SlideShare una empresa de Scribd logo
1 de 45
Descargar para leer sin conexión
ACCOUNTING FOR GROWTH: THE ROLE OF PHYSICAL WORK



Robert U. Ayres and Benjamin Warr*




ABSTRACT



       We test several related hypothesis for explaining US economic growth since 1900.

Introducing physical work, instead of energy, as a factor of production the historical growth

path is reproduced with high accuracy from 1900 until the mid 1970's. In effect, the Solow

residual is explained as increasing energy-conversion (to work) efficiency. The remaining

unexplained residual amounts to only about 12 percent of total growth since that time.

Information technology may be responsible for the unexplained growth.



Keywords: Economic growth; Exergy; Productivity; Resources; Solow Residual; Work



(JEL O39; alternate JEL O47)




       In the 1950's, it was discovered that the growth in capital stock could only account for

a small fraction (about one eighth) of the historical US growth in economic output per worker

(Moses Abramovitz 1952, 1956; Solomon Fabricant 1954). Economic growth theory was

subsequently formulated in its current production function form by Robert Solow and Trevor

Swan (Robert M. Solow 1956, 1957; Trevor Swan 1956). The theory assumes that production
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                                Page 2




of goods and services (in monetary terms) can be expressed as a function of capital and labor.

But the major contribution to growth had to be attributed to something else, namely

“technological progress”or just “technical progress”. Absent any fundamental economic

theory of technical progress, or any convincing independent measure of it, technical progress

has been treated as an unexplained residual. This is another way of saying that it is an

exogenous multiplier, either of labor or capital or both equally (i.e. of the whole production

function, usually taken to be Cobb-Douglas or CES in form).

         As it happens, however, the Solow model makes two fundamental predictions that do

not correspond to historical experience over the last half century. One prediction is that the

rate of growth of an economy will decline as the capital stock grows, due to declining

marginal productivity of capital (and the need to replace depreciation). The other prediction

(known as “convergence”) is that poor countries, with smaller capital stocks, will grow faster

than rich countries. The most popular “fix” is to dispense with the notion that capital

depreciates. Another way of putting it is to assume that decreasing marginal productivity of

capital is compensated by another effect, namely increasing returns to knowledge, arising

from positive externalities (“spillovers”). This notion, first incorporated in the standard

theoretical framework by Romer (Paul M. Romer 1986), has prompted an explosion of so-

called “endogenous growth” theories (e.g. Romer 1986, 1987, 1990; Robert E. Lucas, Jr.

1988; Gene M. Grossman and Elhanen Helpman 1991; Philippe Aghion and Peter Howitt

1998). There is a lot of interest among theorists, at present, in the phenomenon of increasing

returns to scale (as exemplified by network systems of all kinds).

         Most of the recent endogenous growth theories are so-called A-K models, where K is

generalized capital, defined to include knowledge and skills. The Solow multiplier A in these

models is supposed to be a constant, independent of time. Labor no longer appears explicitly
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                                 Page 3




as a factor.1 It is interesting to note that Solow’s argument for choosing capital and labor

productivities in the Cobb-Douglas production function (on the basis of shares in the national

income accounts) no longer applies to the A-K theories. The major difficulty with the “new”

endogenous growth theories is that there is no independent empirical basis for determining

what the generalized capital K should be.

         In this paper we reconsider the possible role of resource inputs as factors of

production, and whether this approach offers a possible alternative to the AK theories

mentioned above.



I. THE ROLE OF NATURAL RESOURCES



         The possible contribution of natural resource inputs to growth (or to technical

progress), was not considered seriously by most economists until the 1970's (mainly in

response to the Club of Rome and “Limits to Growth” (Donella H. Meadows et al 1972)).

The primary focus of the early economic responses to “Limits” was on the problem of

resource exhaustion (e.g. Partha Dasgupta and Geoffrey Heal 1974; Solow 1974; Joseph

Stiglitz 1974). Despite the very small share of national income that could reasonably be

attributed to resources, some economists, notably Jorgenson and his colleagues, introduced

transcendental logarithmic production functions and multi-sector (KLEMS) models with

capital, labor, energy and materials as factors (Dale W. Jorgenson et al 1973). Jorgenson

subsequently tried to calculate factor productivities empirically in a large multi-sector model

(Jorgenson 1984). The results were not sufficiently unambiguous to prompt many imitators.

In most more recent large model applications resource consumption has been implicitly

treated as a consequence of growth and not as a factor of production. This simplistic. and
Ayres and Warr                            Accounting for growth                               Page 4




questionable assumption is built into most of the large-scale models used for policy guidance

by governments.

         An important “engine of growth” since the first industrial revolution has been the

continuously declining real price of physical resources, especially energy (and power)

delivered at a point of use.2 The increasing availability of energy from fossil fuels, and power

from heat engines, has clearly played a fundamental role in growth. Machines powered by

fossil energy have gradually displaced animals, wind power, water power and human muscles

and thus made human workers vastly more productive than they would otherwise have been.

The term energy as used above, and in most discussions (including the economics literature)

is technically incorrect, since energy is conserved and therefore cannot be “used up”. The

correct term in this context is exergy3, which is sometimes called “available energy” or

“useful energy”.We use this term hereafter because of its generality.

         The generic exergy-power feedback cycle works as follows. Technological progress

such as discoveries, inventions, economies of scale, and accumulated experience – or

learning-by-doing – result in cheaper exergy and power at the point of use. Moreover,

inventions (such as the steam engine) enable the substitution of machines for human or

animal muscles, thus delivering more power at lower cost. This, in turn, enables tangible

goods and intangible services to be produced and delivered to consumers at ever lower prices.

Factories and mines also benefit from these price reductions.

         Lower consumer prices encourage higher demand, thanks to price elasticity of

demand. Since demand for final goods and services (including investment) necessarily

corresponds to the sum of factor payments, most of which go back to labor as wages and

salaries, it follows that wages of labor tend to increase as output rises.4 This, in turn,

stimulates the further substitution of fossil exergy and mechanical lower for human (and
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                                  Page 5




animal) labor, resulting in further increases in scale, etc. and still lower costs. In modern

times the use of electric power has been particularly productive, not least because it has

stimulated the development of so many new industries.

         Based on both qualitative and quantitative evidence, the existence of the positive

feedback cycle sketched above implies that physical resource (exergy) flows are a major

factor of production. This observation has tempted many economists to try to quantify the

relationship. Indeed, including a fossil exergy flow proxy in a 3 (or 4) factor Cobb-Douglas or

similar production function has apparently successfully accounted for economic growth quite

accurately, at least for limited time periods, without any exogenous time-dependent term.

Examples of such studies include (Bruce M. Hannon and John Joyce 1981; Reiner Kümmel

1982; Cutler Cleveland et al 1984; Kümmel et al 1985; Cleveland 1992; Robert K.

Kaufmann 1992; Bernard C. Beaudreau 1998; Cleveland et al 2000; Kümmel et al 2000).

         However, even a high degree of correlation (exhibited by some of these studies) does

not necessarily imply causation. In other words, the fact that economic growth tends to be

very closely correlated with energy or exergy consumption for some period of time – a fact

demonstrated in numerous studies – does not a priori mean that energy (or exergy)

consumption is the cause of the growth. Indeed, most economic models assume the opposite:

that economic growth is responsible for increasing energy consumption. This automatically

guarantees correlation. It is also conceivable that both consumption and growth are

simultaneously caused by some third factor. The direction of causality must evidently be

determined empirically by other means.5

         A deeper question is: why should capital services be treated as a “factor of

production” while the role of energy (exergy) services – not to mention other environmental

services – is neglected or minimized? The naive view would seem to be that the two factors
Ayres and Warr                            Accounting for growth                                Page 6




should be treated much the same way. Yet, among many theorists, strong doubts remain. It

appears that there are two reasons. The first and most important is that national accounts are

set up to reflect payments to labor (wages, salaries) and capital owners (rents, royalties,

interest, dividends). In fact, GNP is the sum of all such payments and NNP is the sum of all

such payments to individuals. There is no category for payments to resources.

         If labor and capital are the only two factors, neoclassical theory implies that the

productivity of a factor of production must be proportional to the share of that factor in the

national income. This proposition is quite easy to prove in a hypothetical single sector

economy consisting of a large number of producers manufacturing a single good using only

labor and capital services (as taught in elementary economics texts.) Moreover, the supposed

link between factor payments and factor productivities gives the national accounts a

fundamental role in production theory. This is intuitively very attractive. Labor gets the lion’s

share of payments in the US national accounts, around 70 percent. Capital (defined as

interest, dividends, rents and royalties) gets all of the rest. The figures vary slightly from year

to year, but they have been relatively stable for the past century or more. Land rents are

negligible. Payments for fossil fuels (even in “finished” form, including electric power)

altogether amount to only a few percent of the total GDP.

          It follows, according to the received theory, that energy (exergy) is not a significant

factor of production, or that it can be subsumed in capital, and can be safely ignored.

However, there is a flaw in this argument. Suppose there exists an unpaid factor, e.g.

environmental services. Since there are few economic agents (persons or firms) who receive

income in exchange for providing or protecting environmental services, there are no explicit

payments for such services in the national accounts. Absent such payments, it would seem to

follow from the logic of the preceding two paragraphs that environmental services are not
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                                Page 7




scarce or not economically productive. This implication pervades neoclassical economic

theory. But it seems quite unreasonable to argue that environmental services are

unproductive, given their central role in agriculture and forestry not to mention providing the

welfare benefits of equable climate, fresh water, clean air, waste disposal and so forth. True,

there are no markets for these services, but that is primarily due to indivisibility and lack of

property rights. Free goods can still be scarce

         Just as environmental assets and services may be underpriced, so may exergy and

exergy services. Many environmental economists note to the enormous direct and (mostly)

indirect subsidies to energy use, especially in the US. Motor vehicles are the most obvious

case-in-point. Motor vehicles create very large public costs, not only for highway

construction and maintenance, but from air pollution damage, from uninsured accidents, from

the military expenditures to protect the sea-routes from the Middle East and by the removal of

large urban land areas from other public or private uses. Many studies have been done to

quantify these costs, but the point is that if these damage costs were added to the price of

petroleum products, as theory suggests, the price of fuel would soar – and the petroleum share

of national income would soar also. There is little doubt that all fossil fuels, as well as nuclear

energy, are significantly underpriced. This suggests that the energy share of the national

accounts could be too small by a factor of two or three, or even more.

         Quite apart from the question of under-pricing, there is another reason why factor

payments directly attributable to consumption of physical resources – especially exergy – are

much smaller than the real productivity of exergy to the economy. In reality, the economy is

not a single sector producing a single good – say, bread – from capital and labor.6 On the

contrary it is a complex network of interacting sectors. Most sectors produce products (or

services) by adding value to inputs purchased directly from other sectors.
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                                 Page 8




         In the simple single sector model used to “prove” the neoclassical relationship

between factor productivity and factor payments, this crucial fact is disregarded, resulting in a

major distortion. If the economy were a one-sector model with only one product and one sort

of producer (e.g. bakers of bread), the payments to each factor input would indeed reflect the

marginal productivity of that factor. In a multi-sector economy, however most sectors buy

from others (and sell to others), whence purchased intermediates constitute a significant share

of the factors of production for each sector. Only the extractive sectors consume raw

materials (exergy) extracted directly from nature. The intermediate sectors utilize labor and

capital plus semi-finished materials and products, plus utilities (water, gas, electricity) and a

variety of services (finance, insurance, transport, etc.). The intermediates are, in effect,

“processed exergy”.

         If each sector is considered as a producer, with its own production function, its

factors of production necessarily include exergy consumed in the production of purchased

intermediate goods, including utilities and services. Allowing for the exergy transmitted via

intermediates, the simple picture derived from the 1-sector model changes completely.

Whereas, exergy extracted from nature accounts for a very small share of the national income

directly, “processed exergy” can (and does) contribute a much larger effective share of the

value of aggregate production, indirectly (Robert U. Ayres 2001).

         So much for the anomalously small share of exergy in the national accounts or

(looking at it the other way) the anomalously large share of exergy as a factor of production

and driver of growth.
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                                Page 9




II. PRODUCTION FUNCTIONS



         It is now convenient to postulate two possible relationships of the form:



(1a)      Y = fEgEE or Y = fBgBB



(1b)      Y = gEUE or Y = gBUB



where Y is GDP, measured in dollars, E is a measure of commercial energy (mainly fossil

fuels), B is a measure of all “raw” physical resource inputs (technically, exergy), including

fuels, minerals and agricultural and forest products. Then f is the ratio of “useful work” U

done by the economy as a whole to “raw” exergy input (defined below), and g is the ratio of

economic output in value terms to work input. All the variables have implicit subscripts B or

E, depending on whether or not we are considering only standard measures of energy (E) or

total exergy (B). We neglect the subscripts hereafter where the choice is obvious.

         Since work appears implicitly in both numerator and denominator of (1), its definition

depends on whether we choose B or E. (Note that equation (1 a,b) is merely a definition of

the factors f, g. There is no theory or approximation involved). However we note that the

expressions (1a) or (1b) can be interpreted as a production function in either of two cases.

The first possibility is that E or B is a factor of production and the product fE gE or fBgB can be

approximated by some first order homogeneous function of the three factors: labor L , capital

K and energy consumption E or exergy consumption B. The second possibility is that work U

is a factor of production (instead of E or B) and the function g can be expressed
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                              Page 10




approximately by some first order homogeneous function of K, L and U. (Subscripts omitted.)

We test these possibilities empirically hereafter.

         The traditional variables capital K, and labor L, as usually defined for purposes of

economic analysis, are plotted along with commerical energy (fossil fuels plus hydro and

nuclear power) in Figure 1a from 1900 to 1998; deflated GDP and a traditional Cobb-

Douglas production function of K,L,E are shown in Figure 1b. It is important to note that

GDP increases faster than any of the three contributory factors or (by extension) any first

order homogeneous function of them. The need for a time-dependent factor representing

technical progress (the Solow residual) is evident. It is plotted in the figure.

         The ratio E/GDP is the so-called Kuznets curve. It is often observed that, for many

industrialized countries, the E/GDP (or E/Y) ratio appears to have a characteristic inverted

“U-shape”, at least if E is restricted to commercial fuels. (Not to be confused with our

variable U). However, when the exergy embodied in firewood is included the supposedly

characteristic inverted U-shape is much less pronounced. When non-fuel and mineral

resources, especially agricultural phytomass are included, fuel exergy E is replaced by total

exergy B, and the inverted U form is no longer evident. Figure 2 shows the various exergy

inputs, plotted from 1900 to 1998. Figure 3 displays the three versions of the Kuznets curve.

The top curve is the classical version, namely the ratio of commercial (mostly fossil fuel)

exergy to GDP. The middle curve is the ratio of all fuels, including firewood, to GDP. The

peak is still visible but much less pronounced. The third and lowest curve is the ratio of total

exergy inputs, including non-fuel exergy, especially agricultural phytomass, to GDP. The

pronounced inverted U in the top curve apparently reflects the substitution of commercial

fuels for non-commercial fuels (wood) during early stages of industrialization.
Ayres and Warr                          Accounting for growth                              Page 11




III. CALCULATION OF PHYSICAL WORK



         As noted earlier, the technical definition of exergy is the maximum work that a system

can do as it approaches thermodynamic equilibrium (reversibly) with its surroundings. It is

also measured in energy units. Not surprisingly, exergy values are very nearly the same as

enthalpy (heat values) for ordinary fuels. So, what most people mean when they speak of

“energy”, is really “exergy, except that exergy is also definable for non-fuel materials. We

have done the appropriate calculations in detail in other publications.)

         However, technically, exergy is also equal to maximum potential work. For non-

engineers, mechanical work can be exemplified in a variety of ways, such as pulling a plow,

lifting a weight against gravity or compressing a fluid. The term horsepower was introduced

in the context of horses pumping water from flooded 18th century British coal or tin mines. A

more general definition of work is movement against a potential gradient (or resistance) of

some sort. A heat engine is a mechanical device to perform work from heat, though not all

work is performed by engines as we will point out later. With this in mind, we can subdivide

work into three broad categories, namely work done by animal (or human) muscles7, work

done by heat engines (i.e. mechanical work) and work done in other ways (e.g. thermal or

chemical work).

         Mechanical work can be further subdivided into work done to generate electric power

and work done to provide motive power (e.g. to drive motor vehicles.) The power sources in

both cases are called “prime movers”, including all kinds of internal and external combustion

engines, from steam turbines to jet engines. So called “renewables”, including hydraulic,

nuclear, wind and solar power sources for electric power generation are conventionally

included in energy statistics. Electricity can be thought of as “pure” work, since it can be
Ayres and Warr                          Accounting for growth                               Page 12




reconverted back into mechanical work, chemical work or thermal work with little or no loss.

However electric motors are not prime movers, because electricity is generated by a prior

prime mover, usually a steam or gas turbine.

         Chemical work is exemplified by the reduction of metal ores to obtain the pure metal,

or indeed any endothermic (heat consuming) chemical process, such as ammonia synthesis.

Thermal work is exemplified by the transfer of heat from its point of origin (e.g. a furnace in

the basement) to its point of use, such as a living-room, via a heat-exchanger (e.g. a radiator).

         So much for definitions. To measure the work done U, by the economy as a whole, it

is helpful to classify fuels by use. The first use-category is fuel used by prime movers to do

mechanical work. This consists of fuel used by electric power generation equipment and fuel

used by mobile power sources such as motor vehicles, aircraft and so on. As regards mobile

power sources, we choose to define efficiency in terms of the whole vehicle, not just the

engine itself. Thus the efficiency of an automobile is the ratio of work done by the wheels on

the road to the total potential work (exergy content) of the fuel. Data are available on fuel

consumed by electric power generating plants (known as the “heat rate”) but the work output

is also measured directly as kilowatt hours of electric power produced. The second broad

category is fuel used to generate heat as such, either for industry (process heat to do chemical

work) or space heat and domestic uses such as washing and cooking. Lighting can be thought

of as third category, which is almost a special case.

         So far we have only considered exergy inputs. The inputs for animal work are, of

course, feedstuffs. Horses and mules, which accounted for most animal work on US farms

and urban transport, have not changed biologically since their heyday. The efficiency with

which animals convert feed energy to work is generally reckoned at about 4 percent. The

uncertainty is unimportant for our purposes.
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                              Page 13




         The agricultural phytomass that is converted into human food (as well as petfood,

cotton, tobacco, and soap) contribute to the economy in the same way as other industrial

materials. The recent phytomass-to-food conversion efficiency for North America (via meat,

eggs and milk) has been estimated as 5.5 percent (Stefan Wirsenius 2000). In 1900 a

significant share – about 20 percent – went to feed horses and mules, but as people consume

ever more animal products, the efficiency of conversion is unlikely to be increasing.

         On the other hand, the efficiency of heat engines, domestic and commercial heating

systems and industrial thermal processes has changed significantly over the past 100 years.

We have plotted these increasing conversion efficiencies, from 1900 to 1998 in Figure 4.

(Detailed derivations of these curves can be found in another publication (Ayres et al 2002)).

Work by horses and mules (mostly on farms) has been estimated from the work/feed ratio,

together with the horse-mule population. Exergy allocations to different categories of work

are shown in Figure 5. Animal work was still significant in 1900 but mechanical and

electrical work have since become far more important.

         Electrification has been perhaps the single most important source of work and (as will

be seen later) the most powerful driver of economic growth. Electrical work need not be

computed from fuel inputs, since it is measured directly in kilowatt-hours (kwh) generated.

The fuel required to generate a kilowatt-hour of electric power has decreased by a factor of

nine during the past century. On the other hand, the consumption of electricity in the US has

increased over the same period by a factor of more than 1300, as shown in Figure 6. (This

exemplifies the positive feedback economic “growth engine” discussed earlier.)

         Effectively there are two definitions of work to be considered hereafter, namely
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                                Page 14




(2a)             UB = fBB



(2b)             UE = fEE



The ratios fB and fE are, effectively, composite conversion efficiencies. The former takes into

account animal work and all agricultural products, including animal feed. The latter neglects

animal work and also agricultural production. These two efficiency trends are plotted from

1900 to 1998 in Figure 7. It seems likely that, if the trend in f is fairly steadily upward

throughout a long period (such as a century) it would seem reasonably safe to project this

trend curve into the future for some decades.

         The trends in physical work done by the economy, together with the ratio of physical

work to deflated GDP, are shown in Figure 8. The total quantity of physical work inputs into

the economy rise steadily over the entire period and it seems likely that they will continue

increasing at a similar rate. Surprisingly, however, the slope of the ratio of work input to GDP

changes dramatically around 1970. Prior to this date the GDP output per unit of work input

was decreasing. After this date the trend unaccountably reversed. We think it important to

note that this could not be the result of a business cycle or any other short-term phenomenon.



IV. ELIMINATING THE SOLOW RESIDUAL: A NEARLY ENDOGENOUS

PRODUCTION FUNCTION



         There are two important conditions to be satisfied for either version of the expression

(1a,b) to be a production function. One of them is the Euler condition for constant returns to

scale, which means that for (1a) to be a production function the product fg (subscripts
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                              Page 15




omitted) must be a homogeneous first order function of three independent variables, K,L,E or

K,L,B. Similarly for (1b) to be a production function g must be a function of K,L,UE, or

K,L,UB . The other condition is that the marginal productivities of the three factors be non-

negative at all times, at least over a rolling average. (The marginal productivities, logarithmic

derivatives of output with respect to each of the factors, need not be constant in time. In fact

there is no theoretical reason why marginal productivities should be constant.)

         It is already evident from Figure 1 that the Cobb-Douglas function cannot explain US

economic growth since 1900. Of course Cobb-Douglas is the special case with constant

productivities. Of course, there are other functional forms combining the factors K, L, E (orB)

that do permit variable marginal productivities and thus may provide slightly better fits than

Cobb-Douglas, especially over moderate time periods. However, over the very long-term it is

easy to show that the constant returns (Euler) condition rules out any function of K, L, E or K,

L, B, since a homogeneous first order function cannot explain observed growth because such

a function cannot increase faster than any of its arguments and none of the three arguments

increases fast enough. In particular, exergy inputs – however defined – do not increase fast

enough to compensate for the slow growth of labor and capital. Hence no such functional

form can eliminate the need for a time dependent multiplier (Solow residual). This essentially

rules out (1a) as a viable production function choice.8

         We are left with (1b) and, of course, either (2a) or (2b). Over the long time period of

our data base, we want to allow for the possibility of non-constant productivities. It happens

that a convenient functional form (the so-called LINEX function) has been suggested by

Kümmel (Kümmel 1982)9, namely



(3)              Y = A U exp{aL/U - b(U+L)/K}
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                                  Page 16




where A is a multiplier that should (in principle) be independent of time, while a, b are

parameters to be determined econometrically. It can be verified without difficulty that this

function satisfies the Euler condition for constant returns to scale. It can also be shown that

the requirement of non-negative marginal productivities can be met. The three factor

productivities are as follows:



(4a)      M lnY/M lnK = (MY/ MK)(K/Y) = b(L/K) > 0


(4b       M lnY/M lnL = (MY/ML)(L/Y) = a(L/U) - b(L/K) > 0


(4c)      M lnY/M lnU = (MY/MUE)(U/Y) = 1 - a(L/U) - b(U/K) > 0


It follows from straightforward algebra that the requirement of non-negativity is equivalent to

the following three inequalities:



(5a)             b >0



(5b)             a > b(U/K)



(5c)             1 > a(L/U) + b(U/K)



The variable U in the above expressions (4,5) can, of course be interpreted in either of the

two ways indicated in (2) without affecting the results. The first condition (5a) is trivial.

However the second and third conditions are not automatically satisfied for all possible
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                                Page 17




values of the variables. It is therefore necessary to do the fitting by constrained non-linear

optimization. The statistical procedures and quality measures are discussed in the Appendix.

         The two curves in Figure 9 show the LINEX fits, where we have tested both

definitions of work UE and UB respectively as factors of production. The best fit is obtained

by using UB, recalling that total exergy B includes all phytomass inputs and UB includes

animal work. The unexplained residual has essentially disappeared, prior to 1975 and remains

small thereafter. In short, “technical progress” as defined by the Solow residual is almost

entirely explained by historical improvements in exergy conversion (to physical work), as

summarized in Figure 4, at least until recent times. The remaining unexplained residual,

amounting to roughly 12 percent of recent economic growth, is shown in Figure 10.

         The marginal productivities of the factors can be calculated directly from equations

(4). The three marginal productivities for each of the two interesting cases are plotted in

Figure 11a,b, respectively. The differences are surprisingly large, but the results for the best

fit case appear much smoother and more reasonable. There is a small but noticeable

directional shift that roughly coincides with the two so-called oil crises, and may well have

been triggered by the spike in energy (exergy) prices that occurred at that time. The shift can

be interpreted as a structural change in the economy, and conceivably, a change in the locus

of technological progress from energy conversion efficiency towards systems optimization.

However, interpretation of this shift – assuming it is real – will have to await further analysis.



V. IMPLICATIONS: TOWARDS AN ENDOGENOUS GROWTH MODEL



         In the “standard” Solow model a forecast of GDP requires a forecast of labor L,

capital stock K and a forecast of the technical change (or multi-factor productivity) multiplier
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                              Page 18




A(t). Based on the results described above, the technical progress term can be decomposed

into contributions from improved exergy conversion-to-(primary) work efficiency and

“other”. The years 1972 marked a distinct “turning point” in the economic history of the US.

Prior to those years the marginal increase per unit of primary work input was generally

falling; a kind of saturation phenomenon.

         After 1972, the trend was reversed. Figure 8 expresses this behaviour in terms of

primary work/GDP10. Evidently growth of GDP since 1972 has slightly outstripped growth of

the three input factors, capital (K), labor (L) and physical work (U). Clearly primary physical

work is still by far the dominant driver of growth. However, this does not mean that human

labor or capital are unimportant. The three factors are not really independent of each other.

Increasing exergy conversion efficiency requires investments of capital and labor, while the

creation of capital is highly dependent on the productivity of physical work. An additional

source of value added is involved. Part of the missing source of value added may have been

due to improvements in the efficiency of “secondary work” or work done by electricity.

Improvements in the efficiency of electric lighting, electric motors, refrigeration, electrolytic

processes and so forth have occurred since 1972, but are not reflected in our efficiency curves

(Figure 4). However, preliminary analysis suggests that these efficiency improvements are

not sufficient to account for the “extra” growth since 1972 or so.

         In the spirit of some endogenous growth theories, it would be possible to interpret this

additional productivity to some qualitative improvement in either capital or labor. It is

tempting to argue that the observed shift starting in the 1970's reflects the growing influence

of information technology. Certainly large scale systems optimization depends very strongly

on large data bases and information processing capability. The airline reservation systems

now in use have achieved significant operational economies and productivity gains for
Ayres and Warr                          Accounting for growth                               Page 19




airlines by increasing capacity utilization. Manufacturing firms have achieved comparable

gains through computerized integration of different functions. We cannot, however, offer any

econometric confirmation of these conjectures.

         One of the more important implications of results we have reported in this paper is

that some of the most dramatic and visible technological changes of the past century have

apparently not contributed significantly to overall economic growth. An example in point is

medical progress. While infant mortality has declined dramatically and life expectancy has

increased very significantly since 1900, it its hard to see any direct impact on economic

growth, at least up to the 1970's. Greater life expectancy (beyond the age of 60) has added

little to labor productivity, and may actually decrease it. (However, it is possible that some of

the GDP gains since 1970 can be attributed to increased expenditure on health services.) The

gain from medical progress in recent decades, at least, has been primarily in quality of life,

not quantity of output.

         Changes in telecommunications technology since 1900 may constitute another

example. Faster communication has clearly generated more communication – a kind or

rebound effect – but it is not clear that greater efficiency has resulted. (The examples of fax

and email are instructive in this regard.) New service industries, like moving pictures, radio

and TV have been created, but if the net result is new forms of entertainment, the gains in

employment and output may have come largely at the expense of earlier forms of public news

and entertainment, such as the print media, live theater, circuses and vaudeville. While the

changes have been spectacular, as measured in terms of information transmitted, the

productivity gains may not have been especially large, at least until recently. Again, the net

impact may have been primarily on quality of life.
Ayres and Warr                             Accounting for growth                               Page 20




         Turning to the problem of forecasting, since economic growth for the past century, at

least up to 1980, can be explained with considerable accuracy by three factors, K, L, UB, it is

not unreasonable to expect that future growth for some time to come will be explained quite

well by these three variables, plus a growing contribution from IT. From a long-term

sustainability viewpoint, this conclusion carries a powerful implication. If economic growth

is to continue without proportional increases in exergy (especially fossil fuel) consumption, it

is vitally important to use exergy ever more efficiently as well as to develop ways of

reducing fossil fuel exergy inputs per unit of physical work output. But, as declining marginal

returns to investment in R&D limits the future efficiency gains that can be expected – as

saturation approaches – we must deliberately exploit new ways of generating value added

without doing more physical work. In other words, energy (exergy) conservation is the main

key to long term environmental sustainability.



APPENDIX A



         For each definition of the LINEX function, the optimal parameters were obtained by

using a quasi-Newton non-linear optimization method, with box-constraints. The constraints

on the possible values of the parameters of the LINEX model were required to ensure that the

factor marginal productivities were non-negative. To avoid the influence of local minima the

starting values were selected iteratively. A statistical measure of the precision of fit was

provided by the Mean Square Error,



(A1)             MSE = [ t=1 3n (e2 )] '(n - k)
Ayres and Warr                          Accounting for growth                              Page 21




The MSE is a measure of the absolute deviation of the theoretical fit from the empirical

curve, where n is the number of samples, k the number of parameters and e the residual from

the fitted curve. We also calculated the correlation coefficients (r2) between log-transformed

GDP and each log-transformed factor. We tested the significance of the correlations using a t-

test with Welch modification for unequal variances (Table A1). The alternative hypothesis is

that the true difference in the means is not equal to zero at a 95 percent confidence level. The

results indicate that only fits with UE and UB are significant, and that of UB by far the most

significant as indicated by the low estimated t-values.



REFERENCES



Abramovitz, Moses. “Economics of Growth,” Haley (ed), A survey of contemporary

economics (Volume 2). New York: Richard D. Irwin, Inc, 1952, pp. 132-78.



______. “Resources and Output Trends in the United States since 1870.” American Economic

Review, May 1956, 46.



Aghion, Philippe and Howitt, Peter. Endogenous growth theory. Cambridge MA: The MIT

Press, 1998.



Ayres, Robert U. “The Minimum Complexity of Endogenous Growth Models: the Role of

Physical Resource Flows.” Energy, September 2001, 26(9), pp. 817-38.
Ayres and Warr                        Accounting for growth                           Page 22




Ayres, Robert. U; Ayres, Leslie W. and Warr, Benjamin. “Exergy, Power and Work in the

US Economy, 1900-1998.” Energy, (Forthcoming, 2002).



Barnett, Harold J. and Morse, Chandler. Scarcity and Growth: The Economics of

Resource Scarcity, Baltimore MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1962.



Beaudreau, Bernard C. Energy and Organization: Growth and Distribution Reexamined.

Westwood CT, Greenwood Press, 1998.



Cleveland, Cutler J. “Energy Quality and Energy Surplus in the Extraction of Fossil Fuels in

the US.” Ecological Economics, 1992, 6, pp. 139-62.



Cleveland, Cutler J.; Costanza, Robert; Hall, C. A. S. and Kaufmann, Robert K.

“Energy and the US Economy: A Biophysical Perspective.” Science, 1984, 255, pp. 890-97.



Cleveland, Cutler J.; Kaufmann, Robert K. and Stern, David I. “Aggregation and the

Role of Energy in the Economy.” Ecological Economics, February 2000, 32(2), pp. 301-17.



Dasgupta, Partha and Heal, Geoffrey. “The Optimal Depletion of Exhaustible Resources,”

Symposium on the Economics of Exhaustible Resources, Review of Economic Studies, 1974.



Domar, Evsey D. Essays in the Theory of Economic Growth, London: Oxford University

Press, 1957.
Ayres and Warr                        Accounting for growth                             Page 23




Fabricant, Solomon. “Economic Progress and Economic Change,” 34th Annual Report:

National Bureau of Economic Research, 1954.



Granger, C. W. J. “Investigating Causal Relations by Econometric Models and Cross-

spectral Methods.” Econometrica, 1969, 37, pp. 424-38.



Grossman, Gene M. and Helpman, Elhanen. Innovation and Growth in the Global

Economy. Cambridge MA: MIT Press, 1991.



Hannon, Bruce M. and Joyce, John. “Energy and Technical Progress.” Energy, 1981, 6, pp.

187-95.



Harrod, Roy F. Towards a Dynamic Economics (Out of Print), 1947.



Jorgenson, Dale W. “The Role of Energy in Productivity Growth.” The Energy Journal,

1984, 5(3), pp. 11-26.



Jorgenson, Dale W.; Christensen, Lauritz R. and Lau, Lawrence J. “Transcendental

Logarithmic Production Frontiers.” Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1973,

55(1), pp. 28-45.
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                        Page 24




Kaufmann, Robert K. “A Biophysical Analysis of the Energy/Real GDP Ratio: Implications

for Substitution and Technical Change.” Ecological Economics,, 1992, 6, pp. 33-56.



______.“The Economic Multiplier of Envirnmental Life Support: Can Capital Substitute for a

Degraded Environment?.” Ecological Economics , January 1995, 12(1), pp. 67-80.



Kümmel, Reiner. “Energy, Environment and Industrial Growth,” Economic Theory of

Natural Resources, Würzburg, Germany: Physica-Verlag, 1982.



Kümmel, Reiner; Lindenberger, D. and Eichhorn, Wolfgang. “The Productive Power of

Energy and Economic Evolution.” Indian Journal of Applied Economics, 2000, 8, pp. 231-62.



Kümmel, Reiner; Strassl, Wolfgang; Gossner, Alfred and Eichhorn, Wolfgang.

“Technical Progress and Energy Dependent Production Functions.” Journal of Economics,

1985, 45(3), pp. 285-311.



Lucas, Robert E. Jr. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary

Economics, July 1988, 22(1), pp. 2-42.



Mankiew, N. Gregory. Macroeconomics, Worth Publishing, 1997.



Meadows, Donella H.; Meadows, Dennis L.; Randers, Jorgen and Behrens, William W.

III. The Limits to Growth: A Report for the Club of Rome's Project on the Predicament of

Mankind. New York: Universe Books, 1972.
Ayres and Warr                        Accounting for growth                        Page 25




Potter, Neal and Christy, Francis T. Jr. Trends in Natural Resource Commodities,

Baltimore MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1968



Romer, Paul M. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy,

October 1990, 98(5), pp. S71-S102.



______. “Growth Based on Increasing Returns Due to Specialization.” American Economic

Review, May 1987, 77(2), pp. 56-62.



______. “Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth.” Journal of Political Economy, October

1986, 94(5), pp. 1002-37.



Sims, C. J. A. “Money, Income and Causality.” American Economic Review, 1972.



Smith, H. “The Cumulative Energy Requirements of Some Final Products of the Chemical

Industry.” Transactions of the World Energy Conference, 1969, p. 18(section E).
Ayres and Warr                         Accounting for growth                        Page 26




Solow, Robert M. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal

of Economics, 1956, 70, pp. 65-94.



______. “Intergenerational Equity and Exhaustible Resources.” Review of Economic Studies,

1974, 41, pp. 29-45.



______. “Perspectives on Growth Theory.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Winter 1994,

8(1), pp. 45-54.



______. “Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function.” Review of Economics

and Statistics, August 1957, 39, pp. 312-20.



Stern, David I. “Energy Use and Economic Growth in the USA: a Multivariate Approach.”

Energy Economics, 1993, 15, pp. 137-50.



Stiglitz, Joseph. “Growth with Exhaustible Natural Resources. Efficient and Optimal Growth

Paths.” Review of Economic Studies, 1974.



Swan, Trevor. “Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation.” The Economic Record, 1956,

32(68), pp. 334-361.



Wirsenius, Stefan. “Human Use of Organic Materials,” Doctoral Thesis, Gothenburg,

Sweden: Chalmers Institute of Technology and Gothenburg University, 2000.
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                            Page 27




FOOTNOTES



*        Robert U. Ayres

                 Center for the Management of Environmental Resources

                 INSEAD

                 77305 Fontainebleau, FRANCE

                 Tel: 33 (0) 1 60 72 40 11

                 Fax: 33 (0) 1 60 74 55 64

                 Email: robert.ayres@insead.edu

         Benjamin Warr

                 Center for the Management of Environmental Resources

                 INSEAD

                 77305 Fontainebleau, FRANCE

                 Tel: 33 (0) 1 60 72 41 28

                 Fax: 33 (0) 1 60 74 55 64

                 Email: benjamin.warr@insead.edu

         Research supported by Institute for Advanced Study, UN University, Tokyo and The

                 European Commission, TERRA project.

         We thank Christian Azar, Jonathan Cave, Barry Hughes, Jens Jesinghaus, Yuichi

                 Kaya, Reinhard Kümmel, Jeroen van den Bergh, Chihiro Watanabe, Eric

                 Williams, and Ulrich Witt for helpful discussions and suggestions. All errors

                 are our own.
Ayres and Warr                           Accounting for growth                                 Page 28




1.       The new A-K models are essentially throwbacks to the pre-Solow Harrod-Domar

         growth models (Roy F. Harrod 1948; Evsey D. Domar 1957).



2.       The tendency of virtually all raw material and fuel costs to decline over time (lumber

         was the main exception) has been thoroughly documented, especially by economists at

         Resources For the Future (RFF) (Harold J. Barnett and Chandler Morse 1962; Neal

         Potter and Francis T. Christy, Jr. 1968; H. Smith 1969).



3.       The proper definition of exergy is the maximum work that can be done by a system as

         it approaches equilibrium with its surroundings. Thus delivered exergy is effectively

         equivalent to work. The distinction netween exergy and energy is theoretically

         important because energy is a conserved quantity (first law of thermodynamics). This

         means that energy is not “used up” in physical processes, merely transformed from

         available to less available forms, with concomitant entropy production. On the other

         hand, exergy is not conserved: it is used up. The directionality of all spontaneous

         transformations the direction of increasing entropy (second law of thermodynamics).



4.        Marx believed (with some justification) that the gains would flow mainly to owners

         of capital rather than to workers. Political developments have changed the balance of

         power since Marx’s time. However, in either case, returns to energy or to physical

         resources tend to decline as output grows. This can be interpreted as declining real

         price.
Ayres and Warr                            Accounting for growth                              Page 29




5.       There are statistical approaches to addressing the causality issue. For instance,

         Granger and others have developed statistical tests that can provide some clues as to

         which is cause and which is effect (C. W. J. Granger 1969; C. J. A. Sims 1972). These

         tests have been applied to the question whether energy consumption is a cause or an

         effect of economic growth (David I. Stern 1993; Kaufmann 1995). In brief, the

         conclusions depend upon whether energy is measured in terms of heat value of all

         fuels (in which case the direction of causation is ambiguous) or whether the energy

         aggregate is adjusted to reflect the “quality” (or, more accurately, the price or

         productivity) of each fuel in the mix. In the latter case the econometric evidence seem

         to confirm that energy (exergy) consumption is a cause of growth. We comment on

         this result later.



6.        See the discussion of national income allocation in N. Gregory Mankiew’s new

         economics textbook “Macroeconomics” (N. Gregory Mankiew 1997).



7.       Human muscular work is insignificant by comparison with other sources of work, and

         we can neglect it as regards the US or any industrialized country. Human “labor” is

         something else entirely. It is a combination of sense-based supervision and

         coordination and brain work.



8.       The so-called endogenous growth theory gets around this difficulty by relaxing the

         Euler condition and allowing positive returns. However, as Solow has remarked, this

         seemingly simple change implies that infinite growth can occur in a finite period of

         time (Solow 1994).
Ayres and Warr                         Accounting for growth                           Page 30




9.       Kümmel introduced the LINEX function with E as a variable, rather than U.



10.      This is analogous to the so-called Kuznets (inverted U) curve for E/GDP shown in

         Figure 3 (upper curve).
Ayres and Warr                        Accounting for growth                             Page 31




    Table A1. Statistical measures of the quality and significance of fitted models
   Variable          t-value         Degrees of               p-value        Correlation

   used                                 freedom                           coefficient (r2)
   B                   5.74                158.4              4.5e-08                 0.98
   E                   3.09                174.3               0.002                  0.97
   UE                  0.51                194.8               0.604                  0.99
   UB                  0.19                195.9               0.845                  0.99
Ayres and Warr                          Accounting for growth                             Page 32




FIGURE HEADINGS



Figure 1a. Traditional factors of production K, L, E, USA 1900-1998

Figure 1b. Cobb Douglas production function and Solow Residual, USA 1900-1998

Figure 2. Exergy inputs, USA 1900-1998

Figure 3. The ratio of exergy inputs to GDP, USA 1900-1998

Figure 4. Energy (exergy) conversion efficiencies, USA 1900-1998

Figure 5. Allocation of exergy by types of work, USA 1900-1998

Figure 6. Electricity production and conversion efficiency

Figure 7. Exergy conversion efficiency f, for two definitions of work and exergy, USA 1900-

          1998

Figure 8. Primary work and the primary work/GDP ratio, USA 1900-1998

Figure 9. LINEX production function fits with different ‘energy’ factor inputs, USA 1900-

          1998

Figure 10. The percentage of observed growth unexplained by the LINEX fit with ‘work’

          (UB)

Figure 11a. Marginal productivities (elasticities) of each factor of production using UE in

          LINEX, USA 1900-1998

Figure 11b. Marginal productivities (elasticities) of each factor of production using UB in

          LINEX, USA 1900-1998
12

                                            K
                                            L
                                            E
                                10
standardised value (1900 = 1)




                                8




                                6




                                4




                                2




                                     1900       1920   1940          1960   1980   2000

                                                              year
20             Y GDP (actual)
                           Y = Ka Lb Eg
                           A(t), Solow Residual

                           a = 0.28
                           b = 0.68
            15             g = 0.04

                           MSE = 28
estimates




            10




            5




            0


                 1900             1920            1940          1960   1980   2000

                                                         year
                 Base Year 1900 = 1992 $ 354 billion
100

                         TOTAL FOSSIL FUEL
                         PHYTOMASS
      90                 OTHER
                         MINERALS & METALS
                         RENEWABLES
      80



      70



      60



eJ
      50



      40



      30



      20



      10



      0
           1908   1918   1928   1938   1948   1958 1968   1978   1988   1998
                                       year
1.6
                                                TOTAL EXERGY (incl. Phytomass) /
                                                GDP RATIO
                                                TOTAL EXERGY (excl. Phytomass) /
        1.4                                     GDP RATIO
                                                FOSSIL FUEL EXERGY / GDP RATIO



        1.2




         1



                                               Great
ratio




                                               Depression
        0.8
                 WW I



        0.6




        0.4
                                WW II


                                                                        Peak US
        0.2                                                             Domestic
                                                                        Petroleum
                                                                        Production


         0
          1900    1910   1920    1930   1940     1950   1960   1970   1980   1990
                                                year
40%
                             High Temperature Industrial
                             Heat

               35%           Medium Temperature
                             Industrial Heat

                             Low Temperature Space
                             Heat
               30%
                             Electric Power Generation
                             and Distribution

                             Other Mechanical
               25%           Work
Fraction (%)




               20%




               15%




               10%




               5%




               0%
                     1910   1920   1930   1940   1950    1960   1970   1980   1990   2000
                                                 year
90%
                                                  HEAT

                                                  LIGHT
80%
                                                  ELECTRICITY

                                                  OTHER PRIME
70%                                               MOVERS
                                                  NON-FUEL


60%




50%




40%




30%




20%




10%




0%
      1908   1918   1928   1938   1948   1958   1968   1978   1988   1998
                                  year
40%                                                          800
                          % Electric Power Generation and
                          Distribution (left scale)

             35%          Index of Electricity Production (right scale)   700




             30%                                                          600




                                                                                index of output (1900=5000 gWh)
             25%                                                          500
efficiency




             20%                                                          400




             15%                                                          300




             10%                                                          200




             5%                                                           100




             0%                                                           0
                   1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990
                                           year
0.30

                     calculated using B and UB


                     calculated using E and Ue

        0.25




        0.20
ratio




        0.15




        0.10




        0.05




        0.00
               1908 1918 1928 1938 1948 1958 1968 1978 1988 1998
                                       year
40                                                    2.5

                            Primary work (left scale)


              35            Primary work / GDP ratio (right)


                                                                    2.0

              30




              25
                                                                    1.5
Exergy (eJ)




                                                                          ratio
              20



                                                                    1.0
              15




              10

                                                                    0.5


               5




               0                                                    0.0
                   1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
                                           year
20              empirical GDP
                      Theoretical estimates:



                              using UE    - MSE = 52
              15
                              using UB    - MSE = 7
GDP (1992$)




              10




              5




                   1900     1920         1940          1960   1980   2000

                                                year
12



              10



              8
% of growth




              6



              4



              2



              0




                   1975   1980   1985   1990   1995

                                 year
1.0




             Capital - K
             Labor - L
             Work – UE
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0




      1900    1920         1940          1960   1980   2000

                                  year
1.0




             Capital - K
             Labor - L
             Work - UB
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0




      1900    1920         1940          1960   1980   2000

                                  year

Más contenido relacionado

La actualidad más candente

KS-1648-MP043A-Energy-productivity-in-the-GCC_Evidence-From-an-International-...
KS-1648-MP043A-Energy-productivity-in-the-GCC_Evidence-From-an-International-...KS-1648-MP043A-Energy-productivity-in-the-GCC_Evidence-From-an-International-...
KS-1648-MP043A-Energy-productivity-in-the-GCC_Evidence-From-an-International-...Nicholas Howarth
 
Research Paper on Endogenous Growth Theory 1.2
Research Paper on Endogenous Growth Theory 1.2Research Paper on Endogenous Growth Theory 1.2
Research Paper on Endogenous Growth Theory 1.2Colby Scott
 
Emilie Yonan Honors Thesis Final Copy
Emilie Yonan Honors Thesis Final CopyEmilie Yonan Honors Thesis Final Copy
Emilie Yonan Honors Thesis Final CopyEmilie Yonan
 
Lewis dual sector model and its applicability to Indian agriculture
Lewis dual sector model and its applicability to Indian agricultureLewis dual sector model and its applicability to Indian agriculture
Lewis dual sector model and its applicability to Indian agricultureAshok Taradale
 
New growth theoris
New growth theorisNew growth theoris
New growth theorisU6410
 
A Selective Survey to the Literature on Job Creation and Destruction
A Selective Survey to the Literature on Job Creation and DestructionA Selective Survey to the Literature on Job Creation and Destruction
A Selective Survey to the Literature on Job Creation and DestructionPalkansaajien tutkimuslaitos
 
'Counter-Framing the New Economy'
'Counter-Framing the New Economy''Counter-Framing the New Economy'
'Counter-Framing the New Economy'Sharon Prendeville
 
working in the 'Sharing Economy'
working in the 'Sharing Economy' working in the 'Sharing Economy'
working in the 'Sharing Economy' Al James
 
14. history of energy use
14. history of energy use 14. history of energy use
14. history of energy use mkornrei
 
Lectnotes 8 Econ175a
Lectnotes 8 Econ175aLectnotes 8 Econ175a
Lectnotes 8 Econ175adpaul
 
Population growth decelerating faster than expected; potential consequences f...
Population growth decelerating faster than expected; potential consequences f...Population growth decelerating faster than expected; potential consequences f...
Population growth decelerating faster than expected; potential consequences f...Lewis Larsen
 

La actualidad más candente (14)

KS-1648-MP043A-Energy-productivity-in-the-GCC_Evidence-From-an-International-...
KS-1648-MP043A-Energy-productivity-in-the-GCC_Evidence-From-an-International-...KS-1648-MP043A-Energy-productivity-in-the-GCC_Evidence-From-an-International-...
KS-1648-MP043A-Energy-productivity-in-the-GCC_Evidence-From-an-International-...
 
Rural urban migration
Rural urban migrationRural urban migration
Rural urban migration
 
Research Paper on Endogenous Growth Theory 1.2
Research Paper on Endogenous Growth Theory 1.2Research Paper on Endogenous Growth Theory 1.2
Research Paper on Endogenous Growth Theory 1.2
 
Energy, Environment and Economic Growth
Energy, Environment and Economic GrowthEnergy, Environment and Economic Growth
Energy, Environment and Economic Growth
 
Technical Change, Effective Demand and Employment
Technical Change, Effective Demand and EmploymentTechnical Change, Effective Demand and Employment
Technical Change, Effective Demand and Employment
 
Emilie Yonan Honors Thesis Final Copy
Emilie Yonan Honors Thesis Final CopyEmilie Yonan Honors Thesis Final Copy
Emilie Yonan Honors Thesis Final Copy
 
Lewis dual sector model and its applicability to Indian agriculture
Lewis dual sector model and its applicability to Indian agricultureLewis dual sector model and its applicability to Indian agriculture
Lewis dual sector model and its applicability to Indian agriculture
 
New growth theoris
New growth theorisNew growth theoris
New growth theoris
 
A Selective Survey to the Literature on Job Creation and Destruction
A Selective Survey to the Literature on Job Creation and DestructionA Selective Survey to the Literature on Job Creation and Destruction
A Selective Survey to the Literature on Job Creation and Destruction
 
'Counter-Framing the New Economy'
'Counter-Framing the New Economy''Counter-Framing the New Economy'
'Counter-Framing the New Economy'
 
working in the 'Sharing Economy'
working in the 'Sharing Economy' working in the 'Sharing Economy'
working in the 'Sharing Economy'
 
14. history of energy use
14. history of energy use 14. history of energy use
14. history of energy use
 
Lectnotes 8 Econ175a
Lectnotes 8 Econ175aLectnotes 8 Econ175a
Lectnotes 8 Econ175a
 
Population growth decelerating faster than expected; potential consequences f...
Population growth decelerating faster than expected; potential consequences f...Population growth decelerating faster than expected; potential consequences f...
Population growth decelerating faster than expected; potential consequences f...
 

Similar a Accounting for Growth, Robert Ayres & Benjamin Warr

The role of energy in economic growth - Stern
The role of energy in economic growth - SternThe role of energy in economic growth - Stern
The role of energy in economic growth - SternZeus Guevara
 
Entropy law and the impossibility of perpetual economic growth
Entropy law and the impossibility of perpetual economic growthEntropy law and the impossibility of perpetual economic growth
Entropy law and the impossibility of perpetual economic growthKalasekar M
 
An Empirical And Theoretical Literature Review On Endogenous Growth In Latin ...
An Empirical And Theoretical Literature Review On Endogenous Growth In Latin ...An Empirical And Theoretical Literature Review On Endogenous Growth In Latin ...
An Empirical And Theoretical Literature Review On Endogenous Growth In Latin ...Wendy Hager
 
Thermodinamic and economics
Thermodinamic and economicsThermodinamic and economics
Thermodinamic and economicsMJ
 
4. For non economist paper.pdf
4. For non economist paper.pdf4. For non economist paper.pdf
4. For non economist paper.pdfAnimut Belay
 
Energy Access and Human Development Transcript
Energy Access and Human Development TranscriptEnergy Access and Human Development Transcript
Energy Access and Human Development TranscriptFric Horta
 
A critique of techno optimism (Alexander 2014) Lecturas recomendadas Samuel M...
A critique of techno optimism (Alexander 2014) Lecturas recomendadas Samuel M...A critique of techno optimism (Alexander 2014) Lecturas recomendadas Samuel M...
A critique of techno optimism (Alexander 2014) Lecturas recomendadas Samuel M...Ecologistas en Accion
 
9789740328255
97897403282559789740328255
9789740328255CUPress
 
Mpra paper 69860
Mpra paper 69860Mpra paper 69860
Mpra paper 69860davide7775
 
Christopher A. Hartwell. Institutions, Resource Rents, and Cleanliness: The I...
Christopher A. Hartwell. Institutions, Resource Rents, and Cleanliness: The I...Christopher A. Hartwell. Institutions, Resource Rents, and Cleanliness: The I...
Christopher A. Hartwell. Institutions, Resource Rents, and Cleanliness: The I...Eesti Pank
 
Technology and economic growth
Technology and economic growthTechnology and economic growth
Technology and economic growthalexa_vani
 
Technology and economic growth
Technology and economic growthTechnology and economic growth
Technology and economic growthalexa_vani
 
Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?. Nicholas Bloom, Charles I. Jones, John Van...
Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?. Nicholas Bloom, Charles I. Jones, John Van...Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?. Nicholas Bloom, Charles I. Jones, John Van...
Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?. Nicholas Bloom, Charles I. Jones, John Van...eraser Juan José Calderón
 
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’Adam Higdon
 
Skringar et al 2013 - Systemic and institutional barriers to core sustainabil...
Skringar et al 2013 - Systemic and institutional barriers to core sustainabil...Skringar et al 2013 - Systemic and institutional barriers to core sustainabil...
Skringar et al 2013 - Systemic and institutional barriers to core sustainabil...Elizabeth R Skringar
 

Similar a Accounting for Growth, Robert Ayres & Benjamin Warr (20)

The role of energy in economic growth - Stern
The role of energy in economic growth - SternThe role of energy in economic growth - Stern
The role of energy in economic growth - Stern
 
Entropy law and the impossibility of perpetual economic growth
Entropy law and the impossibility of perpetual economic growthEntropy law and the impossibility of perpetual economic growth
Entropy law and the impossibility of perpetual economic growth
 
Chandraketutripathi_world 2050-1
Chandraketutripathi_world 2050-1Chandraketutripathi_world 2050-1
Chandraketutripathi_world 2050-1
 
An Empirical And Theoretical Literature Review On Endogenous Growth In Latin ...
An Empirical And Theoretical Literature Review On Endogenous Growth In Latin ...An Empirical And Theoretical Literature Review On Endogenous Growth In Latin ...
An Empirical And Theoretical Literature Review On Endogenous Growth In Latin ...
 
Thermodinamic and economics
Thermodinamic and economicsThermodinamic and economics
Thermodinamic and economics
 
4. For non economist paper.pdf
4. For non economist paper.pdf4. For non economist paper.pdf
4. For non economist paper.pdf
 
Energy Access and Human Development Transcript
Energy Access and Human Development TranscriptEnergy Access and Human Development Transcript
Energy Access and Human Development Transcript
 
Transport System Resilience in a Climate Change World
Transport System Resilience in a Climate Change WorldTransport System Resilience in a Climate Change World
Transport System Resilience in a Climate Change World
 
A critique of techno optimism (Alexander 2014) Lecturas recomendadas Samuel M...
A critique of techno optimism (Alexander 2014) Lecturas recomendadas Samuel M...A critique of techno optimism (Alexander 2014) Lecturas recomendadas Samuel M...
A critique of techno optimism (Alexander 2014) Lecturas recomendadas Samuel M...
 
Modigliani lch
Modigliani lchModigliani lch
Modigliani lch
 
9789740328255
97897403282559789740328255
9789740328255
 
Economic growth 2
Economic growth 2Economic growth 2
Economic growth 2
 
Mpra paper 69860
Mpra paper 69860Mpra paper 69860
Mpra paper 69860
 
Christopher A. Hartwell. Institutions, Resource Rents, and Cleanliness: The I...
Christopher A. Hartwell. Institutions, Resource Rents, and Cleanliness: The I...Christopher A. Hartwell. Institutions, Resource Rents, and Cleanliness: The I...
Christopher A. Hartwell. Institutions, Resource Rents, and Cleanliness: The I...
 
Technology and economic growth
Technology and economic growthTechnology and economic growth
Technology and economic growth
 
Technology and economic growth
Technology and economic growthTechnology and economic growth
Technology and economic growth
 
Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?. Nicholas Bloom, Charles I. Jones, John Van...
Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?. Nicholas Bloom, Charles I. Jones, John Van...Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?. Nicholas Bloom, Charles I. Jones, John Van...
Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?. Nicholas Bloom, Charles I. Jones, John Van...
 
Baumol productive unproductive destructive
Baumol productive unproductive destructiveBaumol productive unproductive destructive
Baumol productive unproductive destructive
 
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
 
Skringar et al 2013 - Systemic and institutional barriers to core sustainabil...
Skringar et al 2013 - Systemic and institutional barriers to core sustainabil...Skringar et al 2013 - Systemic and institutional barriers to core sustainabil...
Skringar et al 2013 - Systemic and institutional barriers to core sustainabil...
 

Más de Benjamin Warr

INSEAD Energy Network Our Vision and Action PRESS
INSEAD Energy Network Our Vision and Action PRESSINSEAD Energy Network Our Vision and Action PRESS
INSEAD Energy Network Our Vision and Action PRESSBenjamin Warr
 
Benjamin Warr Thalwil Presentation 2004
Benjamin Warr Thalwil Presentation 2004Benjamin Warr Thalwil Presentation 2004
Benjamin Warr Thalwil Presentation 2004Benjamin Warr
 
Insead Alumni Energy Network 22nd October 2011 by Benjamin Warr
Insead Alumni Energy Network 22nd October 2011 by Benjamin WarrInsead Alumni Energy Network 22nd October 2011 by Benjamin Warr
Insead Alumni Energy Network 22nd October 2011 by Benjamin WarrBenjamin Warr
 
Warr Athens 26 Jan 2010 Sustainable Agriculture
Warr Athens 26 Jan 2010 Sustainable AgricultureWarr Athens 26 Jan 2010 Sustainable Agriculture
Warr Athens 26 Jan 2010 Sustainable AgricultureBenjamin Warr
 
Analyse De Cycle De Vie Life Cycle Analysis
Analyse De Cycle De Vie   Life Cycle AnalysisAnalyse De Cycle De Vie   Life Cycle Analysis
Analyse De Cycle De Vie Life Cycle AnalysisBenjamin Warr
 
Warr Jussieu Presentation 240406
Warr Jussieu Presentation 240406Warr Jussieu Presentation 240406
Warr Jussieu Presentation 240406Benjamin Warr
 
Lund 29th October 2009 The Growth Engine Warr
Lund 29th October 2009 The Growth Engine WarrLund 29th October 2009 The Growth Engine Warr
Lund 29th October 2009 The Growth Engine WarrBenjamin Warr
 
Warr 8th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 8th Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingWarr 8th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 8th Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingBenjamin Warr
 
Warr 3rd Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 3rd Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingWarr 3rd Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 3rd Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingBenjamin Warr
 
Warr 2nd Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 2nd Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingWarr 2nd Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 2nd Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingBenjamin Warr
 
Warr 4th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 4th Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingWarr 4th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 4th Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingBenjamin Warr
 
Warr 7th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 7th Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingWarr 7th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 7th Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingBenjamin Warr
 

Más de Benjamin Warr (12)

INSEAD Energy Network Our Vision and Action PRESS
INSEAD Energy Network Our Vision and Action PRESSINSEAD Energy Network Our Vision and Action PRESS
INSEAD Energy Network Our Vision and Action PRESS
 
Benjamin Warr Thalwil Presentation 2004
Benjamin Warr Thalwil Presentation 2004Benjamin Warr Thalwil Presentation 2004
Benjamin Warr Thalwil Presentation 2004
 
Insead Alumni Energy Network 22nd October 2011 by Benjamin Warr
Insead Alumni Energy Network 22nd October 2011 by Benjamin WarrInsead Alumni Energy Network 22nd October 2011 by Benjamin Warr
Insead Alumni Energy Network 22nd October 2011 by Benjamin Warr
 
Warr Athens 26 Jan 2010 Sustainable Agriculture
Warr Athens 26 Jan 2010 Sustainable AgricultureWarr Athens 26 Jan 2010 Sustainable Agriculture
Warr Athens 26 Jan 2010 Sustainable Agriculture
 
Analyse De Cycle De Vie Life Cycle Analysis
Analyse De Cycle De Vie   Life Cycle AnalysisAnalyse De Cycle De Vie   Life Cycle Analysis
Analyse De Cycle De Vie Life Cycle Analysis
 
Warr Jussieu Presentation 240406
Warr Jussieu Presentation 240406Warr Jussieu Presentation 240406
Warr Jussieu Presentation 240406
 
Lund 29th October 2009 The Growth Engine Warr
Lund 29th October 2009 The Growth Engine WarrLund 29th October 2009 The Growth Engine Warr
Lund 29th October 2009 The Growth Engine Warr
 
Warr 8th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 8th Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingWarr 8th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 8th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
 
Warr 3rd Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 3rd Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingWarr 3rd Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 3rd Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
 
Warr 2nd Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 2nd Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingWarr 2nd Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 2nd Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
 
Warr 4th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 4th Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingWarr 4th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 4th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
 
Warr 7th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 7th Iiasa Titech Technical MeetingWarr 7th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
Warr 7th Iiasa Titech Technical Meeting
 

Último

Church Building Grants To Assist With New Construction, Additions, And Restor...
Church Building Grants To Assist With New Construction, Additions, And Restor...Church Building Grants To Assist With New Construction, Additions, And Restor...
Church Building Grants To Assist With New Construction, Additions, And Restor...Americas Got Grants
 
The-Ethical-issues-ghhhhhhhhjof-Byjus.pptx
The-Ethical-issues-ghhhhhhhhjof-Byjus.pptxThe-Ethical-issues-ghhhhhhhhjof-Byjus.pptx
The-Ethical-issues-ghhhhhhhhjof-Byjus.pptxmbikashkanyari
 
Call US-88OO1O2216 Call Girls In Mahipalpur Female Escort Service
Call US-88OO1O2216 Call Girls In Mahipalpur Female Escort ServiceCall US-88OO1O2216 Call Girls In Mahipalpur Female Escort Service
Call US-88OO1O2216 Call Girls In Mahipalpur Female Escort Servicecallgirls2057
 
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024Kirill Klimov
 
Darshan Hiranandani [News About Next CEO].pdf
Darshan Hiranandani [News About Next CEO].pdfDarshan Hiranandani [News About Next CEO].pdf
Darshan Hiranandani [News About Next CEO].pdfShashank Mehta
 
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchir
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent ChirchirMarketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchir
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchirictsugar
 
TriStar Gold Corporate Presentation - April 2024
TriStar Gold Corporate Presentation - April 2024TriStar Gold Corporate Presentation - April 2024
TriStar Gold Corporate Presentation - April 2024Adnet Communications
 
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Tughlakabad Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Tughlakabad Delhi NCR8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Tughlakabad Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Tughlakabad Delhi NCRashishs7044
 
Investment in The Coconut Industry by Nancy Cheruiyot
Investment in The Coconut Industry by Nancy CheruiyotInvestment in The Coconut Industry by Nancy Cheruiyot
Investment in The Coconut Industry by Nancy Cheruiyotictsugar
 
APRIL2024_UKRAINE_xml_0000000000000 .pdf
APRIL2024_UKRAINE_xml_0000000000000 .pdfAPRIL2024_UKRAINE_xml_0000000000000 .pdf
APRIL2024_UKRAINE_xml_0000000000000 .pdfRbc Rbcua
 
International Business Environments and Operations 16th Global Edition test b...
International Business Environments and Operations 16th Global Edition test b...International Business Environments and Operations 16th Global Edition test b...
International Business Environments and Operations 16th Global Edition test b...ssuserf63bd7
 
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Rohini Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Rohini Delhi NCR8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Rohini Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Rohini Delhi NCRashishs7044
 
Cybersecurity Awareness Training Presentation v2024.03
Cybersecurity Awareness Training Presentation v2024.03Cybersecurity Awareness Training Presentation v2024.03
Cybersecurity Awareness Training Presentation v2024.03DallasHaselhorst
 
Guide Complete Set of Residential Architectural Drawings PDF
Guide Complete Set of Residential Architectural Drawings PDFGuide Complete Set of Residential Architectural Drawings PDF
Guide Complete Set of Residential Architectural Drawings PDFChandresh Chudasama
 
Traction part 2 - EOS Model JAX Bridges.
Traction part 2 - EOS Model JAX Bridges.Traction part 2 - EOS Model JAX Bridges.
Traction part 2 - EOS Model JAX Bridges.Anamaria Contreras
 
Financial-Statement-Analysis-of-Coca-cola-Company.pptx
Financial-Statement-Analysis-of-Coca-cola-Company.pptxFinancial-Statement-Analysis-of-Coca-cola-Company.pptx
Financial-Statement-Analysis-of-Coca-cola-Company.pptxsaniyaimamuddin
 
PSCC - Capability Statement Presentation
PSCC - Capability Statement PresentationPSCC - Capability Statement Presentation
PSCC - Capability Statement PresentationAnamaria Contreras
 

Último (20)

Church Building Grants To Assist With New Construction, Additions, And Restor...
Church Building Grants To Assist With New Construction, Additions, And Restor...Church Building Grants To Assist With New Construction, Additions, And Restor...
Church Building Grants To Assist With New Construction, Additions, And Restor...
 
No-1 Call Girls In Goa 93193 VIP 73153 Escort service In North Goa Panaji, Ca...
No-1 Call Girls In Goa 93193 VIP 73153 Escort service In North Goa Panaji, Ca...No-1 Call Girls In Goa 93193 VIP 73153 Escort service In North Goa Panaji, Ca...
No-1 Call Girls In Goa 93193 VIP 73153 Escort service In North Goa Panaji, Ca...
 
The-Ethical-issues-ghhhhhhhhjof-Byjus.pptx
The-Ethical-issues-ghhhhhhhhjof-Byjus.pptxThe-Ethical-issues-ghhhhhhhhjof-Byjus.pptx
The-Ethical-issues-ghhhhhhhhjof-Byjus.pptx
 
Call US-88OO1O2216 Call Girls In Mahipalpur Female Escort Service
Call US-88OO1O2216 Call Girls In Mahipalpur Female Escort ServiceCall US-88OO1O2216 Call Girls In Mahipalpur Female Escort Service
Call US-88OO1O2216 Call Girls In Mahipalpur Female Escort Service
 
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024
 
Darshan Hiranandani [News About Next CEO].pdf
Darshan Hiranandani [News About Next CEO].pdfDarshan Hiranandani [News About Next CEO].pdf
Darshan Hiranandani [News About Next CEO].pdf
 
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchir
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent ChirchirMarketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchir
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchir
 
TriStar Gold Corporate Presentation - April 2024
TriStar Gold Corporate Presentation - April 2024TriStar Gold Corporate Presentation - April 2024
TriStar Gold Corporate Presentation - April 2024
 
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Tughlakabad Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Tughlakabad Delhi NCR8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Tughlakabad Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Tughlakabad Delhi NCR
 
Investment in The Coconut Industry by Nancy Cheruiyot
Investment in The Coconut Industry by Nancy CheruiyotInvestment in The Coconut Industry by Nancy Cheruiyot
Investment in The Coconut Industry by Nancy Cheruiyot
 
APRIL2024_UKRAINE_xml_0000000000000 .pdf
APRIL2024_UKRAINE_xml_0000000000000 .pdfAPRIL2024_UKRAINE_xml_0000000000000 .pdf
APRIL2024_UKRAINE_xml_0000000000000 .pdf
 
Corporate Profile 47Billion Information Technology
Corporate Profile 47Billion Information TechnologyCorporate Profile 47Billion Information Technology
Corporate Profile 47Billion Information Technology
 
International Business Environments and Operations 16th Global Edition test b...
International Business Environments and Operations 16th Global Edition test b...International Business Environments and Operations 16th Global Edition test b...
International Business Environments and Operations 16th Global Edition test b...
 
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Rohini Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Rohini Delhi NCR8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Rohini Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Rohini Delhi NCR
 
Cybersecurity Awareness Training Presentation v2024.03
Cybersecurity Awareness Training Presentation v2024.03Cybersecurity Awareness Training Presentation v2024.03
Cybersecurity Awareness Training Presentation v2024.03
 
Guide Complete Set of Residential Architectural Drawings PDF
Guide Complete Set of Residential Architectural Drawings PDFGuide Complete Set of Residential Architectural Drawings PDF
Guide Complete Set of Residential Architectural Drawings PDF
 
Traction part 2 - EOS Model JAX Bridges.
Traction part 2 - EOS Model JAX Bridges.Traction part 2 - EOS Model JAX Bridges.
Traction part 2 - EOS Model JAX Bridges.
 
Financial-Statement-Analysis-of-Coca-cola-Company.pptx
Financial-Statement-Analysis-of-Coca-cola-Company.pptxFinancial-Statement-Analysis-of-Coca-cola-Company.pptx
Financial-Statement-Analysis-of-Coca-cola-Company.pptx
 
Japan IT Week 2024 Brochure by 47Billion (English)
Japan IT Week 2024 Brochure by 47Billion (English)Japan IT Week 2024 Brochure by 47Billion (English)
Japan IT Week 2024 Brochure by 47Billion (English)
 
PSCC - Capability Statement Presentation
PSCC - Capability Statement PresentationPSCC - Capability Statement Presentation
PSCC - Capability Statement Presentation
 

Accounting for Growth, Robert Ayres & Benjamin Warr

  • 1. ACCOUNTING FOR GROWTH: THE ROLE OF PHYSICAL WORK Robert U. Ayres and Benjamin Warr* ABSTRACT We test several related hypothesis for explaining US economic growth since 1900. Introducing physical work, instead of energy, as a factor of production the historical growth path is reproduced with high accuracy from 1900 until the mid 1970's. In effect, the Solow residual is explained as increasing energy-conversion (to work) efficiency. The remaining unexplained residual amounts to only about 12 percent of total growth since that time. Information technology may be responsible for the unexplained growth. Keywords: Economic growth; Exergy; Productivity; Resources; Solow Residual; Work (JEL O39; alternate JEL O47) In the 1950's, it was discovered that the growth in capital stock could only account for a small fraction (about one eighth) of the historical US growth in economic output per worker (Moses Abramovitz 1952, 1956; Solomon Fabricant 1954). Economic growth theory was subsequently formulated in its current production function form by Robert Solow and Trevor Swan (Robert M. Solow 1956, 1957; Trevor Swan 1956). The theory assumes that production
  • 2. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 2 of goods and services (in monetary terms) can be expressed as a function of capital and labor. But the major contribution to growth had to be attributed to something else, namely “technological progress”or just “technical progress”. Absent any fundamental economic theory of technical progress, or any convincing independent measure of it, technical progress has been treated as an unexplained residual. This is another way of saying that it is an exogenous multiplier, either of labor or capital or both equally (i.e. of the whole production function, usually taken to be Cobb-Douglas or CES in form). As it happens, however, the Solow model makes two fundamental predictions that do not correspond to historical experience over the last half century. One prediction is that the rate of growth of an economy will decline as the capital stock grows, due to declining marginal productivity of capital (and the need to replace depreciation). The other prediction (known as “convergence”) is that poor countries, with smaller capital stocks, will grow faster than rich countries. The most popular “fix” is to dispense with the notion that capital depreciates. Another way of putting it is to assume that decreasing marginal productivity of capital is compensated by another effect, namely increasing returns to knowledge, arising from positive externalities (“spillovers”). This notion, first incorporated in the standard theoretical framework by Romer (Paul M. Romer 1986), has prompted an explosion of so- called “endogenous growth” theories (e.g. Romer 1986, 1987, 1990; Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1988; Gene M. Grossman and Elhanen Helpman 1991; Philippe Aghion and Peter Howitt 1998). There is a lot of interest among theorists, at present, in the phenomenon of increasing returns to scale (as exemplified by network systems of all kinds). Most of the recent endogenous growth theories are so-called A-K models, where K is generalized capital, defined to include knowledge and skills. The Solow multiplier A in these models is supposed to be a constant, independent of time. Labor no longer appears explicitly
  • 3. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 3 as a factor.1 It is interesting to note that Solow’s argument for choosing capital and labor productivities in the Cobb-Douglas production function (on the basis of shares in the national income accounts) no longer applies to the A-K theories. The major difficulty with the “new” endogenous growth theories is that there is no independent empirical basis for determining what the generalized capital K should be. In this paper we reconsider the possible role of resource inputs as factors of production, and whether this approach offers a possible alternative to the AK theories mentioned above. I. THE ROLE OF NATURAL RESOURCES The possible contribution of natural resource inputs to growth (or to technical progress), was not considered seriously by most economists until the 1970's (mainly in response to the Club of Rome and “Limits to Growth” (Donella H. Meadows et al 1972)). The primary focus of the early economic responses to “Limits” was on the problem of resource exhaustion (e.g. Partha Dasgupta and Geoffrey Heal 1974; Solow 1974; Joseph Stiglitz 1974). Despite the very small share of national income that could reasonably be attributed to resources, some economists, notably Jorgenson and his colleagues, introduced transcendental logarithmic production functions and multi-sector (KLEMS) models with capital, labor, energy and materials as factors (Dale W. Jorgenson et al 1973). Jorgenson subsequently tried to calculate factor productivities empirically in a large multi-sector model (Jorgenson 1984). The results were not sufficiently unambiguous to prompt many imitators. In most more recent large model applications resource consumption has been implicitly treated as a consequence of growth and not as a factor of production. This simplistic. and
  • 4. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 4 questionable assumption is built into most of the large-scale models used for policy guidance by governments. An important “engine of growth” since the first industrial revolution has been the continuously declining real price of physical resources, especially energy (and power) delivered at a point of use.2 The increasing availability of energy from fossil fuels, and power from heat engines, has clearly played a fundamental role in growth. Machines powered by fossil energy have gradually displaced animals, wind power, water power and human muscles and thus made human workers vastly more productive than they would otherwise have been. The term energy as used above, and in most discussions (including the economics literature) is technically incorrect, since energy is conserved and therefore cannot be “used up”. The correct term in this context is exergy3, which is sometimes called “available energy” or “useful energy”.We use this term hereafter because of its generality. The generic exergy-power feedback cycle works as follows. Technological progress such as discoveries, inventions, economies of scale, and accumulated experience – or learning-by-doing – result in cheaper exergy and power at the point of use. Moreover, inventions (such as the steam engine) enable the substitution of machines for human or animal muscles, thus delivering more power at lower cost. This, in turn, enables tangible goods and intangible services to be produced and delivered to consumers at ever lower prices. Factories and mines also benefit from these price reductions. Lower consumer prices encourage higher demand, thanks to price elasticity of demand. Since demand for final goods and services (including investment) necessarily corresponds to the sum of factor payments, most of which go back to labor as wages and salaries, it follows that wages of labor tend to increase as output rises.4 This, in turn, stimulates the further substitution of fossil exergy and mechanical lower for human (and
  • 5. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 5 animal) labor, resulting in further increases in scale, etc. and still lower costs. In modern times the use of electric power has been particularly productive, not least because it has stimulated the development of so many new industries. Based on both qualitative and quantitative evidence, the existence of the positive feedback cycle sketched above implies that physical resource (exergy) flows are a major factor of production. This observation has tempted many economists to try to quantify the relationship. Indeed, including a fossil exergy flow proxy in a 3 (or 4) factor Cobb-Douglas or similar production function has apparently successfully accounted for economic growth quite accurately, at least for limited time periods, without any exogenous time-dependent term. Examples of such studies include (Bruce M. Hannon and John Joyce 1981; Reiner Kümmel 1982; Cutler Cleveland et al 1984; Kümmel et al 1985; Cleveland 1992; Robert K. Kaufmann 1992; Bernard C. Beaudreau 1998; Cleveland et al 2000; Kümmel et al 2000). However, even a high degree of correlation (exhibited by some of these studies) does not necessarily imply causation. In other words, the fact that economic growth tends to be very closely correlated with energy or exergy consumption for some period of time – a fact demonstrated in numerous studies – does not a priori mean that energy (or exergy) consumption is the cause of the growth. Indeed, most economic models assume the opposite: that economic growth is responsible for increasing energy consumption. This automatically guarantees correlation. It is also conceivable that both consumption and growth are simultaneously caused by some third factor. The direction of causality must evidently be determined empirically by other means.5 A deeper question is: why should capital services be treated as a “factor of production” while the role of energy (exergy) services – not to mention other environmental services – is neglected or minimized? The naive view would seem to be that the two factors
  • 6. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 6 should be treated much the same way. Yet, among many theorists, strong doubts remain. It appears that there are two reasons. The first and most important is that national accounts are set up to reflect payments to labor (wages, salaries) and capital owners (rents, royalties, interest, dividends). In fact, GNP is the sum of all such payments and NNP is the sum of all such payments to individuals. There is no category for payments to resources. If labor and capital are the only two factors, neoclassical theory implies that the productivity of a factor of production must be proportional to the share of that factor in the national income. This proposition is quite easy to prove in a hypothetical single sector economy consisting of a large number of producers manufacturing a single good using only labor and capital services (as taught in elementary economics texts.) Moreover, the supposed link between factor payments and factor productivities gives the national accounts a fundamental role in production theory. This is intuitively very attractive. Labor gets the lion’s share of payments in the US national accounts, around 70 percent. Capital (defined as interest, dividends, rents and royalties) gets all of the rest. The figures vary slightly from year to year, but they have been relatively stable for the past century or more. Land rents are negligible. Payments for fossil fuels (even in “finished” form, including electric power) altogether amount to only a few percent of the total GDP. It follows, according to the received theory, that energy (exergy) is not a significant factor of production, or that it can be subsumed in capital, and can be safely ignored. However, there is a flaw in this argument. Suppose there exists an unpaid factor, e.g. environmental services. Since there are few economic agents (persons or firms) who receive income in exchange for providing or protecting environmental services, there are no explicit payments for such services in the national accounts. Absent such payments, it would seem to follow from the logic of the preceding two paragraphs that environmental services are not
  • 7. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 7 scarce or not economically productive. This implication pervades neoclassical economic theory. But it seems quite unreasonable to argue that environmental services are unproductive, given their central role in agriculture and forestry not to mention providing the welfare benefits of equable climate, fresh water, clean air, waste disposal and so forth. True, there are no markets for these services, but that is primarily due to indivisibility and lack of property rights. Free goods can still be scarce Just as environmental assets and services may be underpriced, so may exergy and exergy services. Many environmental economists note to the enormous direct and (mostly) indirect subsidies to energy use, especially in the US. Motor vehicles are the most obvious case-in-point. Motor vehicles create very large public costs, not only for highway construction and maintenance, but from air pollution damage, from uninsured accidents, from the military expenditures to protect the sea-routes from the Middle East and by the removal of large urban land areas from other public or private uses. Many studies have been done to quantify these costs, but the point is that if these damage costs were added to the price of petroleum products, as theory suggests, the price of fuel would soar – and the petroleum share of national income would soar also. There is little doubt that all fossil fuels, as well as nuclear energy, are significantly underpriced. This suggests that the energy share of the national accounts could be too small by a factor of two or three, or even more. Quite apart from the question of under-pricing, there is another reason why factor payments directly attributable to consumption of physical resources – especially exergy – are much smaller than the real productivity of exergy to the economy. In reality, the economy is not a single sector producing a single good – say, bread – from capital and labor.6 On the contrary it is a complex network of interacting sectors. Most sectors produce products (or services) by adding value to inputs purchased directly from other sectors.
  • 8. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 8 In the simple single sector model used to “prove” the neoclassical relationship between factor productivity and factor payments, this crucial fact is disregarded, resulting in a major distortion. If the economy were a one-sector model with only one product and one sort of producer (e.g. bakers of bread), the payments to each factor input would indeed reflect the marginal productivity of that factor. In a multi-sector economy, however most sectors buy from others (and sell to others), whence purchased intermediates constitute a significant share of the factors of production for each sector. Only the extractive sectors consume raw materials (exergy) extracted directly from nature. The intermediate sectors utilize labor and capital plus semi-finished materials and products, plus utilities (water, gas, electricity) and a variety of services (finance, insurance, transport, etc.). The intermediates are, in effect, “processed exergy”. If each sector is considered as a producer, with its own production function, its factors of production necessarily include exergy consumed in the production of purchased intermediate goods, including utilities and services. Allowing for the exergy transmitted via intermediates, the simple picture derived from the 1-sector model changes completely. Whereas, exergy extracted from nature accounts for a very small share of the national income directly, “processed exergy” can (and does) contribute a much larger effective share of the value of aggregate production, indirectly (Robert U. Ayres 2001). So much for the anomalously small share of exergy in the national accounts or (looking at it the other way) the anomalously large share of exergy as a factor of production and driver of growth.
  • 9. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 9 II. PRODUCTION FUNCTIONS It is now convenient to postulate two possible relationships of the form: (1a) Y = fEgEE or Y = fBgBB (1b) Y = gEUE or Y = gBUB where Y is GDP, measured in dollars, E is a measure of commercial energy (mainly fossil fuels), B is a measure of all “raw” physical resource inputs (technically, exergy), including fuels, minerals and agricultural and forest products. Then f is the ratio of “useful work” U done by the economy as a whole to “raw” exergy input (defined below), and g is the ratio of economic output in value terms to work input. All the variables have implicit subscripts B or E, depending on whether or not we are considering only standard measures of energy (E) or total exergy (B). We neglect the subscripts hereafter where the choice is obvious. Since work appears implicitly in both numerator and denominator of (1), its definition depends on whether we choose B or E. (Note that equation (1 a,b) is merely a definition of the factors f, g. There is no theory or approximation involved). However we note that the expressions (1a) or (1b) can be interpreted as a production function in either of two cases. The first possibility is that E or B is a factor of production and the product fE gE or fBgB can be approximated by some first order homogeneous function of the three factors: labor L , capital K and energy consumption E or exergy consumption B. The second possibility is that work U is a factor of production (instead of E or B) and the function g can be expressed
  • 10. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 10 approximately by some first order homogeneous function of K, L and U. (Subscripts omitted.) We test these possibilities empirically hereafter. The traditional variables capital K, and labor L, as usually defined for purposes of economic analysis, are plotted along with commerical energy (fossil fuels plus hydro and nuclear power) in Figure 1a from 1900 to 1998; deflated GDP and a traditional Cobb- Douglas production function of K,L,E are shown in Figure 1b. It is important to note that GDP increases faster than any of the three contributory factors or (by extension) any first order homogeneous function of them. The need for a time-dependent factor representing technical progress (the Solow residual) is evident. It is plotted in the figure. The ratio E/GDP is the so-called Kuznets curve. It is often observed that, for many industrialized countries, the E/GDP (or E/Y) ratio appears to have a characteristic inverted “U-shape”, at least if E is restricted to commercial fuels. (Not to be confused with our variable U). However, when the exergy embodied in firewood is included the supposedly characteristic inverted U-shape is much less pronounced. When non-fuel and mineral resources, especially agricultural phytomass are included, fuel exergy E is replaced by total exergy B, and the inverted U form is no longer evident. Figure 2 shows the various exergy inputs, plotted from 1900 to 1998. Figure 3 displays the three versions of the Kuznets curve. The top curve is the classical version, namely the ratio of commercial (mostly fossil fuel) exergy to GDP. The middle curve is the ratio of all fuels, including firewood, to GDP. The peak is still visible but much less pronounced. The third and lowest curve is the ratio of total exergy inputs, including non-fuel exergy, especially agricultural phytomass, to GDP. The pronounced inverted U in the top curve apparently reflects the substitution of commercial fuels for non-commercial fuels (wood) during early stages of industrialization.
  • 11. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 11 III. CALCULATION OF PHYSICAL WORK As noted earlier, the technical definition of exergy is the maximum work that a system can do as it approaches thermodynamic equilibrium (reversibly) with its surroundings. It is also measured in energy units. Not surprisingly, exergy values are very nearly the same as enthalpy (heat values) for ordinary fuels. So, what most people mean when they speak of “energy”, is really “exergy, except that exergy is also definable for non-fuel materials. We have done the appropriate calculations in detail in other publications.) However, technically, exergy is also equal to maximum potential work. For non- engineers, mechanical work can be exemplified in a variety of ways, such as pulling a plow, lifting a weight against gravity or compressing a fluid. The term horsepower was introduced in the context of horses pumping water from flooded 18th century British coal or tin mines. A more general definition of work is movement against a potential gradient (or resistance) of some sort. A heat engine is a mechanical device to perform work from heat, though not all work is performed by engines as we will point out later. With this in mind, we can subdivide work into three broad categories, namely work done by animal (or human) muscles7, work done by heat engines (i.e. mechanical work) and work done in other ways (e.g. thermal or chemical work). Mechanical work can be further subdivided into work done to generate electric power and work done to provide motive power (e.g. to drive motor vehicles.) The power sources in both cases are called “prime movers”, including all kinds of internal and external combustion engines, from steam turbines to jet engines. So called “renewables”, including hydraulic, nuclear, wind and solar power sources for electric power generation are conventionally included in energy statistics. Electricity can be thought of as “pure” work, since it can be
  • 12. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 12 reconverted back into mechanical work, chemical work or thermal work with little or no loss. However electric motors are not prime movers, because electricity is generated by a prior prime mover, usually a steam or gas turbine. Chemical work is exemplified by the reduction of metal ores to obtain the pure metal, or indeed any endothermic (heat consuming) chemical process, such as ammonia synthesis. Thermal work is exemplified by the transfer of heat from its point of origin (e.g. a furnace in the basement) to its point of use, such as a living-room, via a heat-exchanger (e.g. a radiator). So much for definitions. To measure the work done U, by the economy as a whole, it is helpful to classify fuels by use. The first use-category is fuel used by prime movers to do mechanical work. This consists of fuel used by electric power generation equipment and fuel used by mobile power sources such as motor vehicles, aircraft and so on. As regards mobile power sources, we choose to define efficiency in terms of the whole vehicle, not just the engine itself. Thus the efficiency of an automobile is the ratio of work done by the wheels on the road to the total potential work (exergy content) of the fuel. Data are available on fuel consumed by electric power generating plants (known as the “heat rate”) but the work output is also measured directly as kilowatt hours of electric power produced. The second broad category is fuel used to generate heat as such, either for industry (process heat to do chemical work) or space heat and domestic uses such as washing and cooking. Lighting can be thought of as third category, which is almost a special case. So far we have only considered exergy inputs. The inputs for animal work are, of course, feedstuffs. Horses and mules, which accounted for most animal work on US farms and urban transport, have not changed biologically since their heyday. The efficiency with which animals convert feed energy to work is generally reckoned at about 4 percent. The uncertainty is unimportant for our purposes.
  • 13. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 13 The agricultural phytomass that is converted into human food (as well as petfood, cotton, tobacco, and soap) contribute to the economy in the same way as other industrial materials. The recent phytomass-to-food conversion efficiency for North America (via meat, eggs and milk) has been estimated as 5.5 percent (Stefan Wirsenius 2000). In 1900 a significant share – about 20 percent – went to feed horses and mules, but as people consume ever more animal products, the efficiency of conversion is unlikely to be increasing. On the other hand, the efficiency of heat engines, domestic and commercial heating systems and industrial thermal processes has changed significantly over the past 100 years. We have plotted these increasing conversion efficiencies, from 1900 to 1998 in Figure 4. (Detailed derivations of these curves can be found in another publication (Ayres et al 2002)). Work by horses and mules (mostly on farms) has been estimated from the work/feed ratio, together with the horse-mule population. Exergy allocations to different categories of work are shown in Figure 5. Animal work was still significant in 1900 but mechanical and electrical work have since become far more important. Electrification has been perhaps the single most important source of work and (as will be seen later) the most powerful driver of economic growth. Electrical work need not be computed from fuel inputs, since it is measured directly in kilowatt-hours (kwh) generated. The fuel required to generate a kilowatt-hour of electric power has decreased by a factor of nine during the past century. On the other hand, the consumption of electricity in the US has increased over the same period by a factor of more than 1300, as shown in Figure 6. (This exemplifies the positive feedback economic “growth engine” discussed earlier.) Effectively there are two definitions of work to be considered hereafter, namely
  • 14. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 14 (2a) UB = fBB (2b) UE = fEE The ratios fB and fE are, effectively, composite conversion efficiencies. The former takes into account animal work and all agricultural products, including animal feed. The latter neglects animal work and also agricultural production. These two efficiency trends are plotted from 1900 to 1998 in Figure 7. It seems likely that, if the trend in f is fairly steadily upward throughout a long period (such as a century) it would seem reasonably safe to project this trend curve into the future for some decades. The trends in physical work done by the economy, together with the ratio of physical work to deflated GDP, are shown in Figure 8. The total quantity of physical work inputs into the economy rise steadily over the entire period and it seems likely that they will continue increasing at a similar rate. Surprisingly, however, the slope of the ratio of work input to GDP changes dramatically around 1970. Prior to this date the GDP output per unit of work input was decreasing. After this date the trend unaccountably reversed. We think it important to note that this could not be the result of a business cycle or any other short-term phenomenon. IV. ELIMINATING THE SOLOW RESIDUAL: A NEARLY ENDOGENOUS PRODUCTION FUNCTION There are two important conditions to be satisfied for either version of the expression (1a,b) to be a production function. One of them is the Euler condition for constant returns to scale, which means that for (1a) to be a production function the product fg (subscripts
  • 15. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 15 omitted) must be a homogeneous first order function of three independent variables, K,L,E or K,L,B. Similarly for (1b) to be a production function g must be a function of K,L,UE, or K,L,UB . The other condition is that the marginal productivities of the three factors be non- negative at all times, at least over a rolling average. (The marginal productivities, logarithmic derivatives of output with respect to each of the factors, need not be constant in time. In fact there is no theoretical reason why marginal productivities should be constant.) It is already evident from Figure 1 that the Cobb-Douglas function cannot explain US economic growth since 1900. Of course Cobb-Douglas is the special case with constant productivities. Of course, there are other functional forms combining the factors K, L, E (orB) that do permit variable marginal productivities and thus may provide slightly better fits than Cobb-Douglas, especially over moderate time periods. However, over the very long-term it is easy to show that the constant returns (Euler) condition rules out any function of K, L, E or K, L, B, since a homogeneous first order function cannot explain observed growth because such a function cannot increase faster than any of its arguments and none of the three arguments increases fast enough. In particular, exergy inputs – however defined – do not increase fast enough to compensate for the slow growth of labor and capital. Hence no such functional form can eliminate the need for a time dependent multiplier (Solow residual). This essentially rules out (1a) as a viable production function choice.8 We are left with (1b) and, of course, either (2a) or (2b). Over the long time period of our data base, we want to allow for the possibility of non-constant productivities. It happens that a convenient functional form (the so-called LINEX function) has been suggested by Kümmel (Kümmel 1982)9, namely (3) Y = A U exp{aL/U - b(U+L)/K}
  • 16. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 16 where A is a multiplier that should (in principle) be independent of time, while a, b are parameters to be determined econometrically. It can be verified without difficulty that this function satisfies the Euler condition for constant returns to scale. It can also be shown that the requirement of non-negative marginal productivities can be met. The three factor productivities are as follows: (4a) M lnY/M lnK = (MY/ MK)(K/Y) = b(L/K) > 0 (4b M lnY/M lnL = (MY/ML)(L/Y) = a(L/U) - b(L/K) > 0 (4c) M lnY/M lnU = (MY/MUE)(U/Y) = 1 - a(L/U) - b(U/K) > 0 It follows from straightforward algebra that the requirement of non-negativity is equivalent to the following three inequalities: (5a) b >0 (5b) a > b(U/K) (5c) 1 > a(L/U) + b(U/K) The variable U in the above expressions (4,5) can, of course be interpreted in either of the two ways indicated in (2) without affecting the results. The first condition (5a) is trivial. However the second and third conditions are not automatically satisfied for all possible
  • 17. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 17 values of the variables. It is therefore necessary to do the fitting by constrained non-linear optimization. The statistical procedures and quality measures are discussed in the Appendix. The two curves in Figure 9 show the LINEX fits, where we have tested both definitions of work UE and UB respectively as factors of production. The best fit is obtained by using UB, recalling that total exergy B includes all phytomass inputs and UB includes animal work. The unexplained residual has essentially disappeared, prior to 1975 and remains small thereafter. In short, “technical progress” as defined by the Solow residual is almost entirely explained by historical improvements in exergy conversion (to physical work), as summarized in Figure 4, at least until recent times. The remaining unexplained residual, amounting to roughly 12 percent of recent economic growth, is shown in Figure 10. The marginal productivities of the factors can be calculated directly from equations (4). The three marginal productivities for each of the two interesting cases are plotted in Figure 11a,b, respectively. The differences are surprisingly large, but the results for the best fit case appear much smoother and more reasonable. There is a small but noticeable directional shift that roughly coincides with the two so-called oil crises, and may well have been triggered by the spike in energy (exergy) prices that occurred at that time. The shift can be interpreted as a structural change in the economy, and conceivably, a change in the locus of technological progress from energy conversion efficiency towards systems optimization. However, interpretation of this shift – assuming it is real – will have to await further analysis. V. IMPLICATIONS: TOWARDS AN ENDOGENOUS GROWTH MODEL In the “standard” Solow model a forecast of GDP requires a forecast of labor L, capital stock K and a forecast of the technical change (or multi-factor productivity) multiplier
  • 18. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 18 A(t). Based on the results described above, the technical progress term can be decomposed into contributions from improved exergy conversion-to-(primary) work efficiency and “other”. The years 1972 marked a distinct “turning point” in the economic history of the US. Prior to those years the marginal increase per unit of primary work input was generally falling; a kind of saturation phenomenon. After 1972, the trend was reversed. Figure 8 expresses this behaviour in terms of primary work/GDP10. Evidently growth of GDP since 1972 has slightly outstripped growth of the three input factors, capital (K), labor (L) and physical work (U). Clearly primary physical work is still by far the dominant driver of growth. However, this does not mean that human labor or capital are unimportant. The three factors are not really independent of each other. Increasing exergy conversion efficiency requires investments of capital and labor, while the creation of capital is highly dependent on the productivity of physical work. An additional source of value added is involved. Part of the missing source of value added may have been due to improvements in the efficiency of “secondary work” or work done by electricity. Improvements in the efficiency of electric lighting, electric motors, refrigeration, electrolytic processes and so forth have occurred since 1972, but are not reflected in our efficiency curves (Figure 4). However, preliminary analysis suggests that these efficiency improvements are not sufficient to account for the “extra” growth since 1972 or so. In the spirit of some endogenous growth theories, it would be possible to interpret this additional productivity to some qualitative improvement in either capital or labor. It is tempting to argue that the observed shift starting in the 1970's reflects the growing influence of information technology. Certainly large scale systems optimization depends very strongly on large data bases and information processing capability. The airline reservation systems now in use have achieved significant operational economies and productivity gains for
  • 19. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 19 airlines by increasing capacity utilization. Manufacturing firms have achieved comparable gains through computerized integration of different functions. We cannot, however, offer any econometric confirmation of these conjectures. One of the more important implications of results we have reported in this paper is that some of the most dramatic and visible technological changes of the past century have apparently not contributed significantly to overall economic growth. An example in point is medical progress. While infant mortality has declined dramatically and life expectancy has increased very significantly since 1900, it its hard to see any direct impact on economic growth, at least up to the 1970's. Greater life expectancy (beyond the age of 60) has added little to labor productivity, and may actually decrease it. (However, it is possible that some of the GDP gains since 1970 can be attributed to increased expenditure on health services.) The gain from medical progress in recent decades, at least, has been primarily in quality of life, not quantity of output. Changes in telecommunications technology since 1900 may constitute another example. Faster communication has clearly generated more communication – a kind or rebound effect – but it is not clear that greater efficiency has resulted. (The examples of fax and email are instructive in this regard.) New service industries, like moving pictures, radio and TV have been created, but if the net result is new forms of entertainment, the gains in employment and output may have come largely at the expense of earlier forms of public news and entertainment, such as the print media, live theater, circuses and vaudeville. While the changes have been spectacular, as measured in terms of information transmitted, the productivity gains may not have been especially large, at least until recently. Again, the net impact may have been primarily on quality of life.
  • 20. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 20 Turning to the problem of forecasting, since economic growth for the past century, at least up to 1980, can be explained with considerable accuracy by three factors, K, L, UB, it is not unreasonable to expect that future growth for some time to come will be explained quite well by these three variables, plus a growing contribution from IT. From a long-term sustainability viewpoint, this conclusion carries a powerful implication. If economic growth is to continue without proportional increases in exergy (especially fossil fuel) consumption, it is vitally important to use exergy ever more efficiently as well as to develop ways of reducing fossil fuel exergy inputs per unit of physical work output. But, as declining marginal returns to investment in R&D limits the future efficiency gains that can be expected – as saturation approaches – we must deliberately exploit new ways of generating value added without doing more physical work. In other words, energy (exergy) conservation is the main key to long term environmental sustainability. APPENDIX A For each definition of the LINEX function, the optimal parameters were obtained by using a quasi-Newton non-linear optimization method, with box-constraints. The constraints on the possible values of the parameters of the LINEX model were required to ensure that the factor marginal productivities were non-negative. To avoid the influence of local minima the starting values were selected iteratively. A statistical measure of the precision of fit was provided by the Mean Square Error, (A1) MSE = [ t=1 3n (e2 )] '(n - k)
  • 21. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 21 The MSE is a measure of the absolute deviation of the theoretical fit from the empirical curve, where n is the number of samples, k the number of parameters and e the residual from the fitted curve. We also calculated the correlation coefficients (r2) between log-transformed GDP and each log-transformed factor. We tested the significance of the correlations using a t- test with Welch modification for unequal variances (Table A1). The alternative hypothesis is that the true difference in the means is not equal to zero at a 95 percent confidence level. The results indicate that only fits with UE and UB are significant, and that of UB by far the most significant as indicated by the low estimated t-values. REFERENCES Abramovitz, Moses. “Economics of Growth,” Haley (ed), A survey of contemporary economics (Volume 2). New York: Richard D. Irwin, Inc, 1952, pp. 132-78. ______. “Resources and Output Trends in the United States since 1870.” American Economic Review, May 1956, 46. Aghion, Philippe and Howitt, Peter. Endogenous growth theory. Cambridge MA: The MIT Press, 1998. Ayres, Robert U. “The Minimum Complexity of Endogenous Growth Models: the Role of Physical Resource Flows.” Energy, September 2001, 26(9), pp. 817-38.
  • 22. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 22 Ayres, Robert. U; Ayres, Leslie W. and Warr, Benjamin. “Exergy, Power and Work in the US Economy, 1900-1998.” Energy, (Forthcoming, 2002). Barnett, Harold J. and Morse, Chandler. Scarcity and Growth: The Economics of Resource Scarcity, Baltimore MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1962. Beaudreau, Bernard C. Energy and Organization: Growth and Distribution Reexamined. Westwood CT, Greenwood Press, 1998. Cleveland, Cutler J. “Energy Quality and Energy Surplus in the Extraction of Fossil Fuels in the US.” Ecological Economics, 1992, 6, pp. 139-62. Cleveland, Cutler J.; Costanza, Robert; Hall, C. A. S. and Kaufmann, Robert K. “Energy and the US Economy: A Biophysical Perspective.” Science, 1984, 255, pp. 890-97. Cleveland, Cutler J.; Kaufmann, Robert K. and Stern, David I. “Aggregation and the Role of Energy in the Economy.” Ecological Economics, February 2000, 32(2), pp. 301-17. Dasgupta, Partha and Heal, Geoffrey. “The Optimal Depletion of Exhaustible Resources,” Symposium on the Economics of Exhaustible Resources, Review of Economic Studies, 1974. Domar, Evsey D. Essays in the Theory of Economic Growth, London: Oxford University Press, 1957.
  • 23. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 23 Fabricant, Solomon. “Economic Progress and Economic Change,” 34th Annual Report: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1954. Granger, C. W. J. “Investigating Causal Relations by Econometric Models and Cross- spectral Methods.” Econometrica, 1969, 37, pp. 424-38. Grossman, Gene M. and Helpman, Elhanen. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge MA: MIT Press, 1991. Hannon, Bruce M. and Joyce, John. “Energy and Technical Progress.” Energy, 1981, 6, pp. 187-95. Harrod, Roy F. Towards a Dynamic Economics (Out of Print), 1947. Jorgenson, Dale W. “The Role of Energy in Productivity Growth.” The Energy Journal, 1984, 5(3), pp. 11-26. Jorgenson, Dale W.; Christensen, Lauritz R. and Lau, Lawrence J. “Transcendental Logarithmic Production Frontiers.” Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1973, 55(1), pp. 28-45.
  • 24. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 24 Kaufmann, Robert K. “A Biophysical Analysis of the Energy/Real GDP Ratio: Implications for Substitution and Technical Change.” Ecological Economics,, 1992, 6, pp. 33-56. ______.“The Economic Multiplier of Envirnmental Life Support: Can Capital Substitute for a Degraded Environment?.” Ecological Economics , January 1995, 12(1), pp. 67-80. Kümmel, Reiner. “Energy, Environment and Industrial Growth,” Economic Theory of Natural Resources, Würzburg, Germany: Physica-Verlag, 1982. Kümmel, Reiner; Lindenberger, D. and Eichhorn, Wolfgang. “The Productive Power of Energy and Economic Evolution.” Indian Journal of Applied Economics, 2000, 8, pp. 231-62. Kümmel, Reiner; Strassl, Wolfgang; Gossner, Alfred and Eichhorn, Wolfgang. “Technical Progress and Energy Dependent Production Functions.” Journal of Economics, 1985, 45(3), pp. 285-311. Lucas, Robert E. Jr. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics, July 1988, 22(1), pp. 2-42. Mankiew, N. Gregory. Macroeconomics, Worth Publishing, 1997. Meadows, Donella H.; Meadows, Dennis L.; Randers, Jorgen and Behrens, William W. III. The Limits to Growth: A Report for the Club of Rome's Project on the Predicament of Mankind. New York: Universe Books, 1972.
  • 25. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 25 Potter, Neal and Christy, Francis T. Jr. Trends in Natural Resource Commodities, Baltimore MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1968 Romer, Paul M. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy, October 1990, 98(5), pp. S71-S102. ______. “Growth Based on Increasing Returns Due to Specialization.” American Economic Review, May 1987, 77(2), pp. 56-62. ______. “Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth.” Journal of Political Economy, October 1986, 94(5), pp. 1002-37. Sims, C. J. A. “Money, Income and Causality.” American Economic Review, 1972. Smith, H. “The Cumulative Energy Requirements of Some Final Products of the Chemical Industry.” Transactions of the World Energy Conference, 1969, p. 18(section E).
  • 26. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 26 Solow, Robert M. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1956, 70, pp. 65-94. ______. “Intergenerational Equity and Exhaustible Resources.” Review of Economic Studies, 1974, 41, pp. 29-45. ______. “Perspectives on Growth Theory.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Winter 1994, 8(1), pp. 45-54. ______. “Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function.” Review of Economics and Statistics, August 1957, 39, pp. 312-20. Stern, David I. “Energy Use and Economic Growth in the USA: a Multivariate Approach.” Energy Economics, 1993, 15, pp. 137-50. Stiglitz, Joseph. “Growth with Exhaustible Natural Resources. Efficient and Optimal Growth Paths.” Review of Economic Studies, 1974. Swan, Trevor. “Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation.” The Economic Record, 1956, 32(68), pp. 334-361. Wirsenius, Stefan. “Human Use of Organic Materials,” Doctoral Thesis, Gothenburg, Sweden: Chalmers Institute of Technology and Gothenburg University, 2000.
  • 27. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 27 FOOTNOTES * Robert U. Ayres Center for the Management of Environmental Resources INSEAD 77305 Fontainebleau, FRANCE Tel: 33 (0) 1 60 72 40 11 Fax: 33 (0) 1 60 74 55 64 Email: robert.ayres@insead.edu Benjamin Warr Center for the Management of Environmental Resources INSEAD 77305 Fontainebleau, FRANCE Tel: 33 (0) 1 60 72 41 28 Fax: 33 (0) 1 60 74 55 64 Email: benjamin.warr@insead.edu Research supported by Institute for Advanced Study, UN University, Tokyo and The European Commission, TERRA project. We thank Christian Azar, Jonathan Cave, Barry Hughes, Jens Jesinghaus, Yuichi Kaya, Reinhard Kümmel, Jeroen van den Bergh, Chihiro Watanabe, Eric Williams, and Ulrich Witt for helpful discussions and suggestions. All errors are our own.
  • 28. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 28 1. The new A-K models are essentially throwbacks to the pre-Solow Harrod-Domar growth models (Roy F. Harrod 1948; Evsey D. Domar 1957). 2. The tendency of virtually all raw material and fuel costs to decline over time (lumber was the main exception) has been thoroughly documented, especially by economists at Resources For the Future (RFF) (Harold J. Barnett and Chandler Morse 1962; Neal Potter and Francis T. Christy, Jr. 1968; H. Smith 1969). 3. The proper definition of exergy is the maximum work that can be done by a system as it approaches equilibrium with its surroundings. Thus delivered exergy is effectively equivalent to work. The distinction netween exergy and energy is theoretically important because energy is a conserved quantity (first law of thermodynamics). This means that energy is not “used up” in physical processes, merely transformed from available to less available forms, with concomitant entropy production. On the other hand, exergy is not conserved: it is used up. The directionality of all spontaneous transformations the direction of increasing entropy (second law of thermodynamics). 4. Marx believed (with some justification) that the gains would flow mainly to owners of capital rather than to workers. Political developments have changed the balance of power since Marx’s time. However, in either case, returns to energy or to physical resources tend to decline as output grows. This can be interpreted as declining real price.
  • 29. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 29 5. There are statistical approaches to addressing the causality issue. For instance, Granger and others have developed statistical tests that can provide some clues as to which is cause and which is effect (C. W. J. Granger 1969; C. J. A. Sims 1972). These tests have been applied to the question whether energy consumption is a cause or an effect of economic growth (David I. Stern 1993; Kaufmann 1995). In brief, the conclusions depend upon whether energy is measured in terms of heat value of all fuels (in which case the direction of causation is ambiguous) or whether the energy aggregate is adjusted to reflect the “quality” (or, more accurately, the price or productivity) of each fuel in the mix. In the latter case the econometric evidence seem to confirm that energy (exergy) consumption is a cause of growth. We comment on this result later. 6. See the discussion of national income allocation in N. Gregory Mankiew’s new economics textbook “Macroeconomics” (N. Gregory Mankiew 1997). 7. Human muscular work is insignificant by comparison with other sources of work, and we can neglect it as regards the US or any industrialized country. Human “labor” is something else entirely. It is a combination of sense-based supervision and coordination and brain work. 8. The so-called endogenous growth theory gets around this difficulty by relaxing the Euler condition and allowing positive returns. However, as Solow has remarked, this seemingly simple change implies that infinite growth can occur in a finite period of time (Solow 1994).
  • 30. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 30 9. Kümmel introduced the LINEX function with E as a variable, rather than U. 10. This is analogous to the so-called Kuznets (inverted U) curve for E/GDP shown in Figure 3 (upper curve).
  • 31. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 31 Table A1. Statistical measures of the quality and significance of fitted models Variable t-value Degrees of p-value Correlation used freedom coefficient (r2) B 5.74 158.4 4.5e-08 0.98 E 3.09 174.3 0.002 0.97 UE 0.51 194.8 0.604 0.99 UB 0.19 195.9 0.845 0.99
  • 32. Ayres and Warr Accounting for growth Page 32 FIGURE HEADINGS Figure 1a. Traditional factors of production K, L, E, USA 1900-1998 Figure 1b. Cobb Douglas production function and Solow Residual, USA 1900-1998 Figure 2. Exergy inputs, USA 1900-1998 Figure 3. The ratio of exergy inputs to GDP, USA 1900-1998 Figure 4. Energy (exergy) conversion efficiencies, USA 1900-1998 Figure 5. Allocation of exergy by types of work, USA 1900-1998 Figure 6. Electricity production and conversion efficiency Figure 7. Exergy conversion efficiency f, for two definitions of work and exergy, USA 1900- 1998 Figure 8. Primary work and the primary work/GDP ratio, USA 1900-1998 Figure 9. LINEX production function fits with different ‘energy’ factor inputs, USA 1900- 1998 Figure 10. The percentage of observed growth unexplained by the LINEX fit with ‘work’ (UB) Figure 11a. Marginal productivities (elasticities) of each factor of production using UE in LINEX, USA 1900-1998 Figure 11b. Marginal productivities (elasticities) of each factor of production using UB in LINEX, USA 1900-1998
  • 33. 12 K L E 10 standardised value (1900 = 1) 8 6 4 2 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 year
  • 34. 20 Y GDP (actual) Y = Ka Lb Eg A(t), Solow Residual a = 0.28 b = 0.68 15 g = 0.04 MSE = 28 estimates 10 5 0 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 year Base Year 1900 = 1992 $ 354 billion
  • 35. 100 TOTAL FOSSIL FUEL PHYTOMASS 90 OTHER MINERALS & METALS RENEWABLES 80 70 60 eJ 50 40 30 20 10 0 1908 1918 1928 1938 1948 1958 1968 1978 1988 1998 year
  • 36. 1.6 TOTAL EXERGY (incl. Phytomass) / GDP RATIO TOTAL EXERGY (excl. Phytomass) / 1.4 GDP RATIO FOSSIL FUEL EXERGY / GDP RATIO 1.2 1 Great ratio Depression 0.8 WW I 0.6 0.4 WW II Peak US 0.2 Domestic Petroleum Production 0 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 year
  • 37. 40% High Temperature Industrial Heat 35% Medium Temperature Industrial Heat Low Temperature Space Heat 30% Electric Power Generation and Distribution Other Mechanical 25% Work Fraction (%) 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 year
  • 38. 90% HEAT LIGHT 80% ELECTRICITY OTHER PRIME 70% MOVERS NON-FUEL 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1908 1918 1928 1938 1948 1958 1968 1978 1988 1998 year
  • 39. 40% 800 % Electric Power Generation and Distribution (left scale) 35% Index of Electricity Production (right scale) 700 30% 600 index of output (1900=5000 gWh) 25% 500 efficiency 20% 400 15% 300 10% 200 5% 100 0% 0 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 year
  • 40. 0.30 calculated using B and UB calculated using E and Ue 0.25 0.20 ratio 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 1908 1918 1928 1938 1948 1958 1968 1978 1988 1998 year
  • 41. 40 2.5 Primary work (left scale) 35 Primary work / GDP ratio (right) 2.0 30 25 1.5 Exergy (eJ) ratio 20 1.0 15 10 0.5 5 0 0.0 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 year
  • 42. 20 empirical GDP Theoretical estimates: using UE - MSE = 52 15 using UB - MSE = 7 GDP (1992$) 10 5 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 year
  • 43. 12 10 8 % of growth 6 4 2 0 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 year
  • 44. 1.0 Capital - K Labor - L Work – UE 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 year
  • 45. 1.0 Capital - K Labor - L Work - UB 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 year