SlideShare una empresa de Scribd logo
1 de 6
Descargar para leer sin conexión
CO2 Taxation in Sweden
Experiences of the Past and Future Challenges
by Susanne Åkerfeldt and Henrik Hammar*)
*) The views expressed in the paper do not necessarily reflect those of the Swedish Ministry of Finance.
English language version of article published in French in the October 2015 issue of the journal Revue Projet as
well as on their web site (http://www.revue-projet.com/articles/2015-09-akerfeldt-hammar-la-taxe-carbone-en-
suede/).
@ Revue Projet journal
Contact info for corresponding with authors:
E-mail: susanne.akerfeldt@gov.se
Phone: +46 8 405 1382
Susanne Åkerfeldt, Senior Adviser, Swedish Ministry of Finance, Tax and Customs Department
Susanne Åkerfeldt has a Master’s Degree in Law from Uppsala University, Sweden and is an Associate Judge of
Appeal. She’s a ministerial adviser and international negotiator with more than 20 years of experience related to
policy design of cost-efficient environmental taxation, its interaction with other policy measures nationally and
globally on the road towards developing a sustainable, low-carbon and resource-efficient society. She has been
instrumental in the development of the Swedish CO2 tax over the years and has a long and broad experience of
negotiating energy taxation matters within the EU.
Henrik Hammar Senior Adviser, Swedish Ministry of Finance, Tax and Customs Department
Henrik Hammar completed in 2001 his PhD in economics at Gothenburg University, Sweden, concentrating on
energy and environmental issues and economic instruments in particular. Between 2001 and 2005 he was
secretary in two Swedish Governmental Committees in the area and did academic policy oriented research.
Between 2005 and 2008 he has worked at the Swedish National Institute of Economic Research, doing qualified
economic analyses in environmental economics, before joining the Ministry of Finance in 2008.
1. Sweden has been a pioneer regarding CO2 taxation. Can you remind how it concretely works?
Two different taxes on fuels form the base of the Swedish energy taxation system. An energy tax has been levied
on petrol and diesel since around 1930 and fossil heating fuels started to be taxed during the 1950’s. The CO2 tax
was in 1991 introduced on fossil fuels at rates equivalent to 27 €1
per tonne fossil CO2. At the same time the
energy tax rates were reduced by 50 per cent, which still meant an increase for all fuels.
Average CO2 emission and energy factors are used to calculate the tax rates. No measuring of actual emissions is
necessary. In order to ensure a simple administration, the CO2 tax rates are in the tax law expressed in weight or
volume units for the different fuels. The CO2 tax is collected in the same way as the energy tax, which gives low
administrative costs for the tax authorities as well as for the operators.
The CO2 tax, obviously, should aim at helping society to reach set climate targets. That is why it is logical to
base it on the content of fossil carbon, as only fossil fuel consumption results in net increases of CO2 to the
atmosphere. To also apply it to biofuels would constitute illogic taxation in relation to the aim of the tax and
would also, hence, make the tax less general and thereby less cost effective.
The rationale behind using a market based policy instrument such as a CO2 tax is that the price signal created by
the tax allows for numerous ways to avoid the tax. The cost effectiveness lies, hence, in that the society does not
‘pick a winner’ (e.g. a particular technology or a particular fuel) but rather allows households and firms to
choose the measures that are best (which typically coincide with least cost) for them. Such measures can range
from putting on an additional sweater to invest in a new technology with low or zero greenhouse gas (GHG)
emissions.
The CO2 tax rates have over the years been significantly increased, with the purpose of achieving cost effective
emission reductions by way of applying the Polluter Pays Principle. The tax changes have been implemented
stepwise to give households and firms time to adapt. The same CO2 tax rate is applied for motor fuels and
heating fuels, ensuring the same price signal and thus cost effective emission reductions by equalizing marginal
costs for abatement.
2. In France ecological taxes are the subject of regular changes. The continuity of the Swedish CO2 tax
system is very impressive: can you explain how the political consensus has been built behind it, why in
1991, and which kind of contest it has faced ever since?
The introduction of CO2 taxation in Sweden was part of a major tax reform that among other things implied
dramatically lower marginal income taxes on capital and labour, the elimination of various tax shelters and base
broadening of the value added tax. The political opportunity to introduce the CO2 tax consisted of the confluence
of two separate political processes. On the one hand, there was a demand for a drastic reduction in marginal
income tax rates which had reached very high levels. At the same time there was an increasing interest in
environmental issues politically and throughout the society.
1 Exchange rate used in this article: 1 € = 9,0932 SEK.
There is a broad political consensus of the basic CO2 tax structure and the use of the tax as the primary
instrument to achieve GHG reductions. Sweden has had left-wing and right-wing governments, but this has not
meant any major deviations from the chosen road forward. Business and other stakeholders are involved in the
decision making process by the constitutional system of sending out Government proposals for general public
consultation before presenting them to Parliament. The aim has been to implement tax raises and major changes
of the tax structure in a step by step approach, preferably being announced well in advance giving households
and firms time to adjust. The general CO2 tax rate chosen when the tax was introduced in 1991 was reasonably
low and it has taken us more than 20 years to reach the – what some may call exceptionally high – level of 123 €
per tonne fossil carbon.
Typically, CO2 tax increases for households and firms have been combined with general tax relief in other areas
in order to avoid increases in the overall level of taxation, address undesirable distributional consequences and
stimulate job growth. Such combination of measures creates a balance between different policy considerations.
Also, one aspect of a general welfare state is that it alleviates severe distributional consequences.
Preserving the environment is an issue given high priority not only by the Government but also by most citizens.
So while Swedes probably do not like to pay taxes any more than other people, there is a basic understanding
and acceptance of the underlying rationale to introduce economic instruments, such as the CO2 tax, to help reach
climate targets. It has also been essential over the years to ensure that the households and firms have feasible
options available to help in their transition to a low-carbon economy. While not earmarking CO2 tax revenues for
specific purposes, significant parts of the national budget have still over the years been allocated to various
projects, such as better public transport, an increased use of bio-fuelled district heating and housing isolation.
3. Has CO2 taxation in Sweden been detrimental to competitiveness and employment and how did you
tackle those issues?
The Swedish experience shows that it is possible to combine reduced emissions with economic growth. A
decoupling of the economic growth and reduced emissions could be seen already in 1996 and this development
has continued ever since. During the 1990-2013 period GDP increased by +61 percent, while at the same time
CO2 equivalent emissions was reduced by 23 percent2
.
An essential aspect has been to strike a balance between fulfilling environmental objectives and accounting for
the risks of carbon leakage (which in turn is related to securing the competitiveness of sectors that are subject to
international competition). Industry has ever since the introduction of the CO2 tax faced a lower tax level on
heating fuels than the household and service sectors. When introducing the CO2 tax at the general level of 27 € in
1991, the lower level for industry applied corresponded to 7 €. When the general level of the CO2 tax was raised
during following years, adjustments were also made of the lower level based on competiveness assessments and
other factors.
2 80 per cent of the CO2 e emissions consists of CO2 emissions.
Since it is essential to avoid disruptive effects on competitiveness, such a lower tax level has been a prerequisite
for a high tax level for other sectors and has been instrumental in achieving major emission reductions in the
household, transport and service sectors. This two-level system has in the past been the most important element
in the design of a well-functioning system to curb CO2 emissions in Sweden.
4. What have been the major changes in the Swedish CO2 tax system since its creation? Especially, how
did you integrate the European regulatory changes?
Sweden became a member of the EU in 1995 and adapted our existing legislation to the relevant Community
law. The general CO2 tax design was maintained, as it was in line with relevant EU rules.
As mentioned earlier, a general, lower CO2 tax level was chosen for the industrial sector, when introducing the
CO2 tax. It has been an administratively simple approach to allow for significant increases of the levels of CO2
taxation for other sectors. However, the development of Community law meanwhile resulted in the introduction
of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS), a Community wide economic instrument covering GHG
emissions from the major part of energy intensive industrial installations. In order to apply only one general
economic instrument as an incentive to reduce GHG emissions, no CO2 tax is from 2011 applied in Sweden on
fuels used by industrial installations within the EU ETS.
On the other hand, industry outside the EU ETS is in general less energy intensive and, hence, has relatively low
costs for energy. This implies that an increased CO2 tax for industry outside EU ETS do not cause major
disrupting effects on competitiveness. Further, many firms have relatively good opportunities to switch to non-
fossil heating sources, which is why an increased CO2 tax serve as an incentive to substitute to non-fossil energy.
In a step-wise approach, Sweden has thus increased the lower level for this sector during 2011-2015 (from 21 to
30 per cent of the general CO2 tax level in 2011 and from 30 to 60 per cent in 2015). The Government has
announced its intention to abolish the lower CO2 tax by 1 January 2016. However, it should be noted that a
structural shift from fossil fuels in industry can imply severe effects for individual firms, which also can cause
unwanted consequences on local/regional level. This risk is another reason for, if possible, applying a step-by-
step approach in order to give firms time to adapt and thereby alleviate some of these problems.]
The CO2 tax is levied on the content of fossil carbon in fuels, which meant that biofuels were not subject to the
CO2 tax from the start. Upon implementing the 2009 EU Renewables Directive, sustainability criteria for
biofuels and bioliquids were introduced as a condition for not subjecting such biofuels to the non-CO2 taxation.
According to EU law, aid can only be granted to sustainable biofuels and bioliquids. The EU Commission has
this far considered the Swedish CO2 tax design as a state aid to biofuels.
5. The energy mix in Sweden has shifted from fossil fuels towards biofuels in particular. What kind of
biofuels? Does the overall balance of Swedish CO2 emissions integrate "imported emissions" (incl.
possible deforestation in Amazonia linked with the development of soy, etc.)?
Over the last decades fossil heating fuels has to a large extent been phased out as a source for heating private
homes and apartment buildings. Recent figures show that 92 per cent of all apartments are heated by district
heating, primarily fuelled by household waste and various wood residues. The district heating grids are
continuously expanded to cover also small towns. However, Sweden is sparsely populated and single-family
homes in more remote areas are not connected to district heating grids. The phasing out of fossil fuels has in
those cases meant a transition to wood heat pumps, electricity3
and wood pellets burners. District heating is also
an instrumental source of space heating for the service sector – the figure is 80 per cent.
As for industry the last decades have seen a steady decline in specific energy use; that is amount of energy used
per monetary unit of value added. Technical innovation in Swedish industry has for a long time favoured
electricity solutions, due to the fact that hydro-electricity has been available at reasonably low prices and that
electricity used by industry is taxed with a considerably lower out-put energy tax than electricity used by
households and service sector firms. The energy used by Swedish industry comes primarily from biofuels (40
percent) and electricity (36 percent). Wood scrap products and liquid residues from the paper and pulp industry
account for the bulk part of the biofuels.
The balance of Swedish CO2 emissions is calculated and reported according to procedures that the global
community has agreed upon under the Kyoto Protocol. The annual reporting is based on emissions occurring
from the combustion of fuels within Sweden and at the same time combustion from fuels elsewhere in the world
is accounted for in the annual reports from those countries. Calculations have been made by the Swedish
Environmental Protection Agency of the impact on CO2 emissions from the consumption of Swedish individuals
taking place abroad, either by visits to those countries or by importing products manufactured in other countries.
However, it does not seem feasible in the foreseeable future to take account of such emissions when calculating a
CO2 tax in Sweden that is administratively simple to design and collect.
6. What are the next challenges ahead? Is there any risk that the CO2 tax system be given up? Have other
countries been convinced or interested enough by the Swedish experience to replicate it? If not, what kind
of factors have prevented them to do so?
The major challenge ahead lies in the area of motor fuels. The steadily increased CO2 tax on fossil motor fuels
has played a major role also for an increased use of biofuels in the transport sector. Currently about 11 per cent
of all propellants used in Sweden are biofuels. But major efforts are still needed in order for Sweden to be able to
reach the political vision of a fossil-free vehicle fleet by 2030 and no net increase on greenhouse gas emissions
by 2050.
The CO2 tax has served us well in Sweden as a powerful tool to help reach reductions in GHG emissions during
the past decades. Also for the future the Swedish Government sees the CO2 tax as the major economic
instrument to achieve emission reductions in sectors outside the EU ETS. The 2014 agreement in the European
Council calls for at least a 40 per cent reduction of GHG emissions by 2030. Member States will be obliged to
cut emissions substantially outside the EU ETS. To this end, the Member States need cost effective tools. A CO2
3 Sweden’s electricity production is to a large extent fossil free (figures for 2012: hydro 48 per cent, nuclear 38
per cent, combined heat and power, with basically biomass in-put 10 per cent, wind power 4 per cent; Swedish
Energy Agency, Energy in Sweden 2014).
tax is a key instrument to help reduce the use of fossil fuels and reach set climate targets. An inherent challenge
for the whole of the EU lies in the need to ensure that all parts of the Community legislation are consistently
applied and not creating obstacles for Member States seeking to apply well-functioning taxes. One such example
is the application of the EU state aid rules in relation to high ambitions in the climate area and the consequent
need to be able to have cost-effective instruments, such as a CO2 tax, available as tools in the EU tool-box.
Finland was the first country to introduce a CO2 tax in 1990, closely followed by Sweden, Norway and
Denmark. Within the EU we now also find CO2 taxes in Slovenia (1997), Ireland (2010), France (2014) and in
the next year Portugal. An overall introduction of a CO2 tax in the EU was foreseen by mandatory provisions
proposed by the Commission in 2011, by way of changing the existing EU Energy Taxation Directive. However,
it has unfortunately proved impossible to agree among the Member States on these amendments and the
Commission has in the end of 2014 announced its plans to withdraw the proposal. This is a major set-back in the
EU work on establishing more cost-efficient and coordinated economic instruments in the climate and energy
area.
Promising developments in the area of carbon pricing can also be seen outside the EU, where several countries
have introduced a CO2 tax, such as Switzerland (2008), Japan (2012), Mexico (2014), Chile (2014) and the
Canadian provinces of Alberta and British Columbia (2007-2008). Also, South-Africa is in the process of
finalizing a CO2 tax with a planned date for introduction in 2016. The basic logic of taxation based on the
content of fossil carbon is prevailing for all these countries, even if national conditions are taken into account for
the more detailed design, for example derogations necessary to strike a balance between environment and
competitiveness as well as addressing distributional consequences.

Más contenido relacionado

La actualidad más candente

European Carbon Emissions Trading Scheme
European Carbon Emissions Trading SchemeEuropean Carbon Emissions Trading Scheme
European Carbon Emissions Trading Schemedenise_clock
 
Introduction to the EU Emission Trading System
Introduction to the EU Emission Trading SystemIntroduction to the EU Emission Trading System
Introduction to the EU Emission Trading SystemLeonardo ENERGY
 
Press release Q3 2018
Press release Q3 2018Press release Q3 2018
Press release Q3 2018Hera Group
 
Press release Q3 2016
Press release Q3 2016Press release Q3 2016
Press release Q3 2016Hera Group
 
Vattenfall's Q2 and first half year results 2015
Vattenfall's Q2 and first half year results 2015Vattenfall's Q2 and first half year results 2015
Vattenfall's Q2 and first half year results 2015Vattenfall
 
Политика ценообразования на выбросы углерода: Конкретное изучение налога на у...
Политика ценообразования на выбросы углерода: Конкретное изучение налога на у...Политика ценообразования на выбросы углерода: Конкретное изучение налога на у...
Политика ценообразования на выбросы углерода: Конкретное изучение налога на у...ITMO University
 
Sertse presentation main sources of ghg_ethiopia
Sertse presentation main sources of ghg_ethiopiaSertse presentation main sources of ghg_ethiopia
Sertse presentation main sources of ghg_ethiopiaSertse
 
Taiwan announced INDC target voluntarily to combat climate change
Taiwan announced INDC target voluntarily to combat climate changeTaiwan announced INDC target voluntarily to combat climate change
Taiwan announced INDC target voluntarily to combat climate changeepaslideshare
 
Press release Q1 2015
Press release Q1 2015Press release Q1 2015
Press release Q1 2015Hera Group
 
Decc 4th carbon-budget-policy-statement
Decc 4th carbon-budget-policy-statementDecc 4th carbon-budget-policy-statement
Decc 4th carbon-budget-policy-statementJim Croft
 
Obama Climate Action Plan to Reduce Methane
Obama Climate Action Plan to Reduce MethaneObama Climate Action Plan to Reduce Methane
Obama Climate Action Plan to Reduce MethaneMarcellus Drilling News
 
The Role of Carbon Pricing in the Sustainable Recovery from COVID-19, Daniel ...
The Role of Carbon Pricing in the Sustainable Recovery from COVID-19, Daniel ...The Role of Carbon Pricing in the Sustainable Recovery from COVID-19, Daniel ...
The Role of Carbon Pricing in the Sustainable Recovery from COVID-19, Daniel ...OECD Environment
 
The climate change_performance_index_2018_a4
The climate change_performance_index_2018_a4The climate change_performance_index_2018_a4
The climate change_performance_index_2018_a4Eddy Effendi
 
Press release Q3 2017
Press release Q3 2017Press release Q3 2017
Press release Q3 2017Hera Group
 
CCXG Forum, March 2022, Tomas Bredariol
CCXG Forum, March 2022, Tomas BredariolCCXG Forum, March 2022, Tomas Bredariol
CCXG Forum, March 2022, Tomas BredariolOECD Environment
 
Press release 1Q 2017
Press release 1Q 2017Press release 1Q 2017
Press release 1Q 2017Hera Group
 
CPLC Use of Revenues Executive Briefing--9-16
CPLC Use of Revenues Executive Briefing--9-16CPLC Use of Revenues Executive Briefing--9-16
CPLC Use of Revenues Executive Briefing--9-16andreweil
 

La actualidad más candente (18)

European Carbon Emissions Trading Scheme
European Carbon Emissions Trading SchemeEuropean Carbon Emissions Trading Scheme
European Carbon Emissions Trading Scheme
 
Introduction to the EU Emission Trading System
Introduction to the EU Emission Trading SystemIntroduction to the EU Emission Trading System
Introduction to the EU Emission Trading System
 
Press release Q3 2018
Press release Q3 2018Press release Q3 2018
Press release Q3 2018
 
Press release Q3 2016
Press release Q3 2016Press release Q3 2016
Press release Q3 2016
 
Vattenfall's Q2 and first half year results 2015
Vattenfall's Q2 and first half year results 2015Vattenfall's Q2 and first half year results 2015
Vattenfall's Q2 and first half year results 2015
 
Политика ценообразования на выбросы углерода: Конкретное изучение налога на у...
Политика ценообразования на выбросы углерода: Конкретное изучение налога на у...Политика ценообразования на выбросы углерода: Конкретное изучение налога на у...
Политика ценообразования на выбросы углерода: Конкретное изучение налога на у...
 
Sertse presentation main sources of ghg_ethiopia
Sertse presentation main sources of ghg_ethiopiaSertse presentation main sources of ghg_ethiopia
Sertse presentation main sources of ghg_ethiopia
 
Taiwan announced INDC target voluntarily to combat climate change
Taiwan announced INDC target voluntarily to combat climate changeTaiwan announced INDC target voluntarily to combat climate change
Taiwan announced INDC target voluntarily to combat climate change
 
Press release Q1 2015
Press release Q1 2015Press release Q1 2015
Press release Q1 2015
 
Decc 4th carbon-budget-policy-statement
Decc 4th carbon-budget-policy-statementDecc 4th carbon-budget-policy-statement
Decc 4th carbon-budget-policy-statement
 
41 44
41 4441 44
41 44
 
Obama Climate Action Plan to Reduce Methane
Obama Climate Action Plan to Reduce MethaneObama Climate Action Plan to Reduce Methane
Obama Climate Action Plan to Reduce Methane
 
The Role of Carbon Pricing in the Sustainable Recovery from COVID-19, Daniel ...
The Role of Carbon Pricing in the Sustainable Recovery from COVID-19, Daniel ...The Role of Carbon Pricing in the Sustainable Recovery from COVID-19, Daniel ...
The Role of Carbon Pricing in the Sustainable Recovery from COVID-19, Daniel ...
 
The climate change_performance_index_2018_a4
The climate change_performance_index_2018_a4The climate change_performance_index_2018_a4
The climate change_performance_index_2018_a4
 
Press release Q3 2017
Press release Q3 2017Press release Q3 2017
Press release Q3 2017
 
CCXG Forum, March 2022, Tomas Bredariol
CCXG Forum, March 2022, Tomas BredariolCCXG Forum, March 2022, Tomas Bredariol
CCXG Forum, March 2022, Tomas Bredariol
 
Press release 1Q 2017
Press release 1Q 2017Press release 1Q 2017
Press release 1Q 2017
 
CPLC Use of Revenues Executive Briefing--9-16
CPLC Use of Revenues Executive Briefing--9-16CPLC Use of Revenues Executive Briefing--9-16
CPLC Use of Revenues Executive Briefing--9-16
 

Destacado

Windows Server 2016 and intel Technology
Windows Server 2016 and intel TechnologyWindows Server 2016 and intel Technology
Windows Server 2016 and intel TechnologyKhalefa Fathy
 
GREEN FARM COFFEE HUT LAUNCH
GREEN FARM COFFEE HUT LAUNCHGREEN FARM COFFEE HUT LAUNCH
GREEN FARM COFFEE HUT LAUNCHBelinda Brown
 
Loadแนวข้อสอบ นักวิชาการคอมพิวเตอร์ กรมประมง
 Loadแนวข้อสอบ นักวิชาการคอมพิวเตอร์  กรมประมง Loadแนวข้อสอบ นักวิชาการคอมพิวเตอร์  กรมประมง
Loadแนวข้อสอบ นักวิชาการคอมพิวเตอร์ กรมประมงnawaporn khamseanwong
 
[FOSS4G Korea 2016] Smart Camera UAV를 이용한 오픈소스 기반의 자동촬영 및 UAV Image 처리시스템 개발
[FOSS4G Korea 2016]  Smart Camera UAV를 이용한 오픈소스 기반의 자동촬영 및 UAV Image 처리시스템 개발[FOSS4G Korea 2016]  Smart Camera UAV를 이용한 오픈소스 기반의 자동촬영 및 UAV Image 처리시스템 개발
[FOSS4G Korea 2016] Smart Camera UAV를 이용한 오픈소스 기반의 자동촬영 및 UAV Image 처리시스템 개발Jinwoo Park
 
An Ambitious Wikidata Tutorial
An Ambitious Wikidata TutorialAn Ambitious Wikidata Tutorial
An Ambitious Wikidata Tutorial_Emw
 
Swaggerのさわりだけ
SwaggerのさわりだけSwaggerのさわりだけ
SwaggerのさわりだけMasakazu Muraoka
 
Mapa de Conversaciones en las Redes Sociales - Solvis
Mapa de Conversaciones en las Redes Sociales - SolvisMapa de Conversaciones en las Redes Sociales - Solvis
Mapa de Conversaciones en las Redes Sociales - SolvisSolvis Consulting, LLC
 
react-jsonschema-formについて
react-jsonschema-formについてreact-jsonschema-formについて
react-jsonschema-formについてMasakazu Muraoka
 

Destacado (12)

Windows Server 2016 and intel Technology
Windows Server 2016 and intel TechnologyWindows Server 2016 and intel Technology
Windows Server 2016 and intel Technology
 
GREEN FARM COFFEE HUT LAUNCH
GREEN FARM COFFEE HUT LAUNCHGREEN FARM COFFEE HUT LAUNCH
GREEN FARM COFFEE HUT LAUNCH
 
Loadแนวข้อสอบ นักวิชาการคอมพิวเตอร์ กรมประมง
 Loadแนวข้อสอบ นักวิชาการคอมพิวเตอร์  กรมประมง Loadแนวข้อสอบ นักวิชาการคอมพิวเตอร์  กรมประมง
Loadแนวข้อสอบ นักวิชาการคอมพิวเตอร์ กรมประมง
 
Mobile Wallets: Are We There Yet?
Mobile Wallets: Are We There Yet?Mobile Wallets: Are We There Yet?
Mobile Wallets: Are We There Yet?
 
[FOSS4G Korea 2016] Smart Camera UAV를 이용한 오픈소스 기반의 자동촬영 및 UAV Image 처리시스템 개발
[FOSS4G Korea 2016]  Smart Camera UAV를 이용한 오픈소스 기반의 자동촬영 및 UAV Image 처리시스템 개발[FOSS4G Korea 2016]  Smart Camera UAV를 이용한 오픈소스 기반의 자동촬영 및 UAV Image 처리시스템 개발
[FOSS4G Korea 2016] Smart Camera UAV를 이용한 오픈소스 기반의 자동촬영 및 UAV Image 처리시스템 개발
 
An Ambitious Wikidata Tutorial
An Ambitious Wikidata TutorialAn Ambitious Wikidata Tutorial
An Ambitious Wikidata Tutorial
 
Manosevitch
ManosevitchManosevitch
Manosevitch
 
Swaggerのさわりだけ
SwaggerのさわりだけSwaggerのさわりだけ
Swaggerのさわりだけ
 
Ayu widiyan(os)
Ayu widiyan(os)Ayu widiyan(os)
Ayu widiyan(os)
 
Mapa de Conversaciones en las Redes Sociales - Solvis
Mapa de Conversaciones en las Redes Sociales - SolvisMapa de Conversaciones en las Redes Sociales - Solvis
Mapa de Conversaciones en las Redes Sociales - Solvis
 
react-jsonschema-formについて
react-jsonschema-formについてreact-jsonschema-formについて
react-jsonschema-formについて
 
Digital in 2017: Eastern Asia
Digital in 2017: Eastern AsiaDigital in 2017: Eastern Asia
Digital in 2017: Eastern Asia
 

Similar a 161121 Akerfeldt and Hammar CO2 tax Article

Europe carbon-emissions-trading
Europe carbon-emissions-tradingEurope carbon-emissions-trading
Europe carbon-emissions-tradingKevin A
 
CCXG Forum, September 2020, Mattias Frumerie
CCXG Forum, September 2020, Mattias FrumerieCCXG Forum, September 2020, Mattias Frumerie
CCXG Forum, September 2020, Mattias FrumerieOECD Environment
 
Evaluating Carbon Policies
Evaluating Carbon PoliciesEvaluating Carbon Policies
Evaluating Carbon Policiestutor2u
 
4-Herwig-Immervoll-OECD.pdf
4-Herwig-Immervoll-OECD.pdf4-Herwig-Immervoll-OECD.pdf
4-Herwig-Immervoll-OECD.pdfOECD Governance
 
ORSI Policybrief - Moving Towards Climate Budgeting in Cities
ORSI Policybrief - Moving Towards Climate Budgeting in CitiesORSI Policybrief - Moving Towards Climate Budgeting in Cities
ORSI Policybrief - Moving Towards Climate Budgeting in CitiesORSI
 
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019OECD Environment
 
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_Reduction
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_ReductionAustralian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_Reduction
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_ReductionJames Slezak
 
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28Barbara Albert
 
Making fundamental tax reform happen_Brys
Making fundamental tax reform happen_BrysMaking fundamental tax reform happen_Brys
Making fundamental tax reform happen_BrysBert Brys
 
European Green Deal: Commission proposes transformation of EU economy and soc...
European Green Deal: Commission proposes transformation of EU economy and soc...European Green Deal: Commission proposes transformation of EU economy and soc...
European Green Deal: Commission proposes transformation of EU economy and soc...Voula Zisopoulou
 
The Taxshift Case Study Luxembourg Ex'tax [DEF][74].pdf
The Taxshift Case Study Luxembourg Ex'tax [DEF][74].pdfThe Taxshift Case Study Luxembourg Ex'tax [DEF][74].pdf
The Taxshift Case Study Luxembourg Ex'tax [DEF][74].pdfPaperjam_redaction
 
The Possibilities of Carbon Tax Implementation in indonesia
The Possibilities of Carbon Tax Implementation in indonesiaThe Possibilities of Carbon Tax Implementation in indonesia
The Possibilities of Carbon Tax Implementation in indonesiaDicky Edwin Hindarto
 
Stephan Skare Enevoldsen, Danish Energy Agency - Lessons from Denmark: Govern...
Stephan Skare Enevoldsen, Danish Energy Agency - Lessons from Denmark: Govern...Stephan Skare Enevoldsen, Danish Energy Agency - Lessons from Denmark: Govern...
Stephan Skare Enevoldsen, Danish Energy Agency - Lessons from Denmark: Govern...OECD Environment
 
The Implementation of Carbon Tax for Coal-Fired Steam Power Plant.pdf
The Implementation of Carbon Tax for Coal-Fired Steam Power Plant.pdfThe Implementation of Carbon Tax for Coal-Fired Steam Power Plant.pdf
The Implementation of Carbon Tax for Coal-Fired Steam Power Plant.pdfAHRP Law Firm
 
CCXG Global Forum October 2018 Breakout Group C by Helene Plume
CCXG Global Forum October 2018 Breakout Group C by Helene PlumeCCXG Global Forum October 2018 Breakout Group C by Helene Plume
CCXG Global Forum October 2018 Breakout Group C by Helene PlumeOECD Environment
 
Infrastructure Investment & the Low-carbon Transition
Infrastructure Investment & the Low-carbon Transition Infrastructure Investment & the Low-carbon Transition
Infrastructure Investment & the Low-carbon Transition OECD Environment
 
150612 Paris OECD Final version
150612 Paris OECD Final version150612 Paris OECD Final version
150612 Paris OECD Final versionSusanne
 

Similar a 161121 Akerfeldt and Hammar CO2 tax Article (20)

Europe carbon-emissions-trading
Europe carbon-emissions-tradingEurope carbon-emissions-trading
Europe carbon-emissions-trading
 
CCXG Forum, September 2020, Mattias Frumerie
CCXG Forum, September 2020, Mattias FrumerieCCXG Forum, September 2020, Mattias Frumerie
CCXG Forum, September 2020, Mattias Frumerie
 
Carbontax
CarbontaxCarbontax
Carbontax
 
Evaluating Carbon Policies
Evaluating Carbon PoliciesEvaluating Carbon Policies
Evaluating Carbon Policies
 
4-Herwig-Immervoll-OECD.pdf
4-Herwig-Immervoll-OECD.pdf4-Herwig-Immervoll-OECD.pdf
4-Herwig-Immervoll-OECD.pdf
 
ORSI Policybrief - Moving Towards Climate Budgeting in Cities
ORSI Policybrief - Moving Towards Climate Budgeting in CitiesORSI Policybrief - Moving Towards Climate Budgeting in Cities
ORSI Policybrief - Moving Towards Climate Budgeting in Cities
 
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019
 
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_Reduction
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_ReductionAustralian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_Reduction
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_Reduction
 
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28
 
Making fundamental tax reform happen_Brys
Making fundamental tax reform happen_BrysMaking fundamental tax reform happen_Brys
Making fundamental tax reform happen_Brys
 
European Green Deal: Commission proposes transformation of EU economy and soc...
European Green Deal: Commission proposes transformation of EU economy and soc...European Green Deal: Commission proposes transformation of EU economy and soc...
European Green Deal: Commission proposes transformation of EU economy and soc...
 
The Taxshift Case Study Luxembourg Ex'tax [DEF][74].pdf
The Taxshift Case Study Luxembourg Ex'tax [DEF][74].pdfThe Taxshift Case Study Luxembourg Ex'tax [DEF][74].pdf
The Taxshift Case Study Luxembourg Ex'tax [DEF][74].pdf
 
The Possibilities of Carbon Tax Implementation in indonesia
The Possibilities of Carbon Tax Implementation in indonesiaThe Possibilities of Carbon Tax Implementation in indonesia
The Possibilities of Carbon Tax Implementation in indonesia
 
Stephan Skare Enevoldsen, Danish Energy Agency - Lessons from Denmark: Govern...
Stephan Skare Enevoldsen, Danish Energy Agency - Lessons from Denmark: Govern...Stephan Skare Enevoldsen, Danish Energy Agency - Lessons from Denmark: Govern...
Stephan Skare Enevoldsen, Danish Energy Agency - Lessons from Denmark: Govern...
 
Presentation1
Presentation1Presentation1
Presentation1
 
Economics and Environmental Implications of Carbon Taxation in Malaysia.doc
Economics and Environmental Implications of Carbon Taxation in Malaysia.docEconomics and Environmental Implications of Carbon Taxation in Malaysia.doc
Economics and Environmental Implications of Carbon Taxation in Malaysia.doc
 
The Implementation of Carbon Tax for Coal-Fired Steam Power Plant.pdf
The Implementation of Carbon Tax for Coal-Fired Steam Power Plant.pdfThe Implementation of Carbon Tax for Coal-Fired Steam Power Plant.pdf
The Implementation of Carbon Tax for Coal-Fired Steam Power Plant.pdf
 
CCXG Global Forum October 2018 Breakout Group C by Helene Plume
CCXG Global Forum October 2018 Breakout Group C by Helene PlumeCCXG Global Forum October 2018 Breakout Group C by Helene Plume
CCXG Global Forum October 2018 Breakout Group C by Helene Plume
 
Infrastructure Investment & the Low-carbon Transition
Infrastructure Investment & the Low-carbon Transition Infrastructure Investment & the Low-carbon Transition
Infrastructure Investment & the Low-carbon Transition
 
150612 Paris OECD Final version
150612 Paris OECD Final version150612 Paris OECD Final version
150612 Paris OECD Final version
 

161121 Akerfeldt and Hammar CO2 tax Article

  • 1. CO2 Taxation in Sweden Experiences of the Past and Future Challenges by Susanne Åkerfeldt and Henrik Hammar*) *) The views expressed in the paper do not necessarily reflect those of the Swedish Ministry of Finance. English language version of article published in French in the October 2015 issue of the journal Revue Projet as well as on their web site (http://www.revue-projet.com/articles/2015-09-akerfeldt-hammar-la-taxe-carbone-en- suede/). @ Revue Projet journal Contact info for corresponding with authors: E-mail: susanne.akerfeldt@gov.se Phone: +46 8 405 1382 Susanne Åkerfeldt, Senior Adviser, Swedish Ministry of Finance, Tax and Customs Department Susanne Åkerfeldt has a Master’s Degree in Law from Uppsala University, Sweden and is an Associate Judge of Appeal. She’s a ministerial adviser and international negotiator with more than 20 years of experience related to policy design of cost-efficient environmental taxation, its interaction with other policy measures nationally and globally on the road towards developing a sustainable, low-carbon and resource-efficient society. She has been instrumental in the development of the Swedish CO2 tax over the years and has a long and broad experience of negotiating energy taxation matters within the EU. Henrik Hammar Senior Adviser, Swedish Ministry of Finance, Tax and Customs Department Henrik Hammar completed in 2001 his PhD in economics at Gothenburg University, Sweden, concentrating on energy and environmental issues and economic instruments in particular. Between 2001 and 2005 he was secretary in two Swedish Governmental Committees in the area and did academic policy oriented research. Between 2005 and 2008 he has worked at the Swedish National Institute of Economic Research, doing qualified economic analyses in environmental economics, before joining the Ministry of Finance in 2008.
  • 2. 1. Sweden has been a pioneer regarding CO2 taxation. Can you remind how it concretely works? Two different taxes on fuels form the base of the Swedish energy taxation system. An energy tax has been levied on petrol and diesel since around 1930 and fossil heating fuels started to be taxed during the 1950’s. The CO2 tax was in 1991 introduced on fossil fuels at rates equivalent to 27 €1 per tonne fossil CO2. At the same time the energy tax rates were reduced by 50 per cent, which still meant an increase for all fuels. Average CO2 emission and energy factors are used to calculate the tax rates. No measuring of actual emissions is necessary. In order to ensure a simple administration, the CO2 tax rates are in the tax law expressed in weight or volume units for the different fuels. The CO2 tax is collected in the same way as the energy tax, which gives low administrative costs for the tax authorities as well as for the operators. The CO2 tax, obviously, should aim at helping society to reach set climate targets. That is why it is logical to base it on the content of fossil carbon, as only fossil fuel consumption results in net increases of CO2 to the atmosphere. To also apply it to biofuels would constitute illogic taxation in relation to the aim of the tax and would also, hence, make the tax less general and thereby less cost effective. The rationale behind using a market based policy instrument such as a CO2 tax is that the price signal created by the tax allows for numerous ways to avoid the tax. The cost effectiveness lies, hence, in that the society does not ‘pick a winner’ (e.g. a particular technology or a particular fuel) but rather allows households and firms to choose the measures that are best (which typically coincide with least cost) for them. Such measures can range from putting on an additional sweater to invest in a new technology with low or zero greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. The CO2 tax rates have over the years been significantly increased, with the purpose of achieving cost effective emission reductions by way of applying the Polluter Pays Principle. The tax changes have been implemented stepwise to give households and firms time to adapt. The same CO2 tax rate is applied for motor fuels and heating fuels, ensuring the same price signal and thus cost effective emission reductions by equalizing marginal costs for abatement. 2. In France ecological taxes are the subject of regular changes. The continuity of the Swedish CO2 tax system is very impressive: can you explain how the political consensus has been built behind it, why in 1991, and which kind of contest it has faced ever since? The introduction of CO2 taxation in Sweden was part of a major tax reform that among other things implied dramatically lower marginal income taxes on capital and labour, the elimination of various tax shelters and base broadening of the value added tax. The political opportunity to introduce the CO2 tax consisted of the confluence of two separate political processes. On the one hand, there was a demand for a drastic reduction in marginal income tax rates which had reached very high levels. At the same time there was an increasing interest in environmental issues politically and throughout the society. 1 Exchange rate used in this article: 1 € = 9,0932 SEK.
  • 3. There is a broad political consensus of the basic CO2 tax structure and the use of the tax as the primary instrument to achieve GHG reductions. Sweden has had left-wing and right-wing governments, but this has not meant any major deviations from the chosen road forward. Business and other stakeholders are involved in the decision making process by the constitutional system of sending out Government proposals for general public consultation before presenting them to Parliament. The aim has been to implement tax raises and major changes of the tax structure in a step by step approach, preferably being announced well in advance giving households and firms time to adjust. The general CO2 tax rate chosen when the tax was introduced in 1991 was reasonably low and it has taken us more than 20 years to reach the – what some may call exceptionally high – level of 123 € per tonne fossil carbon. Typically, CO2 tax increases for households and firms have been combined with general tax relief in other areas in order to avoid increases in the overall level of taxation, address undesirable distributional consequences and stimulate job growth. Such combination of measures creates a balance between different policy considerations. Also, one aspect of a general welfare state is that it alleviates severe distributional consequences. Preserving the environment is an issue given high priority not only by the Government but also by most citizens. So while Swedes probably do not like to pay taxes any more than other people, there is a basic understanding and acceptance of the underlying rationale to introduce economic instruments, such as the CO2 tax, to help reach climate targets. It has also been essential over the years to ensure that the households and firms have feasible options available to help in their transition to a low-carbon economy. While not earmarking CO2 tax revenues for specific purposes, significant parts of the national budget have still over the years been allocated to various projects, such as better public transport, an increased use of bio-fuelled district heating and housing isolation. 3. Has CO2 taxation in Sweden been detrimental to competitiveness and employment and how did you tackle those issues? The Swedish experience shows that it is possible to combine reduced emissions with economic growth. A decoupling of the economic growth and reduced emissions could be seen already in 1996 and this development has continued ever since. During the 1990-2013 period GDP increased by +61 percent, while at the same time CO2 equivalent emissions was reduced by 23 percent2 . An essential aspect has been to strike a balance between fulfilling environmental objectives and accounting for the risks of carbon leakage (which in turn is related to securing the competitiveness of sectors that are subject to international competition). Industry has ever since the introduction of the CO2 tax faced a lower tax level on heating fuels than the household and service sectors. When introducing the CO2 tax at the general level of 27 € in 1991, the lower level for industry applied corresponded to 7 €. When the general level of the CO2 tax was raised during following years, adjustments were also made of the lower level based on competiveness assessments and other factors. 2 80 per cent of the CO2 e emissions consists of CO2 emissions.
  • 4. Since it is essential to avoid disruptive effects on competitiveness, such a lower tax level has been a prerequisite for a high tax level for other sectors and has been instrumental in achieving major emission reductions in the household, transport and service sectors. This two-level system has in the past been the most important element in the design of a well-functioning system to curb CO2 emissions in Sweden. 4. What have been the major changes in the Swedish CO2 tax system since its creation? Especially, how did you integrate the European regulatory changes? Sweden became a member of the EU in 1995 and adapted our existing legislation to the relevant Community law. The general CO2 tax design was maintained, as it was in line with relevant EU rules. As mentioned earlier, a general, lower CO2 tax level was chosen for the industrial sector, when introducing the CO2 tax. It has been an administratively simple approach to allow for significant increases of the levels of CO2 taxation for other sectors. However, the development of Community law meanwhile resulted in the introduction of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS), a Community wide economic instrument covering GHG emissions from the major part of energy intensive industrial installations. In order to apply only one general economic instrument as an incentive to reduce GHG emissions, no CO2 tax is from 2011 applied in Sweden on fuels used by industrial installations within the EU ETS. On the other hand, industry outside the EU ETS is in general less energy intensive and, hence, has relatively low costs for energy. This implies that an increased CO2 tax for industry outside EU ETS do not cause major disrupting effects on competitiveness. Further, many firms have relatively good opportunities to switch to non- fossil heating sources, which is why an increased CO2 tax serve as an incentive to substitute to non-fossil energy. In a step-wise approach, Sweden has thus increased the lower level for this sector during 2011-2015 (from 21 to 30 per cent of the general CO2 tax level in 2011 and from 30 to 60 per cent in 2015). The Government has announced its intention to abolish the lower CO2 tax by 1 January 2016. However, it should be noted that a structural shift from fossil fuels in industry can imply severe effects for individual firms, which also can cause unwanted consequences on local/regional level. This risk is another reason for, if possible, applying a step-by- step approach in order to give firms time to adapt and thereby alleviate some of these problems.] The CO2 tax is levied on the content of fossil carbon in fuels, which meant that biofuels were not subject to the CO2 tax from the start. Upon implementing the 2009 EU Renewables Directive, sustainability criteria for biofuels and bioliquids were introduced as a condition for not subjecting such biofuels to the non-CO2 taxation. According to EU law, aid can only be granted to sustainable biofuels and bioliquids. The EU Commission has this far considered the Swedish CO2 tax design as a state aid to biofuels. 5. The energy mix in Sweden has shifted from fossil fuels towards biofuels in particular. What kind of biofuels? Does the overall balance of Swedish CO2 emissions integrate "imported emissions" (incl. possible deforestation in Amazonia linked with the development of soy, etc.)? Over the last decades fossil heating fuels has to a large extent been phased out as a source for heating private homes and apartment buildings. Recent figures show that 92 per cent of all apartments are heated by district
  • 5. heating, primarily fuelled by household waste and various wood residues. The district heating grids are continuously expanded to cover also small towns. However, Sweden is sparsely populated and single-family homes in more remote areas are not connected to district heating grids. The phasing out of fossil fuels has in those cases meant a transition to wood heat pumps, electricity3 and wood pellets burners. District heating is also an instrumental source of space heating for the service sector – the figure is 80 per cent. As for industry the last decades have seen a steady decline in specific energy use; that is amount of energy used per monetary unit of value added. Technical innovation in Swedish industry has for a long time favoured electricity solutions, due to the fact that hydro-electricity has been available at reasonably low prices and that electricity used by industry is taxed with a considerably lower out-put energy tax than electricity used by households and service sector firms. The energy used by Swedish industry comes primarily from biofuels (40 percent) and electricity (36 percent). Wood scrap products and liquid residues from the paper and pulp industry account for the bulk part of the biofuels. The balance of Swedish CO2 emissions is calculated and reported according to procedures that the global community has agreed upon under the Kyoto Protocol. The annual reporting is based on emissions occurring from the combustion of fuels within Sweden and at the same time combustion from fuels elsewhere in the world is accounted for in the annual reports from those countries. Calculations have been made by the Swedish Environmental Protection Agency of the impact on CO2 emissions from the consumption of Swedish individuals taking place abroad, either by visits to those countries or by importing products manufactured in other countries. However, it does not seem feasible in the foreseeable future to take account of such emissions when calculating a CO2 tax in Sweden that is administratively simple to design and collect. 6. What are the next challenges ahead? Is there any risk that the CO2 tax system be given up? Have other countries been convinced or interested enough by the Swedish experience to replicate it? If not, what kind of factors have prevented them to do so? The major challenge ahead lies in the area of motor fuels. The steadily increased CO2 tax on fossil motor fuels has played a major role also for an increased use of biofuels in the transport sector. Currently about 11 per cent of all propellants used in Sweden are biofuels. But major efforts are still needed in order for Sweden to be able to reach the political vision of a fossil-free vehicle fleet by 2030 and no net increase on greenhouse gas emissions by 2050. The CO2 tax has served us well in Sweden as a powerful tool to help reach reductions in GHG emissions during the past decades. Also for the future the Swedish Government sees the CO2 tax as the major economic instrument to achieve emission reductions in sectors outside the EU ETS. The 2014 agreement in the European Council calls for at least a 40 per cent reduction of GHG emissions by 2030. Member States will be obliged to cut emissions substantially outside the EU ETS. To this end, the Member States need cost effective tools. A CO2 3 Sweden’s electricity production is to a large extent fossil free (figures for 2012: hydro 48 per cent, nuclear 38 per cent, combined heat and power, with basically biomass in-put 10 per cent, wind power 4 per cent; Swedish Energy Agency, Energy in Sweden 2014).
  • 6. tax is a key instrument to help reduce the use of fossil fuels and reach set climate targets. An inherent challenge for the whole of the EU lies in the need to ensure that all parts of the Community legislation are consistently applied and not creating obstacles for Member States seeking to apply well-functioning taxes. One such example is the application of the EU state aid rules in relation to high ambitions in the climate area and the consequent need to be able to have cost-effective instruments, such as a CO2 tax, available as tools in the EU tool-box. Finland was the first country to introduce a CO2 tax in 1990, closely followed by Sweden, Norway and Denmark. Within the EU we now also find CO2 taxes in Slovenia (1997), Ireland (2010), France (2014) and in the next year Portugal. An overall introduction of a CO2 tax in the EU was foreseen by mandatory provisions proposed by the Commission in 2011, by way of changing the existing EU Energy Taxation Directive. However, it has unfortunately proved impossible to agree among the Member States on these amendments and the Commission has in the end of 2014 announced its plans to withdraw the proposal. This is a major set-back in the EU work on establishing more cost-efficient and coordinated economic instruments in the climate and energy area. Promising developments in the area of carbon pricing can also be seen outside the EU, where several countries have introduced a CO2 tax, such as Switzerland (2008), Japan (2012), Mexico (2014), Chile (2014) and the Canadian provinces of Alberta and British Columbia (2007-2008). Also, South-Africa is in the process of finalizing a CO2 tax with a planned date for introduction in 2016. The basic logic of taxation based on the content of fossil carbon is prevailing for all these countries, even if national conditions are taken into account for the more detailed design, for example derogations necessary to strike a balance between environment and competitiveness as well as addressing distributional consequences.