the transaction often has different or greater-quality information
than the other parties. Sometimes, not enough information is available on either side of the
market. Consequently, a transaction carried out under imperfect information results in a moral
hazard25. In private markets, we often experience a unique form of moral hazard-the principal-
agent problem21.
A common example of the principal-agent problem is illustrated by the voter-
politician relationship, where politicians (agents) do not always do what is in the best interest
of the voters (principals) 9. While the principal-agent dilemma can be found in a multitude of
everyday situations, from classroom interaction to car purchasing, the problem most
commonly associated with this form of moral hazard is the issue of corporate ownership9.
The problem inherent in the establishment and operation of every corporate business is
that the owners, who initially supply financial as well as other resources to get the corporation
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 7
7
on its feet, cannot or simply do not wish to make the time commitment needed to conduct its
everyday operations. Their desired level of commitment, then, is limited to the receipt of
periodic income from earnings and perhaps maintenance of a certain level of oversight over
company performance. Because they have already invested their time and money into the
firm, these owners, also known as initial investors, are mainly looking for a stable return on
their investment11.
Eventually, additional investors, either common or preferred stockholders, provide
equity capital for the firm to satisfy its financing needs. Even though their commitment does
not seem as extensive as that of the initial founders, these shareholders, too, look for a return
on their investment without unnecessary participation. It is important to realize that while a
large portion of the U.S. stock market is occupied by professional institutional investors, these
shareholders can also be families, individuals looking for retirement income, or college
students wishing to pay off their tuition. Naturally, these market participants do not have time
to devote to everyday operations of the company11.
In order for investors to achieve their desired state of affairs, they enter into a formal
contract with another party, represented by management-in this case the corporate executives.
This agreement, also known as an agency contract, puts management in control of operations,
including planning, production, and performance monitoring. This is done in exchange for
agreed-upon compensation. Most importantly, management is expected to maximize the long-
term value of the corporation, reflected by the average stock price over time, which then
generates positive long-run returns for the owners11.
In theory, such a contract appears to provide a neat solution to a multitude of
problems. While managers are compensated for their time and skilled labor spent on running
the firm, owners agree to give up part of the company profits in order to ensure stable
investment returns. However this is where the principal-agent problem, as well as economic
theory in general, come into play. As we know, all individuals have slightly different
personalities, attributes, and characteristics. What is common to each and every man on the
planet, however, is their self-interested nature that drives every individual to pursue activities
that best meet their unique preferences. Consequently, this special, unifying feature of the
human race can cause the greatest of problems for societies all over the world.
As surprising as it may seem, self-interest not only applies to you, me, and the rest of
our community, it also applies to corporate executives. This phenomenon, then, becomes the
heart of the principal-agent problem we experience in contemporary corporations. Because
both the owners (“principals”), and the managers (“agents”) are driven by their own self-
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 8
8
interest, they have entirely different incentives that can lead to misallocations or inefficient
uses of the company’s resources9. As aforementioned, the principals are looking for
maximization of the long-term stock price, while the agents, even the most selfless ones, tend
to pursue interests unique to their own needs21.
Therefore, agents often take actions that are not deemed by principals as the most
appropriate; this misalignment of incentives is known as the agency problem9. Common
symptoms of such problem often include excessive risk-taking by management as they are
partially shielded from the risk of loss25. If too much risk is taken on by the agents, they do
incur losses in the form of lost compensation, impaired reputation in the marketplace, and the
opportunity cost of searching for a new job. However, their personal assets are protected and
in certain cases, sudden dismissal can often lead to substantial severance packages. However,
this does not necessarily make it beneficial for the manager to take actions that will get him
fired; it does, on the other hand, illustrate that costs incurred as a result of too much risk
taking are relatively low for the executives.
Clearly, the remaining costs spillover to other market participants, whether they are
directly involved in the agency contract, or not9. Most often, principals incur losses when part
of their returns on investment is forgone. While these costs can be material to the individual
investor, it is important to note that the personal assets of each and every shareholder are
protected by corporate law; the extent of the loss that can be borne by investors only amounts
to the size of their investment and creditors cannot make a claim on their personal property11.
In addition, costs of fraud are often borne by other stakeholders involved with the
company, such as its employees, retirees, suppliers, customers, and industry competitors. As
in the case of Enron and many others, retirement savings were forever lost for those who
worked for the company, and many found themselves struggling to find work. Moreover,
other natural gas companies, while maintaining healthy internal control and steady operations,
saw their stock price plummet alongside Enron as investors lost confidence in the entire
industry.
Finally, unrelated third parties may be forced to bear part of the cost. These third
parties, in our case the taxpaying and voting public, incurred costs in the form of lost
production but also the additional tax imposed to fund new regulation. Because third parties
absorb part of these losses, the social cost of risk-taking and fraud in general is higher than the
private cost incurred by the agents alone. This creates a negative externality, leaving the
society with a greater amount of fraud than is desired. To illustrate, let us examine how the
principal-agent problem manifested itself in each of the three case studies.
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 9
9
An essential element of every principal-agent problem is the extent of controls present
to prevent or detect discrepancies or outright fraud in the system. Here, we focus on two
main forms of control relevant to our case scenarios-internal, which includes the checks and
balances as well as corporate governance and organizational culture, and external, which is
represented by a myriad of “watchdog” institutions that maintain additional oversight of the
company´s operations22. Overall, the combined operating effectiveness of these controls
determines the risk that fraud will not be prevented or detected, which in turn determines the
likelihood of fraud occurrence22.
control environment
external auditors
investing public
regulatory oversight
Figure 1
Levels of FraudDetection
Fraud Potential
Fraud Occurence
Detection Level 1
Detection Level 2
control activities
monitoring
financial analysts,
credit rating agencies
Internal Control
External Control
First, internal control has several key components including the control environment,
control activities, and monitoring of the controls in place. Referring to the fraud case studies,
the control environment will be the single most decisive component in our analysis. As per
professional accounting literature, company control environment consists of appreciation for
ethical business conduct, an effective board of directors, and properly designed organizational
structure, which also includes the corporate culture22.
These components also directly relate to the theoretical framework surrounding the
classic fraud triangle introduced by Statements of Auditing Standards No.99, which defines
the conditions that must be present for one to commit fraud10. Referring to Figure 2, we can
see that for individual fraud, usually in the form of misappropriation of assets (defalcation) 22,
to occur, three conditions need to be satisfied. First, the individual must have an incentive or a
pressure to be able to commit the fraud; second, the attitude of the employee must be one that
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 10
10
justifies the fraud. Last, an opportunity such as lack of or malfunction in internal controls
must allow the individual to carry the fraud out10.
Similarly, in a large corporate setting, dealing mostly with fraudulent financial
reporting on the management level22, the fraud triangle is adapted to reflect the changing
organizational scales. First, the leadership style of executives can provide incentives or exert
pressure on employees to falsely improve their performance. Second, the corporate culture
present within the organization often affects the attitudes of employees towards fraud; a
hostile, cut-throat environment may make it more appealing to justify fraudulent behavior.
Finally, management controls and their operating effectiveness should function to eliminate
most opportunities for employees to commit fraud10.
B) corporate
B) attitude culture
A) incentive/ A) leadership C) management
pressure C) opportunity style controls
Figure 2
FraudTriangle per SAS No.99
Individual-level Organization-wide
In the case-scenario discussion that follows, each of these conditions will play a key
role in determining why fraud was not prevented, and, most importantly, not detected by the
internal control systems in place. Additionally, the external watchdogs failed to report the
fraud that was slipping through the checks and balances within. Briefly mentioned in the
discussion below, the failures of banking institutions, credit rating agencies, and stock
underwriters to report unsound accounting practices contributed to the amount of loss that
stakeholders incurred when the scandals unfolded.
Referring back to the agency relationship between stockholders and managers, we can
see that management override of internal control is a symptom of the principal-agent problem
rather than its cause. While both internal and external controls play a critical role in these case
scenarios, it is the divergent incentives of principals and agents that give rise to the
phenomenon. These incentives give rise to three distinct situations that we commonly
encounter when dealing with the principal-agent problem.
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 11
11
agents cheat the principals principals assume the role of agents
principals lie to themselves
Fraud-relatedprincipal-agent problem
Figure 3
First, as outlined in Figure3, the agents themselves tend to break the rules of the
contract and work the systems in place to better suit their preferences. Often, this is a result of
poor incentive alignment by the Board of Directors in terms of management compensation.
While it is clear that the principals’ objective is to maximize the company’s long-term value,
it is often difficult for them to design such a compensation package that would incentivize
management to truly pursue this long-run objective11.
When studying the fraud scenarios, it is obvious that misaligned incentives were at the
heart of the problem at both Enron and Tyco International. To illustrate, Enron executives
received compensation based on meeting several performance criteria, but focusing mainly on
earnings per share (EPS). Because much of Enron´s operations’ focus was on maximizing
EPS, many ignored the fact that most company growth was done through extensive debt
financing, which did not create additional value for shareholders. The executives, however,
collected substantial amounts of compensation as long as the share price increased; and
therefore management made sure it did26.
Over the years, total compensation for the 5 highest ranking Enron executives grew
from 37.46 million dollars in 1996 to 107.67 million dollars in 2000, most of which was
allocated to bonus payments and stock grants26. Stock options, at the time, were the popular
means of aligning management values with the long-term stock price maximization goal of
shareholders. Through granting ownership at discounted prices, principals hoped that
managers would take a more long-run focus in operations and strategy-making. Enron
executives, however, had few restrictions prohibiting them from cashing the stock options
shortly after the exercise date, which defied the purpose of the stock option plan26.
What resulted, then, was a vicious cycle of constant increases in the short-term share
price, quick exercising of stock options, capital gains realization, and push for additional
share price increases. In 2000 alone, Enron CEO Ken Lay earned 123.4 million dollars while
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 12
12
former CEO Jeffrey Skilling cashed 62.5 million dollars by exercising their stock options in
time. This excessive focus on share price and EPS not only shifted management’s focus to the
short run, but it also eroded any intrinsic value the company still had27.
Share prices and stock trading played a critical role in the Tyco International, Inc.
fraud case as well. Over their years in function, top executives managed to gain 430 million
dollars at the company’s expense through fraudulent trading. This again reflected the short-
term focus that management had which, eventually, eroded Tyco’s average share price and
long-term value. Another fraud component prominent at Tyco was the misappropriation of
company assets for personal use by the CEO, Dennis Kozlowski, and his closest advisors12.
Over the years, Kozlowski managed to acquire a 16.8 million-dollar apartment on
Fifth Avenue, pay off an 80,000-dollar American Express bill, and organize his wife’s
birthday party in Sardinia for 2.1 million dollars by covering these expenses from Tyco’s
funds. Other executives, including the CFO Mark Swartz and General Counsel Mark Belnick,
received millions of dollars for personal purchases including real estate, yachts, fine arts, and
business investments. Clearly, the focus was not on long-run shareholder value maximization,
but on generating sufficient profit to allow for embezzlements of such extent to go unnoticed1.
Considering the amounts that were either falsely disclosed, as in the case of Enron, or
outright embezzled, as in Tyco’s case, one begins to wonder how such transactions remained
unnoticed for such a long period of time. Surely, there must have been some level of
suspicion when millions of dollars were misplaced. It is important to remember, though, that
in both cases, the conditions described in Figure 2 all reached an alignment that allowed fraud
to go unreported. To illustrate how the combination of poor leadership, hostile corporate
culture, and weak management controls prevented all actors involved from reporting these
fraudulent activities, we turn our attention to the environment in which both Enron and Tyco
employees operated.
First, the company culture at Enron was one that honored innovation, exceptional
performance, and individualism, but at the same time despised failure or anyone failing to
succeed in the ever-increasing race for greater profit. Jeffrey Skilling himself promoted
behavior with a razor-sharp profit focus and discouraged questioning of methods that
generated it. All Enron employees were periodically evaluated under the Peer Review
Committee (PRC) system, which eliminated the worst-performing 15 percent of employees
every six months. Through the PRC system and a set of incentives that idolized profit-
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 13
13
oriented behavior, Enron´s employees quickly learned to seek gains whenever they could,
even at the expense of their colleagues. In their never-ending bonus chasing, they happily
failed to question their sources10.
Second, the leadership style instituted by Skilling only further promoted the
individualistic, short-term, performance-oriented behavior that slowly eroded the company´s
value. Since compensation in the form of stock option plans was tied so closely to share price,
most employees focused on share price maximization only, with little regard for its long-term
effects. For instance, John Arnold, one of Enron’s traders, conducted transactions that
generated over 700 million dollars in “book” profit, which earned him a 15 million dollar
bonus that he cashed and then terminated his employment10.
Finally, the ever-increasing profits and related capital gains of all Enron employees
helped loosen the integrity of everyone involved, even those charged with internal oversight.
Even though Enron championed a seemingly superior system of management controls, the
compensation-related incentives created many opportunities for control overrides. For
instance, both the Risk Assessment and Control Group charged with evaluation of new
contracts and the Board of Directors failed to report questionable practices of management
because the company’s continued profitability, not professional objectivity, was of their
primary interest. Finally, the checks and balances in place were completely circumvented by
Skilling, which was of little concern as long as the stock price was growing10.
In a similar fashion, most of the fraud taking place at Tyco International was linked
directly to its CEO, Dennis Kozlowski. From the very beginning, Kozlowski’s management
style was characterized by aggressive growth. This would not have been a problem if it was
complimented by strong internal control and oversight. However, at Tyco, this approach was
coupled with a unique form of decentralization that made such oversight difficult to exercise.
Even before Kozlowski’s time as CEO, he worked hard not only to expand the company’s
operations, but also to diversify it into separate units. As a result, Tyco International
constituted four different business units- including electronics, medical products, security
services, and flow control12.
While this approach generated immense growth for Tyco’s shareholders, it also
allowed Kozlowski to single-handedly control each of the four segments. Because the heads
of these business units reported directly to Kozlowski, who himself presented the company
performance to the Board of Directors, it was relatively easy for him to conceal true
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 14
14
operations to those charged with oversight. In addition, Kozlowski enhanced this
decentralized structure with a management bonus system that seemingly reduced
compensation, but in fact gave executives greater power over their paychecks. His leadership
style did not allow questions regarding the company’s direction or its current activities, and
anyone raising them was quickly silenced. In fact, Kozlowski was responsible for terminating
his own employees who were doubting the reported numbers. Also, he exercised power over
the external environment, such as ensuring the termination of a Merrill Lynch analyst who
was questioning the company’s operating results12.
As a result, the leadership style Kozlowski had implemented granted him extreme
power over the company and its operating environment. The Board of Directors, already
weakened by decentralization, also consisted of members who were, in most cases, personally
elected by Kozlowski. These members, while not in absolute control of the Board, also held
all the critical management positions at Tyco. Most of the Board and the company was
controlled by Mark Swartz, CFO, Joseph Welch, CEO of one of Tyco’s business units, and
Frank Walsh, Jr., the director of the Board. While there were certain indicators that
Kozlowski’s behavior was unethical, and even illegal, these members, who had a major
conflict of interest, helped conceal and often participated in the fraud that was taking place12.
Clearly, the CEO’s leadership style as well as poorly functioning management controls
provided great opportunity for fraud to go uncovered. However, unlike the Enron case, Tyco
International’s corporate culture did not glorify the unethical practices that were taking place.
While Enron’s employees were encouraged to turn questionable profits to enable their lavish
lifestyles, the image that Tyco portrayed was one of modesty. Even though Kozlowski’s
actions did not match this general message, most employees were never made aware of how
the executives really lived. Quite contrarily, Kozlowski made it a point to advertise the
frugality with which management operated even in his public interviews12.
This approach, although seemingly trivial, helped Tyco recover from the losses that
resulted from the 2002 scandal. Unlike Enron, Tyco’s employees were still creating value for
their shareholders. While the executives misused some of those assets for personal use, this
value-backed approach provided a basis for a gradual recovery12.
We can see that the first manifestation of the principal-agent problem, where agents
cheat principals because of inverted incentives, can be greatly reduced by proper
implementation of strong oversight and other well-designed management controls22. In the
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 15
15
cases of Enron and Tyco, however, these controls were completely subverted, which created
the environment that allowed management to commit fraud on an organization-wide scale.
The detection of this fraud and subsequent correction of related misstatements, will be in
question next.
Referring back to Figure 3, another problem we encounter in the principal-agent
dilemma is that in certain situations, the principals fail to recognize that fraud is taking place.
Rather, principals refuse to act responsibly even though the indicators of unethical behavior
are clearly present. Often, this is a result of extensive conflicts of interest that were also
present in both of our case studies. As illustrated above, the Boards of Directors charged with
internal oversight at both Enron and Tyco lost their objectivity as their personal well-being
was largely dependent on the success of the company under their control.
At Enron, the Board of Directors was generously compensated for the company’s
success in growing the share price and therefore its members’ personal stakes in the continued
operation of the company were high29. Because Enron’s stock price never stopped growing,
the incentive for Board members to report unethical practices was nonexistent. Instead, most
tended to overlook the fact that profits were being misstated because the false earnings report
often resulted in very real compensation. In fact, the average compensation of a director was
400,000 dollars in the year 2001, and bonuses for additional consulting services were
generous29. Other controls, including the finance, compliance, and audit committees, as well
as the financial disclosure director, were in a situation parallel to that of the Board, and gave
up professional skepticism for greater compensation10.
At Tyco, the Board of Directors was not only overlooking the presence of fraud;
rather, it was directly participating in it. Many, while not all, Board members received hidden
payments from the company that served to satisfy the members’ personal needs. For instance,
the director, Frank Walsh, was granted a secret 20 million dollar bonus for his services in the
acquisition sector. In addition, other companies under Walsh’s control often contracted with
Tyco, and they received generous compensation for their services12.
When Tyco’s fraud surfaced, Mark Swartz, CFO, and Dennis Kozlowski, CEO, were
accused of misappropriating over 170 million dollars in assets and realizing gains of 430
million dollars on illegal trading of Tyco’s stock12. Clearly, these related-party transactions
eliminated any objectivity of the Board, and the hidden payments helped many of its members
overlook the lack thereof.
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 16
16
Moreover, Enron and Tyco experienced conflicts of interest that extended beyond the
firms’ boundaries. In both cases, outside institutions, including the bankers and financial
analysts, had little incentive to launch investigation of questionable corporate behavior of
their clients. Because these institutions had high stakes in the client’s earnings, they feared
that reporting these practices would threaten the revenue generated by servicing the client. For
instance, both Citigroup Inc. and JP Morgan Chase were fined over 225 million dollars by the
SEC in the aftermath of the Enron scandal for loaning funds to Enron in a way that improved
the appearance of the firm’s cash flows. However, Enron’s bankers were not the only ones at
fault. Financial analysts, along with credit rating agencies, were all partaking in the vicious
cycle of profit-chasing and thus failed to exercise professional judgment in evaluating the
company8.
In Tyco International’s case, the conflicts of interest were of equal proportions. As
aforementioned, Merrill Lynch failed to adjust its rating of the company stock and instead
terminated the employee raising who questioned Tyco’s transparency. This was a rational
approach for Merrill Lynch as their company’s revenue-generating abilities were closely tied
to those of Tyco. In fact, Merrill Lynch not only provided consulting services on the division
of frequent mergers and acquisitions, but it also acted as a major underwriter of Tyco’s
stock12. Clearly, downgrading the stock of one of its clients would hurt the performance of the
financial giant as well; therefore, the integrity had to go out the door to preserve the revenues.
Finally, the actors blamed the most for their shortcoming in discovering and reporting
these misstatements were the external auditors. In the wake of both scandals, much attention
was turned to the audit firms responsible for expressing unmodified opinions on the clearly
misstated financial statements. In the case of Enron, the scandal itself proved fatal to its
external auditors, Arthur Andersen & Company. At Tyco, the impact was not as extensive but
brought losses in trust and reputation to PricewaterhouseCoopers (Pwc) 12.
Naturally, the public looked to both accounting firms for independence, professional
skepticism, and objectivity that would ensure the discovery and subsequent disclosure of
fraud. However, they overlooked the fact that these external auditors, while independent in
form, faced the same conflicts of interest as any other institution transacting with their fraud-
affected clients. In fact, auditor independence was practically nonexistent in matter as revenue
ties between the client and its auditor were profound13.
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 17
17
Because accounting firms generated most of their revenue through consulting,
information system design and implementation, and management advice, the audits were
often pushed to the margin of the budget. As a result, audits were not only performed by
inexperienced staff, but the auditors themselves were pressured to perform the examination
quickly and in less detail14. Because Enron represented its second-biggest client, Arthur
Andersen was willing to overlook discrepancies in internal control as well as financial
statement presentation to preserve non-attest revenue20.
In addition, auditor independence was reduced to minimal levels as Andersen
employees in Houston were granted several offices at Enron’s headquarters and regularly took
part in company activities with other Enron employees. The lines were further blurred by
frequent interchange of personnel between both companies; indeed, Andersen auditors were
often hired by Enron to work on certain projects and vice versa. As a result, the auditors lost
their independence but also got extensive exposure to the internal practices taking place at
Enron13.
Because Andersen auditors were aware of the fraud that they failed to disclose, they
attempted to cover up their misconduct by shredding thousands of work papers and other
related audit documentation from the years 1997 to 2000. This action later resulted in an
investigation of the firm and ultimately led to its dissolution20.
When looking at the proportion of audit and non-audit revenue generated by the
accounting firms, it becomes obvious that extensive conflicts of interest prevented these
external monitors from establishing independence. While Arthur Andersen received 25
million dollars for performing the external audit, it was also paid an additional 27 million
dollars for other services13.
The audit revenues tied to Tyco that were generated by PricewaterhouseCoopers in
2001 amounted to 13.2 million dollars, which was only a small fraction of the 51.1 million
dollars paid for all of Pwc’s services12. This disproportion of fees, coupled with a direct
incentive for continued success of their client, created an environment where both quality and
accuracy of audits were secondary to revenue generation.
From the illustrations provided above, it is clear that those charged with oversight
within as well as outside the companies had little motivation to investigate the discrepancies
they encountered in dealing with the clients. Because the auditors’ revenues were tied to the
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 18
18
clients’, the incentive was to overlook the facts and hope that others would do the same,
which proved to be a sustainable practice for several years.
Referring back to Figure 3, the last manifestation of the principal-agent problem
emerges when principals also assume the role of agents. The Madoff Ponzi Scheme serves as
a perfect illustration of this form of principal-agent dilemma. Because Bernie Madoff acted as
both the principal, the founder and owner of BMLIS, and the agent, the chief managing
partner of the company, the incentives to cheat were even greater. First, Madoff did not face
costs in the form of repercussion from the directors or other owners, which reduced his total
costs of fraud. Second, his investment firm was organized as a limited liability corporation,
which shielded Madoff himself from creditors that would make claims on his personal assets
should losses occur6.
As a result, the objectives of the agent were perfectly aligned with those of the
principal because both resided in the same individual. Consequently, Madoff was able to
extract over 65 billion dollars from his clients through false generation of trading reports, and
this Ponzi scheme helped him realize 20 million dollars in personal gains. By accepting
clients who were looking for exceptional returns, accumulating their savings, seemingly
investing them in overseas markets, and using the accounts to pay off other clients, Madoff
orchestrated the largest Ponzi scheme to that date. Because no trading actually occurred,
Madoff was forced to create false confirmations, reports, financial statements, and SEC
filings23. In his plea allocution, he admitted to authorizing audit reports and other SEC
documentation and submitting them to be filed even though he was aware that they were
completely misstated15.
As in the two previous cases, the investors had a tendency to overlook the whole truth
about Madoff’s trading strategy. Similar to Enron’s Board of Directors, Madoff’s clients
enjoyed the profits they read in the reports and failed to question the mechanisms behind
them23. Indeed, none of his clients questioned the split-strike conversion strategy that Madoff
claimed to had invented simply because it was too good to be doubted15. Moreover, Madoff’s
clients put much trust into the BMLIS owner based on the extensive experience that he had
accumulated over the years in the financial markets. Clearly, the co-founder of NASDAQ and
SEC trading advisor took advantage of much blind trust from these clients who failed to see
beyond his public image23.
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 19
19
As illustrated above, all three forms of the principal-agent problem, whether it is
agents cheating the system, principals lying to themselves, or agents simultaneously acting as
principals, can generate outcomes with gravely negative consequences. In the wake of all
three scandals, many were startled to find that private markets gains sometimes get offset by
losses, and the negative impacts of these corporate failures caused a huge public outcry.
Consequently, there was a great push for additional regulation as many individuals lost their
faith in the stock market, or the corporate world altogether.
Because the media linked much of the losses and pain to the executives who were also
the faces of their respective corporations, many laid blame on them and came to believe that
all executives were driven by self-interest and greed. In fact, the percentage of individuals
who put “hardly any” trust in executives when asked increased from 11.7 percent to 17.3
percent after the Enron scandal3. As such, the average citizen felt the need to defend
themselves against these dangerous individuals, and naturally, called for protection in the
form of government reform. Since the Enron scandal was often linked to deregulation of the
utilities industry, it appeared that additional legislation was an appropriate solution.
In its outrage, the public failed to look beyond what was really happening in the
financial world; they focused their attention on the symptoms of the scandals instead of
addressing the underlying causes. At the time, the average investor who lost their savings due
to Enron’s failure gave little regard to the economic concepts that initially caused the
problem, and rightfully so. As a result of the public’s demand for a fast fix, Congress enacted
the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 in response to the Enron scandal16, and the Wall-Street
Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010, which addressed Madoff’s Ponzi scheme5.
The Sarbanes-Oxley Act (Sarbox), signed by George W. Bush on July 30 of 2002, was
only one of many regulations created to boost investor confidence in the stock markets across
the U.S. history. Drafted in hand with the Securities and Exchange Commission, the Act had
two major objectives. First, it sought to re-establish integrity in the financial markets and
therefore increase investor confidence. Second, it strived to prevent future fraud cases through
introduction of new disclosure requirements16.
While the scope of the legislation was very broad, the key issues addressed included
financial statement disclosure, external auditor independence, and integrity of the accounting
profession in general. First, the adoption of Sarbox mandated that corporate executives,
mainly CEOs and CFOs, accept direct responsibility for the content and presentation of the
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 20
20
financial statements. Under Sarbox, both the CEO and CFO must certify that the financials
are accurately stated in all material respects and full disclosure has been achieved. Because
the Act increased the penalties for false representations, the cost of committing fraud through
false financial reporting has increased for executives16.
While corporate executives were blamed for committing the fraud, the external
auditors were the second most targeted actors in all three of the scandals. As a result, much of
the Act focused its attention on enhancing auditor independence, which was so obviously
lacking in the cases discussed above. While new requirements were numerous, a few key
rules affected nearly every accounting firm in the country. First, public accounting companies
were prohibited from performing certain services for clients they were engaged in an external
audit with16. Second, the proportion of audit and non-audit fees was to be disclosed in the
financial statements, along with a Board of Directors statement acknowledging those services
and their impact on auditor independence22.
Third, all audit committees were now required to consist of outside directors only, and
all auditing matters, including planning and compensation, were to be settled through dealings
with the committee rather than company management. Finally, public accounting firms
performing more than 100 issuer audits were to be inspected every year and partners on
engagements were to rotate among clients every 5 years16.
Lastly, because the accounting profession was no longer trusted to operate effectively
under self-regulation, Sarbox created the Public Company Accounting Oversight Board
(PCAOB), which was charged with oversight over public accounting in general. Representing
a subdivision of the SEC, the PCAOB has broad implications for both accounting firms and
their clients. Among others, the Board enforces standards put in place by Sarbox, but can also
modify or completely reject any rules adopted by the Auditing Standards Board (ASB). As
such, it exercises great control over the accounting profession, and has the power to directly
affect the “rules of the game” adopted by the financial markets16.
Clearly, the scope of the Sarbox legislation is very broad. Even though the perceived
benefits include increased investor confidence, greater ease of capital acquisition by public
corporations, and future fraud prevention, a true measure of its utility will not be available for
years to come. The costs, on the other hand, have already been measured through research,
and they have proven to be immense.
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 21
21
However, even such extensive regulation as the Sarbanes-Oxley Act did not prevent
the financial world from experiencing another fraud-related scandal. Only a few years later,
the world watched as the Madoff scandal unfolded and the subprime mortgage loan market
bubble burst. In an attempt to calm the public outrage that followed, the government rushed to
the rescue again with additional regulation, the well-known Dodd-Frank Act of 20105.
Enacted on July 21 of 2010, the Wall-Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act was
adopted in response to the failures in the financial sector, particularly affecting the every-day
operations of banking institutions and trading companies. While the implications are nearly
impossible to summarize, the contents of the Act itself can be divided into several key
sections. Financial Stability Reform, Agency Oversight Reform, Securitization Reform,
Derivatives Regulation, Investor Protection Reform, Credit Rating Agency Reform,
Compensation and Corporate Governance, and the Volcker Rule are all components of this
seemingly all-encompassing legislation. Rather than focusing on regulating the actors charged
with outside oversight, this Act seeks to directly regulate the financial institutions
themselves17.
Relevant to the problems addressed in this paper, the Dodd-Frank Act seeks to impose
extensive restrictions on derivative trading as well as securitization by banking institutions.
Through the establishment of the Financial Stability Oversight Council, the legislation
imposes rules ranging from risk retention by securitizers to prohibition of proprietary trading
by bankers. In essence, the Derivative and Securitization sections of the Act aim to amend
previous regulation by strengthening the oversight, disclosure, and documentation in these
respective industry segments17.
Further, the Investor Protection Reform focuses on improving investor understanding
of financial markets through additional disclosure requirements enforced by the SEC. This
new function also mandates that periodic studies be conducted by the SEC on reporting
standards or lack thereof, self-regulation of certain organizations, analyst-related conflicts of
interest, and so forth. Finally, the creation of the Investor Advisory Committee, a sub-section
of the SEC, is aimed at further increasing investor confidence and thus bringing capital back
into financial markets17.
In addition, a portion of the Act is devoted to addressing corporate governance
structures as well as the compensation packages that executives receive. Mostly focusing on
additional disclosure by corporations, the Compensation and Corporate Governance section
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 22
22
also requires that executive compensation be reduced in the event that accounting
misstatements occur. Further, independence issues are addressed through new rules imposed
on corporate compensation committees17.
Similar to the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, the main objective of the Dodd- Frank Act
of 2010 was to boost the falling investor confidence in the financial markets17. In theory, an
increase in investor trust in the markets would also enhance the ease of capital formation and
acquisition as investors would become more likely to provide their savings to corporations.
While the objectives were clearly designed with good intentions in mind, it will be very
difficult to evaluate the actual benefits provided by these Acts. First, the benefits will be
nearly impossible to quantify because of the nature of the industry; second, the Acts may
produce unwanted secondary effects that might completely offset any benefits created.
While no exact measures can be provided at this time, many researchers set out to
estimate the impacts that both Sarbox and Dodd Frank have had on the financial community.
When looking at the research conducted, we find that while the benefits are questionable, the
costs are very real, and indeed have been measured to be extensive.
First, the costs related to the Sarbanes-Oxley Act have been relatively easy to observe
because the legislation has been in place for over a decade. While researchers differ in the
exact estimations of the Act-related costs, we can use these figures to at least approximate the
scope of Sarbox´s impact. In general, the costs associated with the implementation of Sarbox
can be divided into direct, or auditing and administration costs, and indirect, or opportunity
costs. According to the Academy of Management Perspectives, in the years following the
Act’s adoption, the audit fees amounted to 8.5 million and 1.25 million for large and small
firms, respectively. While this figure represents about 0.1 percent of all sales for large
companies, the toll on earnings is even greater for small firms28.
Researchers at Texas A&M also found that from 2001 to 2007, the absolute costs
related to the implementation of the Act were 39 million, 7 million, and 6 million for large,
medium-sized, and small firms, respectively. This increase in costs also affected the
companies’ cash flows; on average, cash flows from sales declined by 1.8 percent while cash
flows from assets declined by 1.3 percent. Overall, Sarbox costs eliminated about 0.5 percent
of total cash flows in large corporations and up to 3 percent in small companies28.
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 23
23
Finally, a study by Financial Executives International addresses the first-year costs
incurred by companies to stay in compliance with the Act´s provisions. For companies
generating, on average, 5 billion dollars in revenue, the expenses included 1.34 million in
internal administration (27,000 work hours), 1.30 million in auditing expenses, and 1.72
million spent on information technology and consultants7. Unfortunately, most studies
indicate that while the impact on large corporations is significant, the firms picking up most
of the costs are relatively small businesses28. As a result, the indirect costs of the legislation
might have a lasting negative impact on the economy as business activity contracts under such
prohibitive costs.
Second, the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act was signed into effect
only recently; therefore, the process of cost estimation has proven to be more difficult.
Nevertheless, the extent of the Act itself suggests that the absolute costs might be so great that
they will never be truly accounted for in their entirety.
To illustrate, the first four years of compliance alone have imposed over 21.8 billion
dollars of additional costs on the financial industry, which translated into human capital costs
of 60.7 million hours in administrative work. The expenses incurred are not only significant,
but are growing at an increasing rate as well. From 2013 to 2014, when this research was
published, the costs grew by 6.4 million dollars, which is an increase of 41 percent in a single
year18.
Perhaps because of the extent of the regulation and the fear that the public might not
approve of the additional costs to taxpayers, the government failed to disclose the full
amounts incurred; indeed, some cost analyses were released months after the Act was passed
and most were greatly understated. Moreover, certain costs were never made public. For
instance, a number of sections in the Dodd-Frank Act responsible for new rules were
completely omitted from the cost estimation process. When evaluated by researchers, these
sections added up to 1.2 billion dollars in additional costs18.
Moreover, the indirect costs imposed on the financial industry are profound and
perhaps more damaging than the cost related to administration. Because the cost of
conducting business has increased for many financial institutions, especially smaller banks, it
is possible that we will experience a real increase in the cost of capital, and perhaps a decrease
in its availability.
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 24
24
This secondary effect, then, might have very real implications for the individual
citizen as banks and other financial intermediaries might be reluctant to provide certain
services. Since the adoption, the most eliminated business units were residential mortgages,
home equity lines of credit, and lending in general. To illustrate, a study conducted in 2014 by
the American Bankers Association revealed that two-thirds of the institutions involved would
decrease the volume of lending18.
While knowing the exact amounts of the costs imposed on both the corporate entity
and the consumer is impossible, the process of estimation provides us with a clear idea of the
size of the impact that will sweep through the financial markets. Being made aware of these
costs, the only question left to ask is whether the adoption of such costly laws can be
economically justified.
Conclusion
In correctly assessing the situation, it is important to ask why the public asked for
additional regulation in the first place. Essentially, the reason behind most of the public
pressure was the desire for fraud prevention in future years. Because they were concerned
about the losses that had to be absorbed in the aftermath of these scandals, the average
citizens wished to see the risk of such loss eliminated. Being rationally ignorant, the persons
would look to government regulation as the optimal solution to such a seemingly complex
issue.
While the intentions of most people involved in the regulation-crafting process were
undoubtedly honorable, in the eyes of the economist, these intentions are ultimately irrelevant.
Instead, the focus of proper economic analysis is on the outcomes generated by each
respective solution, which is what ultimately affects the individual consumer. Therefore, to
arrive at an accurate conclusion, it is necessary to consider the factors relevant to both fraud
prevention and related business regulation, and the outcomes they generate in private markets.
First, it is essential to understand that fraud is, and always will be, a component of
private markets, whether they are regulated or not. Because all individuals act in self-interest,
the temptation to commit fraud is an inherent part of human nature. Under conditions where
incentives are misaligned, whether through compensation or other mechanisms, individuals
will tend to undertake fraudulent activities because it is the rational thing to do. While
statistically rare, a few individuals with above-average risk appetite will gain control of key
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 25
25
resources and such instances will likely lead to losses. Finally, gains will always be offset by
losses in private markets, whether due to fraud or natural market activity, and this self-
equilibration cannot be prevented by any outside mechanism.
As a result, it is clear that the principal-agent problem introduced in this paper will
always be present; indeed, no solution has yet been found to eliminate the problems
associated with this dilemma. Therefore, as long as principals act in self-interest, agents will
act in self-interest as well, and their interaction will cause inefficiencies in markets.
Second, while such notions are romantic in theory, the presence of regulation in
private markets will not prevent or eliminate fraud. Apart from establishing property rights
and enforcing contracts, there is not much more the government can do to improve the
efficiency of private markets. Looking at the number and scope of financial regulation we
have, ranging from the Securities Acts of 1933 and 1934, through Insider Trading and
Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988, to Dodd-Frank Act of 2010, it would seem
reasonable to expect no additional fraud to occur16.
However, as evidenced by new scandals emerging every year, this is not so. In fact,
adoption of additional regulation might have quite the opposite effect; because investors often
regain trust in the financial markets when new regulation is introduced, they begin to have a
false sense of security which, in turn, makes them less observant and more susceptible to
losses. In essence, government regulation reduces the apparent need for questioning, which
increases the potential for fraud and risk of investor loss.
Further, even with the best intentions in mind, it would be impossible for the
government to solve the principal-agent problem because like any other market entity, the
government faces such a problem as well. As illustrated above, the agencies responsible for
cost estimation and disclosure of the Dodd-Frank act failed to report to the public the true
amounts of expenses that taxpayers would bear18. It is questionable, then, if the government
should oversee proper disclosure by other institutions when it fails to exercise proper
disclosure on its own.
After examining both sides of the issue, one is tempted to ask whether the costs of
regulation outweigh the losses incurred as a result of fraud. In the principal-agent problem, we
encounter the so-called agency costs, which are costs borne by principals when agents fail to
follow the agency contract and take actions different from those preferred by principals. The
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 26
26
agency costs represent the suboptimal results illustrated in the case studies, and such costs
should not be taken lightly, whether in their extent or nature9.
However, the costs of regulation are also high; taxpayers bear the immense costs of
implementation and they must also face the unexpected secondary effects of regulation on
markets across time. Often, these secondary effects can have more profound consequences
than any fraud could; decreases in overall productivity and reduction of business activity are
just two of many examples.
While the question of whether regulation is too costly to be used as a form of fraud
prevention will be left to each individual and their personal preferences, there are certain
factors that prove regulation to be a suboptimal solution to the problem of fraud. First, as
mentioned above, fraud will never truly be eliminated, no matter the number of Acts Congress
passes or the extent of each law. Second, in an attempt to regulate, governments and their
citizens often forget to see the underlying causes of the problem and focus on symptoms
instead, thus producing unwanted secondary effects. Last, it is impossible to regulate human
nature to such an extent as to eliminate fraud without imposing limitations on basic human
freedoms.
In the concluding paragraphs, an alternative is presented that should allow each
individual to evaluate the situation in terms of their own preferences. Referring back to the
basic goal of every corporation, maximization of shareholder value, it is clear that no long-
term goal-oriented corporation desires fraud to occur. Ultimately, neither managers nor
owners want fraud present in their workplace as it inhibits the company’s ability to generate
future profits, and often endangers its ability to continue as a going concern.
This, in turn, has very real effects on the stakeholders’ well-being, and therefore there
is a strong incentive to engage in activities that ensure fraud prevention. Even without
government regulators, companies design extensive internal control systems and undertake
monitoring activities that will protect them from losses from fraud.
Tyco International, Inc. is a prime example of the fact that although fraud may occur, a
company´s primary objective is to create value for the consumer and stay fraud-free. At Tyco,
Edward Breen, who became CEO after Kozlowski´s infamous step-down, restructured the
company and its internal control to prevent future misappropriations12.
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 27
27
In the first few years, Breen ensured that 90% of the headquarters’ employees were
replaced, severance payments increased for executives, and a new Guide to Ethical Conduct
was adopted. Even without the guidance from Sarbanes Oxley, Breen required that the Board
chairman be independent of the company and a new Board of Directors be elected by the
shareholders. These and other measures illustrate Tyco´s natural desire to prevent fraud
without the presence of regulation12.
In conclusion, the argument that each of us faces is very simple; is it more beneficial
to accept private markets with their inherent inefficiencies and risks of loss, and enjoy the
ability to exercise our freedoms in making decisions, or are the costs of doing so too high?
Similarly, do the benefits of increased government control, such as greater perceived degree
of safety, outweigh the costs, such as the lack of freedom to choose? Do we, as rationally
ignorant, self-interested market participants, willingly overlook the additional inefficiencies
generated by government to create a false sense of security for ourselves? Finally, how
willing are we to regulate our own human nature?
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 28
28
Sources
1. American Institute of Public Accountants. (2005, January 1). Tyco International Ltd.
Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&ved=0CB4QFj
AA&url=http://www.aicpa.org/InterestAreas/AccountingEducation/Resources/Download
ableDocuments/tyco.ppt&ei=wgE3VdzFHsykyASi04DoCw&usg=AFQjCNE5Vtd1NLj3
UhXDgdNJQZ_sFqQ9tw&bvm=bv.91427555,d.aWw
2. Von Frentz C. (2003, June 25). Consequences of the ENRON Scandal. Retrieved April
22, 2015, from http://www.global-ethic-now.de/gen-eng/0d_weltethos-und-wirtschaft/0d-
01-globale-wirtschaft/0d-01-203-enron-folgen.php
3. Neuman, E. (2005, January 1). THE IMPACT OF THE ENRON ACCOUNTING
SCANDAL ON IMPRESSIONS OF. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://ericneuman.com/Papers/post-enron-attributions_aom_2005.pdf
4. Bernstein, E. (2009, February 12). Madoff Scandal's Deep Impact On Funding for Health,
Science. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB123439995182175299
5. Alessandro, K. (2013, January 1). How Madoff Has Transformed the Investment
Industry. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.eci.com/blog/488-five-years-later-
how-bernie-madoff-has-transformed-the-investment-industry.html
6. Lenzner, R. (2008, January 1). Bernie Madoff's $50 Billion Ponzi Scheme. Retrieved
April 22, 2015, from http://www.forbes.com/2008/12/12/madoff-ponzi-hedge-pf-ii-
in_rl_1212croesus_inl.html
7. Goelzer, D. (2005, January 1). The Costs & Benefits of Sarbanes-Oxley Section 404.
Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://pcaobus.org/News/Speech/Pages/03212005_GoelzerCostsBenefitsofSOX404. aspx
8. Kay, J. (2003, August 5). World Socialist Web Site. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
https://www.wsws.org/en/articles/2003/08/enrn-a05.html
9. Bezroukov, N. (2015, January 1). Principal-agent problem. Retrieved April 22, 2015,
from
http://www.softpanorama.org/Skeptics/Financial_skeptic/Casino_capitalism/Systemic_ins
tability_of_financial_sector/principal_agent_problem.shtml
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 29
29
10. Free, C., Macintosh, N., Stein, M., Macintosh, N., & Stein, M. (2007, August 1). Ivey
Business Journal. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://iveybusinessjournal.com/publication/management-controls-the-organizational-
fraud-triangle-of-leadership-culture-and-control-in-enron/
11. Brigham, E., and Houston, J. (2011, January 26) Fundamentals of Financial Management
Cengage Learning 8th Edition pp 9-15
12. Boostrom, R. (2011, January 1). Daniels Fund Ethics Initiative. Retrieved April 22, 2015,
from http://danielsethics.mgt.unm.edu/
13. Herrick, T., & Barrionuevo, A. (2002, January 21). Were Enron, Anderson Too Close To
Allow Auditor to Do Its Job? Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB1011565452932132000
14. Chicago Tribune. (2002, September 1). The fall of Andersen. Retrieved April 22, 2015,
from http://chicagotribune.com/news/chi-0209010315sep01-story.html
15. Madoff, B. (2009, March 12). The Text of Madoff's Plea Allocution. Retrieved April 22,
2015, from http://dealbook.nytimes.com//2009/03/12/the-text-of-madoffs-plea-allocution/
16. Hoyle, J. (2014) “Financial Reporting and the Securities and Exchange Commission”
Advanced Accounting 12th edition from
http://textflow.mheducations.com/parser.php?secload=12&fake&print
17. Morrison, A. (2011, January 1). Dodd-Frank Cheat Sheet. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&ved=0CB4QFj
AA&url=http://www.mofo.com/files/uploads/images/summarydoddfrankact.pdf&ei=H6
w3Vfi_LtGoogTSkYHADg&usg=AFQjCNGoBlXXLyNhDuUm2UxEXtMnN9mNNA&
bvm=bv.91427555,bs.1,d.aWw
18. Winkler, A., Gitis, B., & Batkins, S. (2014, July 15). Dodd-Frank at 4: More Regulation,
More Regulators, and a Sluggish Housing Market | Research. Retrieved April 22, 2015,
from http://americanactionforum.org/research/dodd-frank-at-4-more-regulation-more-
regulators-and-a-sluggish-housing-mark
19. Li, Y. (2010, October 1). The Case Analysis of the Scandal of Enron. Retrieved April 22,
2015, from
http://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&ved=0CB4QFj
AA&url=http://www.ccsenet.org/journal/index.php/ijbm/article/viewFile/7627/5855.&ei
=2Kw3VaWTLtG6ogTEkYCQDA&usg=AFQjCNFzjeNPvcL3L0ZRH4tN8odcmkMFK
Q&bvm=bv.91071109,d.cGU
CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 30
30
20. Thomas, C. (2002, March 31). The Rise and Fall of Enron. Retrieved April 22, 2015,
from
http://www.journalofaccountancy.com/Issues/2002/Apr/TheRiseAndFallOfEnron.htm
21. McEachern, W. (2013). Contemporary economics (3 e. ed., pp. 312-314). Mason, Ohio:
South-Western Cengage Learning
22. Whittington, R., & Pany, K. (2013). Principles of auditing and other assurance services
(13th ed., pp. 244-253). Boston: Irwin/McGraw-Hill.
23. Yang, S. (2014, July 1). 5 Years Ago Bernie Madoff Was Sentenced to 150 Years In
Prison – Here's How His Scheme Worked. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://www.businessinsider.com/how-bernie-madoffs-ponzi-scheme-worked-2014-
7#ixzz3XratglBu
24. Time. (1995, January 1). Fortune. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://archive.fortune.com/magazines/fortune/fortune500_archive/snapshots/1995/478.ht
ml
25. Times. (2015, January 1). Moral Hazard Definition | Moral Hazard Meaning - The
Economic Times. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/definition/moral-hazard
26. Ackman, D. (2002, March 22). Pay Madness At Enron. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://www.forbes.com/2002/03/22/0322enronpay.html
27. Hitt, G., & Schlesinger, J. (2002, March 26). Stock Options Come Under Fire In the
Wake of Enron's Collapse. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB1017093594617163160
28. Martin, J. (2010, August 1). Sarbanes-Oxley: Does the Cost Knock Your Socks Off?
Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://amp.aom.org/content/24/3/103.extract
29. Abelson, R. (2002, January 18). One Enron Inquiry Suggests Board Played Important
Role. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from
http://www.nytimes.com/2002/01/19/business/enron-s-collapse-directors-one-enron-
inquiry-suggests-board-played-important.html

More Related Content

What's hot

Enron SWOT Analysis
Enron    SWOT AnalysisEnron    SWOT Analysis
Enron SWOT Analysis
joelnshisso
 
38299644 tyco-fraud-case-study-1
38299644 tyco-fraud-case-study-138299644 tyco-fraud-case-study-1
38299644 tyco-fraud-case-study-1
Nantha Kumaran
 
Lessons from-worldcom-1231784975071368-3
Lessons from-worldcom-1231784975071368-3Lessons from-worldcom-1231784975071368-3
Lessons from-worldcom-1231784975071368-3
stevenwatts1965
 
Week 8_Final Course Presentation_Accounting Fraud at WordCom_Walker,S.
Week 8_Final Course Presentation_Accounting Fraud at WordCom_Walker,S.Week 8_Final Course Presentation_Accounting Fraud at WordCom_Walker,S.
Week 8_Final Course Presentation_Accounting Fraud at WordCom_Walker,S.
Stephanie Walker
 

What's hot (20)

Corporate fraud: the cost of doing nothing
Corporate fraud: the cost of doing nothingCorporate fraud: the cost of doing nothing
Corporate fraud: the cost of doing nothing
 
Dissertation Report On A Case Analysis On Enron Failure
Dissertation Report On A Case Analysis On Enron FailureDissertation Report On A Case Analysis On Enron Failure
Dissertation Report On A Case Analysis On Enron Failure
 
The Culprit Is All Of Us By Ss Powell Barrons
The Culprit Is All Of Us  By Ss Powell BarronsThe Culprit Is All Of Us  By Ss Powell Barrons
The Culprit Is All Of Us By Ss Powell Barrons
 
Lehman brothers
Lehman brothersLehman brothers
Lehman brothers
 
236425643 case-study-1
236425643 case-study-1236425643 case-study-1
236425643 case-study-1
 
Case Study, Enron's Fraud
Case Study, Enron's FraudCase Study, Enron's Fraud
Case Study, Enron's Fraud
 
Worldcom scam 2002
Worldcom scam 2002Worldcom scam 2002
Worldcom scam 2002
 
Enron SWOT Analysis
Enron    SWOT AnalysisEnron    SWOT Analysis
Enron SWOT Analysis
 
38299644 tyco-fraud-case-study-1
38299644 tyco-fraud-case-study-138299644 tyco-fraud-case-study-1
38299644 tyco-fraud-case-study-1
 
Lessons from-worldcom-1231784975071368-3
Lessons from-worldcom-1231784975071368-3Lessons from-worldcom-1231784975071368-3
Lessons from-worldcom-1231784975071368-3
 
Enron scandal
Enron scandalEnron scandal
Enron scandal
 
Worldcom
WorldcomWorldcom
Worldcom
 
Week 8_Final Course Presentation_Accounting Fraud at WordCom_Walker,S.
Week 8_Final Course Presentation_Accounting Fraud at WordCom_Walker,S.Week 8_Final Course Presentation_Accounting Fraud at WordCom_Walker,S.
Week 8_Final Course Presentation_Accounting Fraud at WordCom_Walker,S.
 
The Enron Scandal : A Simple Overview
The Enron Scandal : A Simple OverviewThe Enron Scandal : A Simple Overview
The Enron Scandal : A Simple Overview
 
Enron Aa12
Enron Aa12Enron Aa12
Enron Aa12
 
MCI Case Study
MCI Case StudyMCI Case Study
MCI Case Study
 
World.com
World.comWorld.com
World.com
 
Enron scandal Assignment / Report. By A. K. M. Sultan Mahmud Faisal
Enron scandal Assignment /  Report. By A. K. M. Sultan Mahmud FaisalEnron scandal Assignment /  Report. By A. K. M. Sultan Mahmud Faisal
Enron scandal Assignment / Report. By A. K. M. Sultan Mahmud Faisal
 
Enron Scandal " A Fundamental Case Study"
Enron Scandal " A Fundamental Case Study" Enron Scandal " A Fundamental Case Study"
Enron Scandal " A Fundamental Case Study"
 
After Sarbanes Oxley
After Sarbanes OxleyAfter Sarbanes Oxley
After Sarbanes Oxley
 

Viewers also liked

New concepts in human
New concepts in humanNew concepts in human
New concepts in human
bechikmn
 
Dematic Logistics Review #4
Dematic Logistics Review #4Dematic Logistics Review #4
Dematic Logistics Review #4
hagenbucksw
 
Bloombase 为 KVM 企业级虚拟数据中心提供全方位信息安全保护及运算
Bloombase 为 KVM 企业级虚拟数据中心提供全方位信息安全保护及运算Bloombase 为 KVM 企业级虚拟数据中心提供全方位信息安全保护及运算
Bloombase 为 KVM 企业级虚拟数据中心提供全方位信息安全保护及运算
Bloombase
 
Estrategias y recursos i
Estrategias y recursos iEstrategias y recursos i
Estrategias y recursos i
jkrls
 
E-group's pitch
E-group's pitchE-group's pitch
E-group's pitch
i7
 
History of the llano estacado
History of the llano estacadoHistory of the llano estacado
History of the llano estacado
Mark McGinley
 

Viewers also liked (20)

201411203 goto night on graphs for fraud detection
201411203 goto night on graphs for fraud detection201411203 goto night on graphs for fraud detection
201411203 goto night on graphs for fraud detection
 
IBM Counter Fraud Management
IBM Counter Fraud ManagementIBM Counter Fraud Management
IBM Counter Fraud Management
 
DABiS800
DABiS800DABiS800
DABiS800
 
Optimizing the Virtual Environment
Optimizing the Virtual EnvironmentOptimizing the Virtual Environment
Optimizing the Virtual Environment
 
Guide to Investment: Republic of Tatarstan
Guide to Investment: Republic of TatarstanGuide to Investment: Republic of Tatarstan
Guide to Investment: Republic of Tatarstan
 
Mapa Mental
Mapa MentalMapa Mental
Mapa Mental
 
New concepts in human
New concepts in humanNew concepts in human
New concepts in human
 
Tranzeo
TranzeoTranzeo
Tranzeo
 
30 Band Marks
30 Band Marks30 Band Marks
30 Band Marks
 
Tieto Enator
Tieto EnatorTieto Enator
Tieto Enator
 
Safend- DL
Safend- DLSafend- DL
Safend- DL
 
Dematic Logistics Review #4
Dematic Logistics Review #4Dematic Logistics Review #4
Dematic Logistics Review #4
 
OutSys Company Presentation
OutSys Company PresentationOutSys Company Presentation
OutSys Company Presentation
 
Bloombase 为 KVM 企业级虚拟数据中心提供全方位信息安全保护及运算
Bloombase 为 KVM 企业级虚拟数据中心提供全方位信息安全保护及运算Bloombase 为 KVM 企业级虚拟数据中心提供全方位信息安全保护及运算
Bloombase 为 KVM 企业级虚拟数据中心提供全方位信息安全保护及运算
 
Catalog Sew-Eurodrive
Catalog Sew-EurodriveCatalog Sew-Eurodrive
Catalog Sew-Eurodrive
 
Estrategias y recursos i
Estrategias y recursos iEstrategias y recursos i
Estrategias y recursos i
 
E-group's pitch
E-group's pitchE-group's pitch
E-group's pitch
 
History of the llano estacado
History of the llano estacadoHistory of the llano estacado
History of the llano estacado
 
Desafios jurídicos de Internet
Desafios jurídicos de InternetDesafios jurídicos de Internet
Desafios jurídicos de Internet
 
Girl, interrupted
Girl, interruptedGirl, interrupted
Girl, interrupted
 

Similar to Financial Fraud Paper

Research Topics with Explanation SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT PROV.docx
Research Topics with Explanation SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT PROV.docxResearch Topics with Explanation SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT PROV.docx
Research Topics with Explanation SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT PROV.docx
ronak56
 
PAGE 280APPLYING THE CONCEPTTRUTH OR CONSEQUENCES PONZI SCHEM.docx
PAGE 280APPLYING THE CONCEPTTRUTH OR CONSEQUENCES PONZI SCHEM.docxPAGE 280APPLYING THE CONCEPTTRUTH OR CONSEQUENCES PONZI SCHEM.docx
PAGE 280APPLYING THE CONCEPTTRUTH OR CONSEQUENCES PONZI SCHEM.docx
smile790243
 
Internal Controls – The changing Indian Landscape--By Samit Saraf
Internal Controls – The changing Indian Landscape--By Samit SarafInternal Controls – The changing Indian Landscape--By Samit Saraf
Internal Controls – The changing Indian Landscape--By Samit Saraf
kirtane&Pandit
 
History Of The Sarbanes-Oxley Act
History Of The Sarbanes-Oxley ActHistory Of The Sarbanes-Oxley Act
History Of The Sarbanes-Oxley Act
Angela Weber
 
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis FinalBynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Cynthia Bynum
 
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis FinalBynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Cynthia Bynum
 
HONORS Sarbanes-Oxley Act Aleksandar Krajisnik
HONORS Sarbanes-Oxley Act Aleksandar KrajisnikHONORS Sarbanes-Oxley Act Aleksandar Krajisnik
HONORS Sarbanes-Oxley Act Aleksandar Krajisnik
Aleksandar Krajisnik
 
Identify in 150 - 200 words your reactions to the concepts of global.pdf
Identify in 150 - 200 words your reactions to the concepts of global.pdfIdentify in 150 - 200 words your reactions to the concepts of global.pdf
Identify in 150 - 200 words your reactions to the concepts of global.pdf
fathimafancyjeweller
 
White Collar Crime A growing global problem
White Collar Crime A growing global problemWhite Collar Crime A growing global problem
White Collar Crime A growing global problem
Ovais Rehman
 
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
Gabriel Hernandez Fonte
 

Similar to Financial Fraud Paper (18)

Research Topics with Explanation SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT PROV.docx
Research Topics with Explanation SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT PROV.docxResearch Topics with Explanation SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT PROV.docx
Research Topics with Explanation SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT PROV.docx
 
PAGE 280APPLYING THE CONCEPTTRUTH OR CONSEQUENCES PONZI SCHEM.docx
PAGE 280APPLYING THE CONCEPTTRUTH OR CONSEQUENCES PONZI SCHEM.docxPAGE 280APPLYING THE CONCEPTTRUTH OR CONSEQUENCES PONZI SCHEM.docx
PAGE 280APPLYING THE CONCEPTTRUTH OR CONSEQUENCES PONZI SCHEM.docx
 
Lessons from 2000s
Lessons from 2000sLessons from 2000s
Lessons from 2000s
 
Internal Controls – The changing Indian Landscape--By Samit Saraf
Internal Controls – The changing Indian Landscape--By Samit SarafInternal Controls – The changing Indian Landscape--By Samit Saraf
Internal Controls – The changing Indian Landscape--By Samit Saraf
 
History Of The Sarbanes-Oxley Act
History Of The Sarbanes-Oxley ActHistory Of The Sarbanes-Oxley Act
History Of The Sarbanes-Oxley Act
 
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis FinalBynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
 
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis FinalBynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
 
Enron scandal
Enron scandalEnron scandal
Enron scandal
 
The Freddie Mac Fraud.pptx
The Freddie Mac Fraud.pptxThe Freddie Mac Fraud.pptx
The Freddie Mac Fraud.pptx
 
HONORS Sarbanes-Oxley Act Aleksandar Krajisnik
HONORS Sarbanes-Oxley Act Aleksandar KrajisnikHONORS Sarbanes-Oxley Act Aleksandar Krajisnik
HONORS Sarbanes-Oxley Act Aleksandar Krajisnik
 
Ivo Pezzuto - CONCLUSIONS OF THE US FINANCIAL CRISIS INQUIRY COMMISSION (2011)
Ivo Pezzuto - CONCLUSIONS OF THE US FINANCIAL CRISIS INQUIRY COMMISSION (2011)Ivo Pezzuto - CONCLUSIONS OF THE US FINANCIAL CRISIS INQUIRY COMMISSION (2011)
Ivo Pezzuto - CONCLUSIONS OF THE US FINANCIAL CRISIS INQUIRY COMMISSION (2011)
 
Identify in 150 - 200 words your reactions to the concepts of global.pdf
Identify in 150 - 200 words your reactions to the concepts of global.pdfIdentify in 150 - 200 words your reactions to the concepts of global.pdf
Identify in 150 - 200 words your reactions to the concepts of global.pdf
 
White Collar Crime A growing global problem
White Collar Crime A growing global problemWhite Collar Crime A growing global problem
White Collar Crime A growing global problem
 
12345678
1234567812345678
12345678
 
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
 
Jon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - Introduction
Jon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - IntroductionJon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - Introduction
Jon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - Introduction
 
Preventing financial fraud
Preventing financial fraudPreventing financial fraud
Preventing financial fraud
 
LEHMAN BROTHERS-B.E.pptx
LEHMAN BROTHERS-B.E.pptxLEHMAN BROTHERS-B.E.pptx
LEHMAN BROTHERS-B.E.pptx
 

Financial Fraud Paper

  • 1. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 1 1 Can We Regulate Human Nature? A Study of Financial Fraud, Government Regulation, and The Principal-Agent Dilemma Marketa Kreuzingerova Brescia University Dr. Rohnn Sanderson Business Administration
  • 2. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 2 2 Introduction In recent years, corporate fraud has seemed to permeate the workings of the private financial markets where dishonest accounting practices and extensive financial misstatements led to the demise of America´s brightest and most promising enterprises. As a result of these scandals, many Americans have been materially harmed. Thousands of jobs and retirement savings in pension funds have been lost. Because of this, investor confidence has eroded substantially. However, the greatest impact these crises have had on the world is that they instilled fear in the average American citizen that private markets should not, and no longer will, be trusted. Currently, they are seen as breeding ground for greedy, dishonest businessmen. The Enron debacle, which unfolded in the late months of 200119, seemed to be the trigger for an avalanche of corporate scandals to come. In 2000, Enron reported over a 1.41 billion dollars in pretax profit and a share price of 90.56 dollars20. America´s favorite company appeared to be in great financial shape and thriving. Positioning itself in the 7th highest ranking on the Fortune 500 List in the same year, Enron was thought to be one of the most successful innovators in the country, and the entire market was cheering it on as investors were realizing capital gains on stock prices they otherwise wouldn’t have dreamed of24. After placing so much confidence in the company, it is easy to understand why Enron´s collapse had such a devastating and profound impact on American financial markets. Specifically, there were around 4,500 jobs lost directly related to Enron’s failure, with all pension accounts frozen and never recovered2. While loyal employees found themselves struggling to recover from the shock, investors lost 64.2 billion dollars, all in a matter of a few days2. Through the practices of mark-to-market accounting, extensive off-balance-sheet debt financing, and organization-wide internal control overrides, Enron transformed itself from a promising new-industry business to the largest corporate bankruptcy to that date in the United States of America10. In the aftermath of the scandal, many began to question the trust placed in top executives and the checks and balances present at those positions. Absorbing the losses resulting from Enron´s failure, the public began, naturally, calling for more extensive
  • 3. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 3 3 regulation. While CEO and CFO fraudulent activities within the company were at question, the more disturbing factor was the complete failure of all external “watchdogs” to prevent, or detect and correct, the fraud that was taking place. Indeed, none of the investor analysts, bond rating agencies, independent auditors, or SEC oversight managed to uncover the misstatements that some claim they simply did not want to be seen. In either case, these failures have had grave impacts on the accounting profession, which has lost most of its credibility, as well as American financial markets, whose trustworthiness people stopped believing. Yet Enron was only the first of many disappointments to come. Tyco International, the next in line in the domino effect of failing corporations following Enron´s collapse, did not come to its breaking point until a year later, when substantial misappropriation of funds by Tyco’s CEO, Dennis Kozlowski, was discovered12. Up to that point, Tyco appeared to be in perfect condition as it was constantly expanding its market reach, from security to healthcare services, and disclosed revenues of over 36 billion dollars in 20011. However, when Kozlowski´s activities came to light in early 2002, additional issues concerning the company´s honest practices started to surface. Later that year, it became clear that the embezzlement of hundreds of millions of dollars in cash and other assets on Kozlowski´s part was accompanied by 56 million dollars given out to employees to pay off inter-company loans, related-party transactions that never appeared on the financial statements, and false appreciation(insider trading) of the company stock1. After the start of the investigation, other executives, including the CFO and the Chairman of the Board of Directors, were accused of participating in the embezzlements and placed on trial12. Again, the signals leading to the fraud discovery were overlooked and the very few who saw what was coming were silenced, as in the case of Enron. The reason was simple; Tyco International, then conducting operations in over 100 countries, reported profits that were too good to jeopardize by unnecessary questioning1. However, in Tyco’s case, the annual revenue growth of 48.7 percent from 1997 to 2001 was backed by real value created through successful operation of the company12. Unlike Enron, Tyco International did not have to face bankruptcy and managed to preserve most jobs as well as retirement funds12. While its stock price decreased immensely, this did not prevent the company from eventual recovery.
  • 4. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 4 4 In fact, Tyco has made extensive changes to its internal control environment as well as ethical standards promoted within the company. This has allowed it to reclaim its success in recent years. Despite a 2 billion-dollar write-off in the financial statements following the scandal, Tyco continued to grow and now operates as three separate entities, each of which became global leaders in their respective industry. This includes Tyco Healthcare, Tyco Electronics, and Tyco Fire and Security12. However, the recovery of Tyco International was a unique case of corporate fraud. As other “too big to fail” corporations, including Sunbeam, WorldCom, and Duke Energy, began collapsing, people all over the country were on the edge of their seats calling for more regulation to prevent these situations in the future. Consequently, this continuous pressure from the public led to a fast adoption of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, which appeared to have dealt with the issues of fraud taking place at that time. Following the enactment of the law, there was a period of time during which the public came to believe that the problems inherent to financial markets had been solved. Then, in the late 2000s, the “financial wizard” and genius investment fund broker Bernie Madoff came around. He offered double-digit returns when other investor groups were only generating single. Clients flooded to Bernard L. Madoff Investment Securities, LLC (BLMIS) seeking greater capital gains as well as increases in annual incomes23. As in the previous cases, many failed to question the workings behind such returns as long as their appetite for additional funds was being satisfied. Among others, his clients included large not- for-profit organizations, usually charitable funds, formed by affluent couples and designated for donation purposes15. While the clients entrusted their savings with Madoff and were enjoying the unreal returns, the former NASDAQ Chairman was very well aware that the entire system was but a well-orchestrated show15. In fact, the profits generated by BLMIS were nothing but numbers printed on paper, and consequently, his clients ended up with double-digit paper profits. Unlike the other cases, where internal control and organizational checks and balances failed to function properly, in the Madoff scenario, there were none5. Madoff, being the owner as well as President of the company, had unlimited access and control over the financial statements and their issuance. In fact, Madoff himself was responsible for creating these financial statements by selecting stock prices that would complement his earnings projections15. While a simple confirmation of quoted prices would
  • 5. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 5 5 have uncovered such fraudulent practices, none dared to question a company headed by a former NASDAQ chairman, especially when he was generating such “magical” profits5. As a result, it took several years before Madoff´s Ponzi Scheme turned into a public scandal and BLMIS came crashing down with it. Naturally, as in the previous cases, the consequences were grave. In the aftermath of the scandal, it was estimated that Madoff´s clients lost approximately 50 billion dollars in their investments, even though the actual losses incurred may be higher6. Overall, about 12,000 individual investors were affected. Many of these found their hedge funds liquidated to absorb the impacts of the fraud5. In fact, Madoff´s Ponzi Scheme had a much more profound effect on the American economy as many funds dedicated to medical and other scientific research were frozen and funding for these programs disappeared4. In response to the scandal, Congress drafted and adopted the Dodd-Frank Act, also known as the Wall-Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, in an effort to calm the increasing pressures from the voting public5. While it will be discussed in more detail later in the paper, this law was aimed at decreasing the probability of loss to financial market consumers5. In the meantime, many started questioning the credibility of the financial markets again and what followed we came to know as the Great Recession. While the case studies discussed above are undoubtedly unique in their nature, we can identify certain attributes that all of them, and many others, share. First, the uncovering of every fraud had some negative consequences, even though the extent varied from scenario to scenario depending on the condition of the company. As illustrated by Tyco’s case, we could see that fraud did not necessarily cause collapse if the entity had been backed by some intrinsic value. Second, each fraud case ignited a public outrage that eroded much of the investor confidence and trust in the financial markets. Moreover, many started to despise the financial community as businessmen came to be portrayed as evil profit-seekers rather than value- creators. In fact, some have even started questioning human nature itself as a result of these scandals; in recent years, we have seen the emergence of the field of behavioral finance, which attempts to describe management behavior in psychological terms. Third, this fear and questioning of human nature instilled in much of the public the sense that the average citizen needs to be protected from corporate executives and their
  • 6. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 6 6 “dirty” tricks by regulation. As we can see, each case resulted in some form of regulation, usually called for by the general public that was meant to prevent the next case from happening. However, it was never so. Therefore, this paper takes a different approach to analyzing fraud; it starts by an introduction to the economic phenomenon also known as the principal-agent problem, then introduces the specific impacts this concept had in each one of our scenarios, and concludes by examining the benefits and costs of the regulation that was adopted in response to these scandals. Finally, an argument for continued trust in the credibility of the financial markets will be made. However, as with any other market analysis, this will not be done without a call for ever-present caution and questioning. Analysis In private markets, we experience several phenomena that most would refer to as market failures, which are instances when the markets do not generate optimal results, and inefficiencies are generated. One of these phenomena is the so-called moral hazard, in which one market participant transfers part of the possibility of loss to another party, effectively reduces their cost of transacting, and therefore takes actions of greater risk. Often, because of this greater risk, the likelihood of loss increases, and these losses are partially borne by outside parties25. Moral hazard occurs when there is incomplete or imperfect information, meaning that one of the parties involved in the transaction often has different or greater-quality information than the other parties. Sometimes, not enough information is available on either side of the market. Consequently, a transaction carried out under imperfect information results in a moral hazard25. In private markets, we often experience a unique form of moral hazard-the principal- agent problem21. A common example of the principal-agent problem is illustrated by the voter- politician relationship, where politicians (agents) do not always do what is in the best interest of the voters (principals) 9. While the principal-agent dilemma can be found in a multitude of everyday situations, from classroom interaction to car purchasing, the problem most commonly associated with this form of moral hazard is the issue of corporate ownership9. The problem inherent in the establishment and operation of every corporate business is that the owners, who initially supply financial as well as other resources to get the corporation
  • 7. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 7 7 on its feet, cannot or simply do not wish to make the time commitment needed to conduct its everyday operations. Their desired level of commitment, then, is limited to the receipt of periodic income from earnings and perhaps maintenance of a certain level of oversight over company performance. Because they have already invested their time and money into the firm, these owners, also known as initial investors, are mainly looking for a stable return on their investment11. Eventually, additional investors, either common or preferred stockholders, provide equity capital for the firm to satisfy its financing needs. Even though their commitment does not seem as extensive as that of the initial founders, these shareholders, too, look for a return on their investment without unnecessary participation. It is important to realize that while a large portion of the U.S. stock market is occupied by professional institutional investors, these shareholders can also be families, individuals looking for retirement income, or college students wishing to pay off their tuition. Naturally, these market participants do not have time to devote to everyday operations of the company11. In order for investors to achieve their desired state of affairs, they enter into a formal contract with another party, represented by management-in this case the corporate executives. This agreement, also known as an agency contract, puts management in control of operations, including planning, production, and performance monitoring. This is done in exchange for agreed-upon compensation. Most importantly, management is expected to maximize the long- term value of the corporation, reflected by the average stock price over time, which then generates positive long-run returns for the owners11. In theory, such a contract appears to provide a neat solution to a multitude of problems. While managers are compensated for their time and skilled labor spent on running the firm, owners agree to give up part of the company profits in order to ensure stable investment returns. However this is where the principal-agent problem, as well as economic theory in general, come into play. As we know, all individuals have slightly different personalities, attributes, and characteristics. What is common to each and every man on the planet, however, is their self-interested nature that drives every individual to pursue activities that best meet their unique preferences. Consequently, this special, unifying feature of the human race can cause the greatest of problems for societies all over the world. As surprising as it may seem, self-interest not only applies to you, me, and the rest of our community, it also applies to corporate executives. This phenomenon, then, becomes the heart of the principal-agent problem we experience in contemporary corporations. Because both the owners (“principals”), and the managers (“agents”) are driven by their own self-
  • 8. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 8 8 interest, they have entirely different incentives that can lead to misallocations or inefficient uses of the company’s resources9. As aforementioned, the principals are looking for maximization of the long-term stock price, while the agents, even the most selfless ones, tend to pursue interests unique to their own needs21. Therefore, agents often take actions that are not deemed by principals as the most appropriate; this misalignment of incentives is known as the agency problem9. Common symptoms of such problem often include excessive risk-taking by management as they are partially shielded from the risk of loss25. If too much risk is taken on by the agents, they do incur losses in the form of lost compensation, impaired reputation in the marketplace, and the opportunity cost of searching for a new job. However, their personal assets are protected and in certain cases, sudden dismissal can often lead to substantial severance packages. However, this does not necessarily make it beneficial for the manager to take actions that will get him fired; it does, on the other hand, illustrate that costs incurred as a result of too much risk taking are relatively low for the executives. Clearly, the remaining costs spillover to other market participants, whether they are directly involved in the agency contract, or not9. Most often, principals incur losses when part of their returns on investment is forgone. While these costs can be material to the individual investor, it is important to note that the personal assets of each and every shareholder are protected by corporate law; the extent of the loss that can be borne by investors only amounts to the size of their investment and creditors cannot make a claim on their personal property11. In addition, costs of fraud are often borne by other stakeholders involved with the company, such as its employees, retirees, suppliers, customers, and industry competitors. As in the case of Enron and many others, retirement savings were forever lost for those who worked for the company, and many found themselves struggling to find work. Moreover, other natural gas companies, while maintaining healthy internal control and steady operations, saw their stock price plummet alongside Enron as investors lost confidence in the entire industry. Finally, unrelated third parties may be forced to bear part of the cost. These third parties, in our case the taxpaying and voting public, incurred costs in the form of lost production but also the additional tax imposed to fund new regulation. Because third parties absorb part of these losses, the social cost of risk-taking and fraud in general is higher than the private cost incurred by the agents alone. This creates a negative externality, leaving the society with a greater amount of fraud than is desired. To illustrate, let us examine how the principal-agent problem manifested itself in each of the three case studies.
  • 9. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 9 9 An essential element of every principal-agent problem is the extent of controls present to prevent or detect discrepancies or outright fraud in the system. Here, we focus on two main forms of control relevant to our case scenarios-internal, which includes the checks and balances as well as corporate governance and organizational culture, and external, which is represented by a myriad of “watchdog” institutions that maintain additional oversight of the company´s operations22. Overall, the combined operating effectiveness of these controls determines the risk that fraud will not be prevented or detected, which in turn determines the likelihood of fraud occurrence22. control environment external auditors investing public regulatory oversight Figure 1 Levels of FraudDetection Fraud Potential Fraud Occurence Detection Level 1 Detection Level 2 control activities monitoring financial analysts, credit rating agencies Internal Control External Control First, internal control has several key components including the control environment, control activities, and monitoring of the controls in place. Referring to the fraud case studies, the control environment will be the single most decisive component in our analysis. As per professional accounting literature, company control environment consists of appreciation for ethical business conduct, an effective board of directors, and properly designed organizational structure, which also includes the corporate culture22. These components also directly relate to the theoretical framework surrounding the classic fraud triangle introduced by Statements of Auditing Standards No.99, which defines the conditions that must be present for one to commit fraud10. Referring to Figure 2, we can see that for individual fraud, usually in the form of misappropriation of assets (defalcation) 22, to occur, three conditions need to be satisfied. First, the individual must have an incentive or a pressure to be able to commit the fraud; second, the attitude of the employee must be one that
  • 10. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 10 10 justifies the fraud. Last, an opportunity such as lack of or malfunction in internal controls must allow the individual to carry the fraud out10. Similarly, in a large corporate setting, dealing mostly with fraudulent financial reporting on the management level22, the fraud triangle is adapted to reflect the changing organizational scales. First, the leadership style of executives can provide incentives or exert pressure on employees to falsely improve their performance. Second, the corporate culture present within the organization often affects the attitudes of employees towards fraud; a hostile, cut-throat environment may make it more appealing to justify fraudulent behavior. Finally, management controls and their operating effectiveness should function to eliminate most opportunities for employees to commit fraud10. B) corporate B) attitude culture A) incentive/ A) leadership C) management pressure C) opportunity style controls Figure 2 FraudTriangle per SAS No.99 Individual-level Organization-wide In the case-scenario discussion that follows, each of these conditions will play a key role in determining why fraud was not prevented, and, most importantly, not detected by the internal control systems in place. Additionally, the external watchdogs failed to report the fraud that was slipping through the checks and balances within. Briefly mentioned in the discussion below, the failures of banking institutions, credit rating agencies, and stock underwriters to report unsound accounting practices contributed to the amount of loss that stakeholders incurred when the scandals unfolded. Referring back to the agency relationship between stockholders and managers, we can see that management override of internal control is a symptom of the principal-agent problem rather than its cause. While both internal and external controls play a critical role in these case scenarios, it is the divergent incentives of principals and agents that give rise to the phenomenon. These incentives give rise to three distinct situations that we commonly encounter when dealing with the principal-agent problem.
  • 11. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 11 11 agents cheat the principals principals assume the role of agents principals lie to themselves Fraud-relatedprincipal-agent problem Figure 3 First, as outlined in Figure3, the agents themselves tend to break the rules of the contract and work the systems in place to better suit their preferences. Often, this is a result of poor incentive alignment by the Board of Directors in terms of management compensation. While it is clear that the principals’ objective is to maximize the company’s long-term value, it is often difficult for them to design such a compensation package that would incentivize management to truly pursue this long-run objective11. When studying the fraud scenarios, it is obvious that misaligned incentives were at the heart of the problem at both Enron and Tyco International. To illustrate, Enron executives received compensation based on meeting several performance criteria, but focusing mainly on earnings per share (EPS). Because much of Enron´s operations’ focus was on maximizing EPS, many ignored the fact that most company growth was done through extensive debt financing, which did not create additional value for shareholders. The executives, however, collected substantial amounts of compensation as long as the share price increased; and therefore management made sure it did26. Over the years, total compensation for the 5 highest ranking Enron executives grew from 37.46 million dollars in 1996 to 107.67 million dollars in 2000, most of which was allocated to bonus payments and stock grants26. Stock options, at the time, were the popular means of aligning management values with the long-term stock price maximization goal of shareholders. Through granting ownership at discounted prices, principals hoped that managers would take a more long-run focus in operations and strategy-making. Enron executives, however, had few restrictions prohibiting them from cashing the stock options shortly after the exercise date, which defied the purpose of the stock option plan26. What resulted, then, was a vicious cycle of constant increases in the short-term share price, quick exercising of stock options, capital gains realization, and push for additional share price increases. In 2000 alone, Enron CEO Ken Lay earned 123.4 million dollars while
  • 12. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 12 12 former CEO Jeffrey Skilling cashed 62.5 million dollars by exercising their stock options in time. This excessive focus on share price and EPS not only shifted management’s focus to the short run, but it also eroded any intrinsic value the company still had27. Share prices and stock trading played a critical role in the Tyco International, Inc. fraud case as well. Over their years in function, top executives managed to gain 430 million dollars at the company’s expense through fraudulent trading. This again reflected the short- term focus that management had which, eventually, eroded Tyco’s average share price and long-term value. Another fraud component prominent at Tyco was the misappropriation of company assets for personal use by the CEO, Dennis Kozlowski, and his closest advisors12. Over the years, Kozlowski managed to acquire a 16.8 million-dollar apartment on Fifth Avenue, pay off an 80,000-dollar American Express bill, and organize his wife’s birthday party in Sardinia for 2.1 million dollars by covering these expenses from Tyco’s funds. Other executives, including the CFO Mark Swartz and General Counsel Mark Belnick, received millions of dollars for personal purchases including real estate, yachts, fine arts, and business investments. Clearly, the focus was not on long-run shareholder value maximization, but on generating sufficient profit to allow for embezzlements of such extent to go unnoticed1. Considering the amounts that were either falsely disclosed, as in the case of Enron, or outright embezzled, as in Tyco’s case, one begins to wonder how such transactions remained unnoticed for such a long period of time. Surely, there must have been some level of suspicion when millions of dollars were misplaced. It is important to remember, though, that in both cases, the conditions described in Figure 2 all reached an alignment that allowed fraud to go unreported. To illustrate how the combination of poor leadership, hostile corporate culture, and weak management controls prevented all actors involved from reporting these fraudulent activities, we turn our attention to the environment in which both Enron and Tyco employees operated. First, the company culture at Enron was one that honored innovation, exceptional performance, and individualism, but at the same time despised failure or anyone failing to succeed in the ever-increasing race for greater profit. Jeffrey Skilling himself promoted behavior with a razor-sharp profit focus and discouraged questioning of methods that generated it. All Enron employees were periodically evaluated under the Peer Review Committee (PRC) system, which eliminated the worst-performing 15 percent of employees every six months. Through the PRC system and a set of incentives that idolized profit-
  • 13. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 13 13 oriented behavior, Enron´s employees quickly learned to seek gains whenever they could, even at the expense of their colleagues. In their never-ending bonus chasing, they happily failed to question their sources10. Second, the leadership style instituted by Skilling only further promoted the individualistic, short-term, performance-oriented behavior that slowly eroded the company´s value. Since compensation in the form of stock option plans was tied so closely to share price, most employees focused on share price maximization only, with little regard for its long-term effects. For instance, John Arnold, one of Enron’s traders, conducted transactions that generated over 700 million dollars in “book” profit, which earned him a 15 million dollar bonus that he cashed and then terminated his employment10. Finally, the ever-increasing profits and related capital gains of all Enron employees helped loosen the integrity of everyone involved, even those charged with internal oversight. Even though Enron championed a seemingly superior system of management controls, the compensation-related incentives created many opportunities for control overrides. For instance, both the Risk Assessment and Control Group charged with evaluation of new contracts and the Board of Directors failed to report questionable practices of management because the company’s continued profitability, not professional objectivity, was of their primary interest. Finally, the checks and balances in place were completely circumvented by Skilling, which was of little concern as long as the stock price was growing10. In a similar fashion, most of the fraud taking place at Tyco International was linked directly to its CEO, Dennis Kozlowski. From the very beginning, Kozlowski’s management style was characterized by aggressive growth. This would not have been a problem if it was complimented by strong internal control and oversight. However, at Tyco, this approach was coupled with a unique form of decentralization that made such oversight difficult to exercise. Even before Kozlowski’s time as CEO, he worked hard not only to expand the company’s operations, but also to diversify it into separate units. As a result, Tyco International constituted four different business units- including electronics, medical products, security services, and flow control12. While this approach generated immense growth for Tyco’s shareholders, it also allowed Kozlowski to single-handedly control each of the four segments. Because the heads of these business units reported directly to Kozlowski, who himself presented the company performance to the Board of Directors, it was relatively easy for him to conceal true
  • 14. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 14 14 operations to those charged with oversight. In addition, Kozlowski enhanced this decentralized structure with a management bonus system that seemingly reduced compensation, but in fact gave executives greater power over their paychecks. His leadership style did not allow questions regarding the company’s direction or its current activities, and anyone raising them was quickly silenced. In fact, Kozlowski was responsible for terminating his own employees who were doubting the reported numbers. Also, he exercised power over the external environment, such as ensuring the termination of a Merrill Lynch analyst who was questioning the company’s operating results12. As a result, the leadership style Kozlowski had implemented granted him extreme power over the company and its operating environment. The Board of Directors, already weakened by decentralization, also consisted of members who were, in most cases, personally elected by Kozlowski. These members, while not in absolute control of the Board, also held all the critical management positions at Tyco. Most of the Board and the company was controlled by Mark Swartz, CFO, Joseph Welch, CEO of one of Tyco’s business units, and Frank Walsh, Jr., the director of the Board. While there were certain indicators that Kozlowski’s behavior was unethical, and even illegal, these members, who had a major conflict of interest, helped conceal and often participated in the fraud that was taking place12. Clearly, the CEO’s leadership style as well as poorly functioning management controls provided great opportunity for fraud to go uncovered. However, unlike the Enron case, Tyco International’s corporate culture did not glorify the unethical practices that were taking place. While Enron’s employees were encouraged to turn questionable profits to enable their lavish lifestyles, the image that Tyco portrayed was one of modesty. Even though Kozlowski’s actions did not match this general message, most employees were never made aware of how the executives really lived. Quite contrarily, Kozlowski made it a point to advertise the frugality with which management operated even in his public interviews12. This approach, although seemingly trivial, helped Tyco recover from the losses that resulted from the 2002 scandal. Unlike Enron, Tyco’s employees were still creating value for their shareholders. While the executives misused some of those assets for personal use, this value-backed approach provided a basis for a gradual recovery12. We can see that the first manifestation of the principal-agent problem, where agents cheat principals because of inverted incentives, can be greatly reduced by proper implementation of strong oversight and other well-designed management controls22. In the
  • 15. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 15 15 cases of Enron and Tyco, however, these controls were completely subverted, which created the environment that allowed management to commit fraud on an organization-wide scale. The detection of this fraud and subsequent correction of related misstatements, will be in question next. Referring back to Figure 3, another problem we encounter in the principal-agent dilemma is that in certain situations, the principals fail to recognize that fraud is taking place. Rather, principals refuse to act responsibly even though the indicators of unethical behavior are clearly present. Often, this is a result of extensive conflicts of interest that were also present in both of our case studies. As illustrated above, the Boards of Directors charged with internal oversight at both Enron and Tyco lost their objectivity as their personal well-being was largely dependent on the success of the company under their control. At Enron, the Board of Directors was generously compensated for the company’s success in growing the share price and therefore its members’ personal stakes in the continued operation of the company were high29. Because Enron’s stock price never stopped growing, the incentive for Board members to report unethical practices was nonexistent. Instead, most tended to overlook the fact that profits were being misstated because the false earnings report often resulted in very real compensation. In fact, the average compensation of a director was 400,000 dollars in the year 2001, and bonuses for additional consulting services were generous29. Other controls, including the finance, compliance, and audit committees, as well as the financial disclosure director, were in a situation parallel to that of the Board, and gave up professional skepticism for greater compensation10. At Tyco, the Board of Directors was not only overlooking the presence of fraud; rather, it was directly participating in it. Many, while not all, Board members received hidden payments from the company that served to satisfy the members’ personal needs. For instance, the director, Frank Walsh, was granted a secret 20 million dollar bonus for his services in the acquisition sector. In addition, other companies under Walsh’s control often contracted with Tyco, and they received generous compensation for their services12. When Tyco’s fraud surfaced, Mark Swartz, CFO, and Dennis Kozlowski, CEO, were accused of misappropriating over 170 million dollars in assets and realizing gains of 430 million dollars on illegal trading of Tyco’s stock12. Clearly, these related-party transactions eliminated any objectivity of the Board, and the hidden payments helped many of its members overlook the lack thereof.
  • 16. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 16 16 Moreover, Enron and Tyco experienced conflicts of interest that extended beyond the firms’ boundaries. In both cases, outside institutions, including the bankers and financial analysts, had little incentive to launch investigation of questionable corporate behavior of their clients. Because these institutions had high stakes in the client’s earnings, they feared that reporting these practices would threaten the revenue generated by servicing the client. For instance, both Citigroup Inc. and JP Morgan Chase were fined over 225 million dollars by the SEC in the aftermath of the Enron scandal for loaning funds to Enron in a way that improved the appearance of the firm’s cash flows. However, Enron’s bankers were not the only ones at fault. Financial analysts, along with credit rating agencies, were all partaking in the vicious cycle of profit-chasing and thus failed to exercise professional judgment in evaluating the company8. In Tyco International’s case, the conflicts of interest were of equal proportions. As aforementioned, Merrill Lynch failed to adjust its rating of the company stock and instead terminated the employee raising who questioned Tyco’s transparency. This was a rational approach for Merrill Lynch as their company’s revenue-generating abilities were closely tied to those of Tyco. In fact, Merrill Lynch not only provided consulting services on the division of frequent mergers and acquisitions, but it also acted as a major underwriter of Tyco’s stock12. Clearly, downgrading the stock of one of its clients would hurt the performance of the financial giant as well; therefore, the integrity had to go out the door to preserve the revenues. Finally, the actors blamed the most for their shortcoming in discovering and reporting these misstatements were the external auditors. In the wake of both scandals, much attention was turned to the audit firms responsible for expressing unmodified opinions on the clearly misstated financial statements. In the case of Enron, the scandal itself proved fatal to its external auditors, Arthur Andersen & Company. At Tyco, the impact was not as extensive but brought losses in trust and reputation to PricewaterhouseCoopers (Pwc) 12. Naturally, the public looked to both accounting firms for independence, professional skepticism, and objectivity that would ensure the discovery and subsequent disclosure of fraud. However, they overlooked the fact that these external auditors, while independent in form, faced the same conflicts of interest as any other institution transacting with their fraud- affected clients. In fact, auditor independence was practically nonexistent in matter as revenue ties between the client and its auditor were profound13.
  • 17. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 17 17 Because accounting firms generated most of their revenue through consulting, information system design and implementation, and management advice, the audits were often pushed to the margin of the budget. As a result, audits were not only performed by inexperienced staff, but the auditors themselves were pressured to perform the examination quickly and in less detail14. Because Enron represented its second-biggest client, Arthur Andersen was willing to overlook discrepancies in internal control as well as financial statement presentation to preserve non-attest revenue20. In addition, auditor independence was reduced to minimal levels as Andersen employees in Houston were granted several offices at Enron’s headquarters and regularly took part in company activities with other Enron employees. The lines were further blurred by frequent interchange of personnel between both companies; indeed, Andersen auditors were often hired by Enron to work on certain projects and vice versa. As a result, the auditors lost their independence but also got extensive exposure to the internal practices taking place at Enron13. Because Andersen auditors were aware of the fraud that they failed to disclose, they attempted to cover up their misconduct by shredding thousands of work papers and other related audit documentation from the years 1997 to 2000. This action later resulted in an investigation of the firm and ultimately led to its dissolution20. When looking at the proportion of audit and non-audit revenue generated by the accounting firms, it becomes obvious that extensive conflicts of interest prevented these external monitors from establishing independence. While Arthur Andersen received 25 million dollars for performing the external audit, it was also paid an additional 27 million dollars for other services13. The audit revenues tied to Tyco that were generated by PricewaterhouseCoopers in 2001 amounted to 13.2 million dollars, which was only a small fraction of the 51.1 million dollars paid for all of Pwc’s services12. This disproportion of fees, coupled with a direct incentive for continued success of their client, created an environment where both quality and accuracy of audits were secondary to revenue generation. From the illustrations provided above, it is clear that those charged with oversight within as well as outside the companies had little motivation to investigate the discrepancies they encountered in dealing with the clients. Because the auditors’ revenues were tied to the
  • 18. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 18 18 clients’, the incentive was to overlook the facts and hope that others would do the same, which proved to be a sustainable practice for several years. Referring back to Figure 3, the last manifestation of the principal-agent problem emerges when principals also assume the role of agents. The Madoff Ponzi Scheme serves as a perfect illustration of this form of principal-agent dilemma. Because Bernie Madoff acted as both the principal, the founder and owner of BMLIS, and the agent, the chief managing partner of the company, the incentives to cheat were even greater. First, Madoff did not face costs in the form of repercussion from the directors or other owners, which reduced his total costs of fraud. Second, his investment firm was organized as a limited liability corporation, which shielded Madoff himself from creditors that would make claims on his personal assets should losses occur6. As a result, the objectives of the agent were perfectly aligned with those of the principal because both resided in the same individual. Consequently, Madoff was able to extract over 65 billion dollars from his clients through false generation of trading reports, and this Ponzi scheme helped him realize 20 million dollars in personal gains. By accepting clients who were looking for exceptional returns, accumulating their savings, seemingly investing them in overseas markets, and using the accounts to pay off other clients, Madoff orchestrated the largest Ponzi scheme to that date. Because no trading actually occurred, Madoff was forced to create false confirmations, reports, financial statements, and SEC filings23. In his plea allocution, he admitted to authorizing audit reports and other SEC documentation and submitting them to be filed even though he was aware that they were completely misstated15. As in the two previous cases, the investors had a tendency to overlook the whole truth about Madoff’s trading strategy. Similar to Enron’s Board of Directors, Madoff’s clients enjoyed the profits they read in the reports and failed to question the mechanisms behind them23. Indeed, none of his clients questioned the split-strike conversion strategy that Madoff claimed to had invented simply because it was too good to be doubted15. Moreover, Madoff’s clients put much trust into the BMLIS owner based on the extensive experience that he had accumulated over the years in the financial markets. Clearly, the co-founder of NASDAQ and SEC trading advisor took advantage of much blind trust from these clients who failed to see beyond his public image23.
  • 19. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 19 19 As illustrated above, all three forms of the principal-agent problem, whether it is agents cheating the system, principals lying to themselves, or agents simultaneously acting as principals, can generate outcomes with gravely negative consequences. In the wake of all three scandals, many were startled to find that private markets gains sometimes get offset by losses, and the negative impacts of these corporate failures caused a huge public outcry. Consequently, there was a great push for additional regulation as many individuals lost their faith in the stock market, or the corporate world altogether. Because the media linked much of the losses and pain to the executives who were also the faces of their respective corporations, many laid blame on them and came to believe that all executives were driven by self-interest and greed. In fact, the percentage of individuals who put “hardly any” trust in executives when asked increased from 11.7 percent to 17.3 percent after the Enron scandal3. As such, the average citizen felt the need to defend themselves against these dangerous individuals, and naturally, called for protection in the form of government reform. Since the Enron scandal was often linked to deregulation of the utilities industry, it appeared that additional legislation was an appropriate solution. In its outrage, the public failed to look beyond what was really happening in the financial world; they focused their attention on the symptoms of the scandals instead of addressing the underlying causes. At the time, the average investor who lost their savings due to Enron’s failure gave little regard to the economic concepts that initially caused the problem, and rightfully so. As a result of the public’s demand for a fast fix, Congress enacted the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 in response to the Enron scandal16, and the Wall-Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010, which addressed Madoff’s Ponzi scheme5. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act (Sarbox), signed by George W. Bush on July 30 of 2002, was only one of many regulations created to boost investor confidence in the stock markets across the U.S. history. Drafted in hand with the Securities and Exchange Commission, the Act had two major objectives. First, it sought to re-establish integrity in the financial markets and therefore increase investor confidence. Second, it strived to prevent future fraud cases through introduction of new disclosure requirements16. While the scope of the legislation was very broad, the key issues addressed included financial statement disclosure, external auditor independence, and integrity of the accounting profession in general. First, the adoption of Sarbox mandated that corporate executives, mainly CEOs and CFOs, accept direct responsibility for the content and presentation of the
  • 20. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 20 20 financial statements. Under Sarbox, both the CEO and CFO must certify that the financials are accurately stated in all material respects and full disclosure has been achieved. Because the Act increased the penalties for false representations, the cost of committing fraud through false financial reporting has increased for executives16. While corporate executives were blamed for committing the fraud, the external auditors were the second most targeted actors in all three of the scandals. As a result, much of the Act focused its attention on enhancing auditor independence, which was so obviously lacking in the cases discussed above. While new requirements were numerous, a few key rules affected nearly every accounting firm in the country. First, public accounting companies were prohibited from performing certain services for clients they were engaged in an external audit with16. Second, the proportion of audit and non-audit fees was to be disclosed in the financial statements, along with a Board of Directors statement acknowledging those services and their impact on auditor independence22. Third, all audit committees were now required to consist of outside directors only, and all auditing matters, including planning and compensation, were to be settled through dealings with the committee rather than company management. Finally, public accounting firms performing more than 100 issuer audits were to be inspected every year and partners on engagements were to rotate among clients every 5 years16. Lastly, because the accounting profession was no longer trusted to operate effectively under self-regulation, Sarbox created the Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB), which was charged with oversight over public accounting in general. Representing a subdivision of the SEC, the PCAOB has broad implications for both accounting firms and their clients. Among others, the Board enforces standards put in place by Sarbox, but can also modify or completely reject any rules adopted by the Auditing Standards Board (ASB). As such, it exercises great control over the accounting profession, and has the power to directly affect the “rules of the game” adopted by the financial markets16. Clearly, the scope of the Sarbox legislation is very broad. Even though the perceived benefits include increased investor confidence, greater ease of capital acquisition by public corporations, and future fraud prevention, a true measure of its utility will not be available for years to come. The costs, on the other hand, have already been measured through research, and they have proven to be immense.
  • 21. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 21 21 However, even such extensive regulation as the Sarbanes-Oxley Act did not prevent the financial world from experiencing another fraud-related scandal. Only a few years later, the world watched as the Madoff scandal unfolded and the subprime mortgage loan market bubble burst. In an attempt to calm the public outrage that followed, the government rushed to the rescue again with additional regulation, the well-known Dodd-Frank Act of 20105. Enacted on July 21 of 2010, the Wall-Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act was adopted in response to the failures in the financial sector, particularly affecting the every-day operations of banking institutions and trading companies. While the implications are nearly impossible to summarize, the contents of the Act itself can be divided into several key sections. Financial Stability Reform, Agency Oversight Reform, Securitization Reform, Derivatives Regulation, Investor Protection Reform, Credit Rating Agency Reform, Compensation and Corporate Governance, and the Volcker Rule are all components of this seemingly all-encompassing legislation. Rather than focusing on regulating the actors charged with outside oversight, this Act seeks to directly regulate the financial institutions themselves17. Relevant to the problems addressed in this paper, the Dodd-Frank Act seeks to impose extensive restrictions on derivative trading as well as securitization by banking institutions. Through the establishment of the Financial Stability Oversight Council, the legislation imposes rules ranging from risk retention by securitizers to prohibition of proprietary trading by bankers. In essence, the Derivative and Securitization sections of the Act aim to amend previous regulation by strengthening the oversight, disclosure, and documentation in these respective industry segments17. Further, the Investor Protection Reform focuses on improving investor understanding of financial markets through additional disclosure requirements enforced by the SEC. This new function also mandates that periodic studies be conducted by the SEC on reporting standards or lack thereof, self-regulation of certain organizations, analyst-related conflicts of interest, and so forth. Finally, the creation of the Investor Advisory Committee, a sub-section of the SEC, is aimed at further increasing investor confidence and thus bringing capital back into financial markets17. In addition, a portion of the Act is devoted to addressing corporate governance structures as well as the compensation packages that executives receive. Mostly focusing on additional disclosure by corporations, the Compensation and Corporate Governance section
  • 22. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 22 22 also requires that executive compensation be reduced in the event that accounting misstatements occur. Further, independence issues are addressed through new rules imposed on corporate compensation committees17. Similar to the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, the main objective of the Dodd- Frank Act of 2010 was to boost the falling investor confidence in the financial markets17. In theory, an increase in investor trust in the markets would also enhance the ease of capital formation and acquisition as investors would become more likely to provide their savings to corporations. While the objectives were clearly designed with good intentions in mind, it will be very difficult to evaluate the actual benefits provided by these Acts. First, the benefits will be nearly impossible to quantify because of the nature of the industry; second, the Acts may produce unwanted secondary effects that might completely offset any benefits created. While no exact measures can be provided at this time, many researchers set out to estimate the impacts that both Sarbox and Dodd Frank have had on the financial community. When looking at the research conducted, we find that while the benefits are questionable, the costs are very real, and indeed have been measured to be extensive. First, the costs related to the Sarbanes-Oxley Act have been relatively easy to observe because the legislation has been in place for over a decade. While researchers differ in the exact estimations of the Act-related costs, we can use these figures to at least approximate the scope of Sarbox´s impact. In general, the costs associated with the implementation of Sarbox can be divided into direct, or auditing and administration costs, and indirect, or opportunity costs. According to the Academy of Management Perspectives, in the years following the Act’s adoption, the audit fees amounted to 8.5 million and 1.25 million for large and small firms, respectively. While this figure represents about 0.1 percent of all sales for large companies, the toll on earnings is even greater for small firms28. Researchers at Texas A&M also found that from 2001 to 2007, the absolute costs related to the implementation of the Act were 39 million, 7 million, and 6 million for large, medium-sized, and small firms, respectively. This increase in costs also affected the companies’ cash flows; on average, cash flows from sales declined by 1.8 percent while cash flows from assets declined by 1.3 percent. Overall, Sarbox costs eliminated about 0.5 percent of total cash flows in large corporations and up to 3 percent in small companies28.
  • 23. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 23 23 Finally, a study by Financial Executives International addresses the first-year costs incurred by companies to stay in compliance with the Act´s provisions. For companies generating, on average, 5 billion dollars in revenue, the expenses included 1.34 million in internal administration (27,000 work hours), 1.30 million in auditing expenses, and 1.72 million spent on information technology and consultants7. Unfortunately, most studies indicate that while the impact on large corporations is significant, the firms picking up most of the costs are relatively small businesses28. As a result, the indirect costs of the legislation might have a lasting negative impact on the economy as business activity contracts under such prohibitive costs. Second, the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act was signed into effect only recently; therefore, the process of cost estimation has proven to be more difficult. Nevertheless, the extent of the Act itself suggests that the absolute costs might be so great that they will never be truly accounted for in their entirety. To illustrate, the first four years of compliance alone have imposed over 21.8 billion dollars of additional costs on the financial industry, which translated into human capital costs of 60.7 million hours in administrative work. The expenses incurred are not only significant, but are growing at an increasing rate as well. From 2013 to 2014, when this research was published, the costs grew by 6.4 million dollars, which is an increase of 41 percent in a single year18. Perhaps because of the extent of the regulation and the fear that the public might not approve of the additional costs to taxpayers, the government failed to disclose the full amounts incurred; indeed, some cost analyses were released months after the Act was passed and most were greatly understated. Moreover, certain costs were never made public. For instance, a number of sections in the Dodd-Frank Act responsible for new rules were completely omitted from the cost estimation process. When evaluated by researchers, these sections added up to 1.2 billion dollars in additional costs18. Moreover, the indirect costs imposed on the financial industry are profound and perhaps more damaging than the cost related to administration. Because the cost of conducting business has increased for many financial institutions, especially smaller banks, it is possible that we will experience a real increase in the cost of capital, and perhaps a decrease in its availability.
  • 24. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 24 24 This secondary effect, then, might have very real implications for the individual citizen as banks and other financial intermediaries might be reluctant to provide certain services. Since the adoption, the most eliminated business units were residential mortgages, home equity lines of credit, and lending in general. To illustrate, a study conducted in 2014 by the American Bankers Association revealed that two-thirds of the institutions involved would decrease the volume of lending18. While knowing the exact amounts of the costs imposed on both the corporate entity and the consumer is impossible, the process of estimation provides us with a clear idea of the size of the impact that will sweep through the financial markets. Being made aware of these costs, the only question left to ask is whether the adoption of such costly laws can be economically justified. Conclusion In correctly assessing the situation, it is important to ask why the public asked for additional regulation in the first place. Essentially, the reason behind most of the public pressure was the desire for fraud prevention in future years. Because they were concerned about the losses that had to be absorbed in the aftermath of these scandals, the average citizens wished to see the risk of such loss eliminated. Being rationally ignorant, the persons would look to government regulation as the optimal solution to such a seemingly complex issue. While the intentions of most people involved in the regulation-crafting process were undoubtedly honorable, in the eyes of the economist, these intentions are ultimately irrelevant. Instead, the focus of proper economic analysis is on the outcomes generated by each respective solution, which is what ultimately affects the individual consumer. Therefore, to arrive at an accurate conclusion, it is necessary to consider the factors relevant to both fraud prevention and related business regulation, and the outcomes they generate in private markets. First, it is essential to understand that fraud is, and always will be, a component of private markets, whether they are regulated or not. Because all individuals act in self-interest, the temptation to commit fraud is an inherent part of human nature. Under conditions where incentives are misaligned, whether through compensation or other mechanisms, individuals will tend to undertake fraudulent activities because it is the rational thing to do. While statistically rare, a few individuals with above-average risk appetite will gain control of key
  • 25. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 25 25 resources and such instances will likely lead to losses. Finally, gains will always be offset by losses in private markets, whether due to fraud or natural market activity, and this self- equilibration cannot be prevented by any outside mechanism. As a result, it is clear that the principal-agent problem introduced in this paper will always be present; indeed, no solution has yet been found to eliminate the problems associated with this dilemma. Therefore, as long as principals act in self-interest, agents will act in self-interest as well, and their interaction will cause inefficiencies in markets. Second, while such notions are romantic in theory, the presence of regulation in private markets will not prevent or eliminate fraud. Apart from establishing property rights and enforcing contracts, there is not much more the government can do to improve the efficiency of private markets. Looking at the number and scope of financial regulation we have, ranging from the Securities Acts of 1933 and 1934, through Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988, to Dodd-Frank Act of 2010, it would seem reasonable to expect no additional fraud to occur16. However, as evidenced by new scandals emerging every year, this is not so. In fact, adoption of additional regulation might have quite the opposite effect; because investors often regain trust in the financial markets when new regulation is introduced, they begin to have a false sense of security which, in turn, makes them less observant and more susceptible to losses. In essence, government regulation reduces the apparent need for questioning, which increases the potential for fraud and risk of investor loss. Further, even with the best intentions in mind, it would be impossible for the government to solve the principal-agent problem because like any other market entity, the government faces such a problem as well. As illustrated above, the agencies responsible for cost estimation and disclosure of the Dodd-Frank act failed to report to the public the true amounts of expenses that taxpayers would bear18. It is questionable, then, if the government should oversee proper disclosure by other institutions when it fails to exercise proper disclosure on its own. After examining both sides of the issue, one is tempted to ask whether the costs of regulation outweigh the losses incurred as a result of fraud. In the principal-agent problem, we encounter the so-called agency costs, which are costs borne by principals when agents fail to follow the agency contract and take actions different from those preferred by principals. The
  • 26. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 26 26 agency costs represent the suboptimal results illustrated in the case studies, and such costs should not be taken lightly, whether in their extent or nature9. However, the costs of regulation are also high; taxpayers bear the immense costs of implementation and they must also face the unexpected secondary effects of regulation on markets across time. Often, these secondary effects can have more profound consequences than any fraud could; decreases in overall productivity and reduction of business activity are just two of many examples. While the question of whether regulation is too costly to be used as a form of fraud prevention will be left to each individual and their personal preferences, there are certain factors that prove regulation to be a suboptimal solution to the problem of fraud. First, as mentioned above, fraud will never truly be eliminated, no matter the number of Acts Congress passes or the extent of each law. Second, in an attempt to regulate, governments and their citizens often forget to see the underlying causes of the problem and focus on symptoms instead, thus producing unwanted secondary effects. Last, it is impossible to regulate human nature to such an extent as to eliminate fraud without imposing limitations on basic human freedoms. In the concluding paragraphs, an alternative is presented that should allow each individual to evaluate the situation in terms of their own preferences. Referring back to the basic goal of every corporation, maximization of shareholder value, it is clear that no long- term goal-oriented corporation desires fraud to occur. Ultimately, neither managers nor owners want fraud present in their workplace as it inhibits the company’s ability to generate future profits, and often endangers its ability to continue as a going concern. This, in turn, has very real effects on the stakeholders’ well-being, and therefore there is a strong incentive to engage in activities that ensure fraud prevention. Even without government regulators, companies design extensive internal control systems and undertake monitoring activities that will protect them from losses from fraud. Tyco International, Inc. is a prime example of the fact that although fraud may occur, a company´s primary objective is to create value for the consumer and stay fraud-free. At Tyco, Edward Breen, who became CEO after Kozlowski´s infamous step-down, restructured the company and its internal control to prevent future misappropriations12.
  • 27. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 27 27 In the first few years, Breen ensured that 90% of the headquarters’ employees were replaced, severance payments increased for executives, and a new Guide to Ethical Conduct was adopted. Even without the guidance from Sarbanes Oxley, Breen required that the Board chairman be independent of the company and a new Board of Directors be elected by the shareholders. These and other measures illustrate Tyco´s natural desire to prevent fraud without the presence of regulation12. In conclusion, the argument that each of us faces is very simple; is it more beneficial to accept private markets with their inherent inefficiencies and risks of loss, and enjoy the ability to exercise our freedoms in making decisions, or are the costs of doing so too high? Similarly, do the benefits of increased government control, such as greater perceived degree of safety, outweigh the costs, such as the lack of freedom to choose? Do we, as rationally ignorant, self-interested market participants, willingly overlook the additional inefficiencies generated by government to create a false sense of security for ourselves? Finally, how willing are we to regulate our own human nature?
  • 28. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 28 28 Sources 1. American Institute of Public Accountants. (2005, January 1). Tyco International Ltd. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&ved=0CB4QFj AA&url=http://www.aicpa.org/InterestAreas/AccountingEducation/Resources/Download ableDocuments/tyco.ppt&ei=wgE3VdzFHsykyASi04DoCw&usg=AFQjCNE5Vtd1NLj3 UhXDgdNJQZ_sFqQ9tw&bvm=bv.91427555,d.aWw 2. Von Frentz C. (2003, June 25). Consequences of the ENRON Scandal. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.global-ethic-now.de/gen-eng/0d_weltethos-und-wirtschaft/0d- 01-globale-wirtschaft/0d-01-203-enron-folgen.php 3. Neuman, E. (2005, January 1). THE IMPACT OF THE ENRON ACCOUNTING SCANDAL ON IMPRESSIONS OF. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://ericneuman.com/Papers/post-enron-attributions_aom_2005.pdf 4. Bernstein, E. (2009, February 12). Madoff Scandal's Deep Impact On Funding for Health, Science. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB123439995182175299 5. Alessandro, K. (2013, January 1). How Madoff Has Transformed the Investment Industry. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.eci.com/blog/488-five-years-later- how-bernie-madoff-has-transformed-the-investment-industry.html 6. Lenzner, R. (2008, January 1). Bernie Madoff's $50 Billion Ponzi Scheme. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.forbes.com/2008/12/12/madoff-ponzi-hedge-pf-ii- in_rl_1212croesus_inl.html 7. Goelzer, D. (2005, January 1). The Costs & Benefits of Sarbanes-Oxley Section 404. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://pcaobus.org/News/Speech/Pages/03212005_GoelzerCostsBenefitsofSOX404. aspx 8. Kay, J. (2003, August 5). World Socialist Web Site. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from https://www.wsws.org/en/articles/2003/08/enrn-a05.html 9. Bezroukov, N. (2015, January 1). Principal-agent problem. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.softpanorama.org/Skeptics/Financial_skeptic/Casino_capitalism/Systemic_ins tability_of_financial_sector/principal_agent_problem.shtml
  • 29. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 29 29 10. Free, C., Macintosh, N., Stein, M., Macintosh, N., & Stein, M. (2007, August 1). Ivey Business Journal. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://iveybusinessjournal.com/publication/management-controls-the-organizational- fraud-triangle-of-leadership-culture-and-control-in-enron/ 11. Brigham, E., and Houston, J. (2011, January 26) Fundamentals of Financial Management Cengage Learning 8th Edition pp 9-15 12. Boostrom, R. (2011, January 1). Daniels Fund Ethics Initiative. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://danielsethics.mgt.unm.edu/ 13. Herrick, T., & Barrionuevo, A. (2002, January 21). Were Enron, Anderson Too Close To Allow Auditor to Do Its Job? Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB1011565452932132000 14. Chicago Tribune. (2002, September 1). The fall of Andersen. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://chicagotribune.com/news/chi-0209010315sep01-story.html 15. Madoff, B. (2009, March 12). The Text of Madoff's Plea Allocution. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://dealbook.nytimes.com//2009/03/12/the-text-of-madoffs-plea-allocution/ 16. Hoyle, J. (2014) “Financial Reporting and the Securities and Exchange Commission” Advanced Accounting 12th edition from http://textflow.mheducations.com/parser.php?secload=12&fake&print 17. Morrison, A. (2011, January 1). Dodd-Frank Cheat Sheet. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&ved=0CB4QFj AA&url=http://www.mofo.com/files/uploads/images/summarydoddfrankact.pdf&ei=H6 w3Vfi_LtGoogTSkYHADg&usg=AFQjCNGoBlXXLyNhDuUm2UxEXtMnN9mNNA& bvm=bv.91427555,bs.1,d.aWw 18. Winkler, A., Gitis, B., & Batkins, S. (2014, July 15). Dodd-Frank at 4: More Regulation, More Regulators, and a Sluggish Housing Market | Research. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://americanactionforum.org/research/dodd-frank-at-4-more-regulation-more- regulators-and-a-sluggish-housing-mark 19. Li, Y. (2010, October 1). The Case Analysis of the Scandal of Enron. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&ved=0CB4QFj AA&url=http://www.ccsenet.org/journal/index.php/ijbm/article/viewFile/7627/5855.&ei =2Kw3VaWTLtG6ogTEkYCQDA&usg=AFQjCNFzjeNPvcL3L0ZRH4tN8odcmkMFK Q&bvm=bv.91071109,d.cGU
  • 30. CAN WE REGULATE HUMAN NATURE? 30 30 20. Thomas, C. (2002, March 31). The Rise and Fall of Enron. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.journalofaccountancy.com/Issues/2002/Apr/TheRiseAndFallOfEnron.htm 21. McEachern, W. (2013). Contemporary economics (3 e. ed., pp. 312-314). Mason, Ohio: South-Western Cengage Learning 22. Whittington, R., & Pany, K. (2013). Principles of auditing and other assurance services (13th ed., pp. 244-253). Boston: Irwin/McGraw-Hill. 23. Yang, S. (2014, July 1). 5 Years Ago Bernie Madoff Was Sentenced to 150 Years In Prison – Here's How His Scheme Worked. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.businessinsider.com/how-bernie-madoffs-ponzi-scheme-worked-2014- 7#ixzz3XratglBu 24. Time. (1995, January 1). Fortune. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://archive.fortune.com/magazines/fortune/fortune500_archive/snapshots/1995/478.ht ml 25. Times. (2015, January 1). Moral Hazard Definition | Moral Hazard Meaning - The Economic Times. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/definition/moral-hazard 26. Ackman, D. (2002, March 22). Pay Madness At Enron. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.forbes.com/2002/03/22/0322enronpay.html 27. Hitt, G., & Schlesinger, J. (2002, March 26). Stock Options Come Under Fire In the Wake of Enron's Collapse. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB1017093594617163160 28. Martin, J. (2010, August 1). Sarbanes-Oxley: Does the Cost Knock Your Socks Off? Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://amp.aom.org/content/24/3/103.extract 29. Abelson, R. (2002, January 18). One Enron Inquiry Suggests Board Played Important Role. Retrieved April 22, 2015, from http://www.nytimes.com/2002/01/19/business/enron-s-collapse-directors-one-enron- inquiry-suggests-board-played-important.html