SlideShare una empresa de Scribd logo
1 de 179
AC210: Corporate Finance
Norvald Instefjord
ninstef@essex.ac.uk
5NW.4.9
Introduction to Corporate Finance
• What is finance?
• What is the distinction between financial
and real assets?
• What is corporate finance?
• What is the role of financial assets in
corporate finance?
Week 1
Financial Markets and Financial
Instruments
• How do firms finance their investments?
– Earnings (free cash flow, internal capital)
– Equity capital (external – public or private)
– Debt capital (external)
• Public and private capital
• Trading of public capital
– New issues
– Secondary trading
Equity Issues
• First time a firm seeks public equity is
called an initial public offering (IPO)
– Primary issue: new equity is issued
– Secondary issue: existing private equity is
sold to outside investors (most privatisations
take this form)
– Legal and underwriting services provided by
investment banks
Debt Issues
• Bank loans – not publicly traded
• Corporate Bonds – traded actively in the
secondary market
• Debt capital and equity capital account for
most of the firm’s financial capital
Definition of Debt
• Fixed claim
– Specifies what needs to be repaid to the
investor and when
– Default risk – risk that the repayment plan is
not fulfilled
– Conversion options – covenants that allow
debt to be reclassified as equity
Definition of Equity
• Residual claim
– Does not specify a repayment plan
– Repayment is defined as the residual:
whatever is not claimed by other claim
holders should go to the equity holders
– Voting rights: Equity holders normally have a
right to vote on important corporate decisions
• Mergers, takeovers
• Large investments
• Board representation
Trends in Corporate Finance
• Globalisation
• Deregulation
• Financial innovation
• Technological advances in the financial
system
• Securitization
What you should take home
• You should be able to
– Understand the distinction between a fixed claim and
a residual claim
– List the main attributes of a debt claim
– List the main attributes of an equity claim
– Describe the ways in which firms raise funds for new
investment
– Describe the difference between private and public
equity
– Describe the difference between bank loans and
corporate bonds
Readings
• Grinblatt/Titman: Financial Markets and
Corporate Strategy
– Ch 1: overview of the process of raising
capital for investment
– Ch 2: overview of the process of raising debt
capital
– Ch 3: overview of the process of raising equity
capital
Problems
1. Why do firms use underwriters when
they issue new equity?
2. In what ways do you think it matters that
debt holders have a fixed claim when
equity holders have not?
3. In what ways do you think it matters that
equity holders have voting rights when
debt holders have not?
Review problems
1. Invest 95 and sell for 102 – what is the return?
2. Invest 95 and sell for 102. Each transaction is charged
a 1% trading commission – what is the return?
3. Invest 95 and sell for 102. You receive additional
interest payments/dividends of 2 during the holding
period. What is the return?
4. Invest 95 and sell for 110 three years later – what is
the annual return on your investment?
5. Invest 95 now and another 98 next year. In the
following year you sell your investment for a total of
202. What is the annual return on your investment?
Week 2:
Valuing Financial Assets: Portfolio
Tools
• Tool box
– Expected portfolio return
– Portfolio variance
– Covariance between the return on two assets
• Optimal investment
– “Fair” price of an asset means that the value equals
the purchasing price
– Even if prices are “fair” there are still ways of
investing your money that is better than others
• Risk Aversion
– Investors demand compensation for including risk in
their portfolio
Portfolio weights
• A portfolio of financial assets can be represented
in a number of ways
– The number of shares held in the various stocks (e.g.
1000 shares in BT, 250 shares in Marks&Spencer
etc.)
– The dollar-value held in the various stocks (e.g.
£2,500 in Lloyds Bank, £10,000 in Jarvis etc.)
– As portfolio weights: the dollar-weight of the various
stocks (e.g. if total portfolio is £100,000, then the
portfolio weight of Lloyds is 0.025 and the portfolio
weight of Jarvis is 0.1 etc.)
From portfolio weights to portfolio
expected return and variance
• To determine the expected return and
variance of a portfolio we need to know
– The portfolio weights
– The expected return on the individual assets
– The variance of the return on the individual
assets
– The covariance between the return on any
pair of assets
Expectation, Variance and
Covariance
• Expected return (“average” return) is a location
measure
• Variance of return is a spread measure
• Covariance is a measure of how the return of
two assets are “related” (they can move in the
same or opposite directions, or they can be
uncorrelated)
• If the returns move in the same directions,
covariance is positive, if the returns move in the
opposite directions, covariance is negative, and
if uncorrelated, covariance is zero
The input data for a portfolio
of N assets
• N expected returns
• N variances
• N(N-1)/2 covariances
• Plus N portfolio weights
• For FTSE100 there are therefore
100+100+100(99)/2 = 5150 data points that
need to be estimated even before working out
the portfolio weights
Formulas
 


 







N
i j
i
j
i
j
i
i
i
P
N
i
N
j j
i
j
i
P
N
i
i
i
P
r
r
Cov
w
w
r
Var
w
r
Var
r
r
Cov
w
w
r
Var
r
E
w
r
E
1
2
1
1
1
)
,
(
2
)
(
)
(
)
,
(
)
(
)
(
)
(
Covariance and Correlation
• Covariance is a measure of relatedness
that depends on the unit of measurement,
so if the return is measured as a percent
(e.g. 10 percent) or as a desimal (e.g.
0.10) the covariance will be different
• Correlation is a measure of relatedness
that is normalized to be independent of the
unit of measurement
Covariance and Correlation
j
i
j
i
ij
j
i
ij
j
i
ij
j
i
r
r
Cov
n
Correlatio
r
Var
r
Var
r
r
Cov







)
,
(
)
(
)
(
)
,
(




The Mean-Standard Deviation
Approach to Investment
• Risk averse investors don’t like risk
• Variance averse investors don’t like risk that comes as
variance
• This is not the same in general – variance aversion is a
special case of risk aversion
• Portfolio theory takes the variance aversion approach –
which in practice means that we assume investors wish
to maximize their expected return given a certain
variance, or minimize their variance given a certain
expected return
Mean-Standard Deviation
for Two-Asset Investments
)
,
(
)
1
(
2
)
(
)
1
(
)
(
)
(
)
(
)
1
(
)
(
)
(
2
1
2
2
1
2
2
1
r
r
Cov
w
w
r
Var
w
r
Var
w
r
Var
r
E
w
r
wE
r
E
P
P








Portfolio Frontier
Mean-Std Dev for Portfolios of the
Risk Free Asset and a Risky Asset
w
r
Var
r
Var
w
r
Var
r
r
E
w
r
r
w
r
wE
r
E
P
F
F
F
P
)
(
)
(
)
(
)
)
(
(
)
1
(
)
(
)
(
2








Covariance as Marginal Variance
• We can interpret the covariance between
the return on a stock and the return on a
portfolio as the stock’s marginal variance
• That is, if we increase the stock’s portfolio
weight marginally, the portfolio variance
will increase by approximately twice the
stock’s covariance with the portfolio
Algebraic “proof”
)
,
(
2
)
(
)
,
(
2
)
(
2
)
(
)
,
(
2
)
(
)
(
)
(
)
)
(
(
)
(
)
(
)
(
0
2
i
P
m
i
P
i
i
P
i
P
F
i
P
F
i
P
F
i
P
r
r
Cov
dm
r
dVar
r
r
Cov
r
mVar
dm
r
dVar
r
r
mCov
r
Var
m
r
Var
r
Var
r
r
E
m
r
E
r
E
r
r
m
r
mr
mr
r
r
















What to take home
• Understanding of expected values, variances,
and covariances
• Understanding of expected return and variance
for a portfolio
• Understanding of risk aversion and variance
aversion
• Understanding of the portfolio frontier
• Appreciation of the linearity of expected return
and standard deviation for portfolios consisting
of the risk free asset and a risky portfolio
Readings
• Chapter 4 in Grinblatt/Titman
Problems
1. Variance: Prove that E(x-E(x))2=Ex2-
(E(x))2
2. Covariance: Prove that E(x-E(x))(y-
E(y))=Exy-E(x)E(y)
3. Take a time series of returns 0.05, -0.03,
0.10, 0.04, -0.10, 0.20. Estimate the
expected return and the variance of
return.
Week 3:
From Mean-Variance to the CAPM
• Capital Market Line
– Finding the market portfolio
• Two-fund Separation
– Optimal diversification
– Market vs idiosyncratic risk
• CAPM expected returns relationship
– Expected return on assets depend on their
covariance (i.e. their relatedness) with the market
portfolio
– Estimating beta risk
Capital Market Line
• The line that goes through the risk free
asset and the tangency portfolio
• Identification?
– Maximization procedure
– Simplifying “trick”, the excess return on any
asset divided by its covariance with the
tangency portfolio, is constant
Maximization programme to find
the Capital Market Line
• We can identify the frontier portfolios of
risky assets
• Consider investments consisting of the risk
free asset and a frontier portfolio – these
are represented by straight lines
• For the frontier portfolio that is the
tangency portfolio, the angle of the straight
line is the steepest
Capital Market Line cont..
)
(
)
)
(
(
))
(
)
(
(
max
)
(
)
1
(
)
,
(
)
1
(
2
)
(
)
(
)
(
)
1
(
)
(
)
(
)
(
)
(
max
2
2
T
F
B
B
A
w
B
B
A
A
T
B
A
T
T
F
T
w
r
Var
r
r
E
r
E
r
E
w
r
Var
w
r
r
Cov
w
w
r
Var
w
r
Var
r
E
w
r
wE
r
E
r
Var
r
r
E












Capital Market Line cont..
• The maximization programme normally
leads to a fairly complicated equation –
with two risky assets we get a quadratic
equation to solve
• In the class exercises you will be asked to
have a go at such a problem
Simplifying “trick”: finding the
Capital Market Line
• We know the expected return on all risky
assets and the risk free return
• The difference between the two is called
the “excess return” for the asset
• The excess return, divided by its
covariance with the tangency portfolio, is
always constant
Capital Market Line
F
N
N
N
N
F
N
N
F
N
N
F
i
T
i
i
N
N
i
i
i
i
T
i
r
r
E
r
Var
w
r
r
Cov
w
r
r
E
r
r
Cov
w
r
r
Cov
w
r
r
E
r
r
Cov
w
r
Var
w
r
r
E
r
r
Cov
r
r
Cov
w
r
Var
w
r
r
Cov
w
r
r
Cov
w
r
r
Cov




















)
(
)
(
)
,
(
)
(
)
,
(
)
,
(
)
(
)
,
(
)
(
)
(
)
,
(
)
,
(
)
(
)
,
(
)
,
(
)
,
(
1
1
2
2
2
1
1
1
1
1
1
2
2
1
1






Example
06
.
17
.
.06
-
.17
.06
-
.15
Return
Excess
002
.
001
.
0
001
.
002
.
001
.
0
001
.
002
.
Var/Cov



Example cont..
5
.
,
1
.
,
4
.
50
10
40
06
.
17
.
002
.
001
.
0
06
.
17
.
001
.
002
.
001
.
06
.
15
.
0
001
.
002
.
3
2
1
3
2
1
3
2
1
3
2
1
3
2
1


















w
w
w
w
w
w
w
w
w
w
w
w
w
w
w
CAPM: Risk and Return
• Since the excess return divided by the
covariance with the tangency portfolio is
constant across assets, we can derive
important relationships between risk and
return
• The covariance with the tangency portfolio
is, if solved for the tangency portfolio itself,
equal to the variance of the tangency
portfolio
Risk and Return
 
 
F
T
i
F
i
F
T
T
T
i
F
i
T
F
T
T
i
F
i
T
F
T
T
i
F
i
r
r
E
r
r
E
r
r
E
r
Var
r
r
Cov
r
r
E
r
Var
r
r
E
r
r
Cov
r
r
E
r
Var
r
r
E
r
r
Cov
r
r
E













)
(
)
(
)
(
)
(
)
,
(
)
(
)
(
)
(
)
,
(
)
(
constant
)
(
)
(
constant
)
,
(
)
(

Security Market Line
• The expected return of securities is linear
in their beta-factors
• In the (beta,expected return) plane, the
line crossing through (0,rF) and (1,E(rT)) is
called the security market line
Properties of betas
• Beta is linear: the beta of a portfolio of
securities equals the portfolio-weighted
average of the betas of the individual
securities
• An implication is that the beta of the
assets of the company equals the value-
weighted beta of the liabilities of the
company
Tracking portfolios
• A portfolio tracks another perfectly if the
difference in the returns of the portfolios is
a constant (possibly zero)
• Imperfect tracking: A portfolio consisting of
a weight (1-b) in the risk free asset and a
weight b in the tangency portfolio tracks a
stock with beta β=b, because the two
should have the same expected return
Tracking Errors
• The two investments should have the same
expected return, which implies that the tracking
error has zero expectation and zero value
• Of course, investors do not like risk so they
choose to hold the tracking portfolio instead of
the stock
• Because such diversification is free of cost, the
tracking error is also free of cost (i.e. it has zero
value)
Estimating the risk free return
• For risk free return use government bond
or government bill data (long or short term
instruments backed by the government)
• The return offered on such instruments is
a good proxy for the actual risk free return
• Alternative, use the average return of a
zero-beta risky stock, or the intercept with
the y-axis if no zero-beta stock exists
Estimating market risk premia
• Estimate the long-run average return on a broad
stock market index and subtract the risk free rate
• Both the average stock market index return and
the risk free return change over time
• The change in the difference is more volatile
than the changes in the individual time series.
• Therefore, estimate the long-run average index
return first. Do not estimate the difference
between the market return and the risk free rate
directly
Beta estimation
• A raw beta estimate can be obtained from historical
covariance and variance estimates (or by a regression)
• Average beta is one (this is the beta of the market index)
• If the raw estimate exceeds (is below) one, we know
there is a possibility that the raw beta is an overestimate
(underestimate)
• Raw beta estimates should be adjusted – i.e. they
should be pulled down if they are above one or be
bumped up if they are below one.
• There are ways of optimally adjust beta estimates
Beta Adjustment
• Bloomberg adjustment
– Adjusted beta = .66 times Unadjusted beta +
.34 times One
• Rosenberg adjustment
– Adjustment also incorporates fundamental
variables (industry variables, company
characteristics such as size, etc..)
• Also betas are adjusted sometimes to take
into account infrequent trading problems
What to take home
• Two-fund separation
• Capital Market Line vs Security Market
Line
• Risk-Return relationships
• Tracking portfolio
• Parameter estimation: problems and
current practice
Readings
• Grinblatt/Titman ch 5
Problems
• What is the tracking portfolio for a real
asset?
• How would you estimate the beta of the
assets of a firm that has traded debt and
equity?
• How would you estimate the beta of a
company that has never traded?
Week 4: From CAPM to Arbitrage
Pricing Theory
• Main purpose is to extend the valuation
approach into more advanced and flexible
valuation models
• CAPM can be thought of as a “one-factor” model
(returns are determined by movements in the
market portfolio only) but has important
empirical problems (systematic deviations from
predictions)
• APT extends to “multi-factor” pricing that can
mitigate some of the CAPM’s empirical problems
Risk Decomposition
• The Market Model
– One-factor (the return on the market portfolio)
– Related to the CAPM model
– The regression estimates of the market model
generates raw beta-estimates for the CAPM
• Risk Decomposition
– Systematic (market) risk: asset risk that is explained
by market movements
– Unsystematic (diversifiable, idiosyncratic) risk: asset
risk that cannot be explained by market movements
Market model regression
0
)
,
cov(
)
var(
)
,
cov(
)
1
(







Mt
it
Mt
Mt
it
i
F
i
i
it
Mt
i
i
it
r
r
r
r
r
r
r







Risk Decomposition
)
var(
)
var(
)
var(
risk
tic
idiosyncra
)
var(
risk
market
)
var(
)
var(
risk
total
)
var(
2
2
it
Mt
i
it
it
Mt
i
Mt
i
it
r
r
r
r
r











APT: The arbitrage principle
behind factor models
F
j
i
j
j
i
i
j
j
i
j
j
j
i
j
j
i
i
j
i
i
i
i
r
r
b
b
b
r
b
b
b
b
b
b
w
b
w
wb
f
b
a
w
f
b
a
w
r
w
r
w
f
b
a
r




























free
risk
1
solution
has
which
0
)
1
(
Set
)
)(
1
(
)
(
)
1
(
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
APT: Factor pricing
F
M
i
F
i
i
j
F
j
i
F
i
F
i
F
j
j
i
i
j
F
j
i
j
j
i
i
j
j
r
r
E
b
r
a
r
E
b
r
a
b
r
a
r
b
r
b
a
b
a
b
r
a
b
b
b
a
b
b
b


























)
(
CAPM,
For
)
(
constant
1



Multi-factor models
~
~
~
2
2
~
1
1
~
2
2
1
1
)
(
model
factor
-
K
it
Kt
iK
t
i
t
i
i
it
K
iK
i
i
F
i
f
b
f
b
f
b
a
r
b
b
b
r
r
E

















We do not know what
the factors are!
• Can be evaluated statistically – using a
method called factor analysis
• The output generates portfolios associated
with each factor
• Can use firm characteristics or
macroeconomic variables as proxies for
the factors
Factor betas
• The betas determine the asset’s sensitivity to the
factors
• A high loading on factor number 2 means that
the asset is particularly sensitive to risks
associated with factor 2
• Factor models extends into portfolio analysis
since the factor betas of portfolio is just the
value-weighted average factor beta for the
individual assets in the portfolio
Factor models: computing the
variance-covariance structure
• Recall that computing the variance-covariance
structure requires a large number of estimates
• For N assets, N variance estimates and N(N-1)/2
covariance estimates
• N=100, 100 variance estimates and 100(99)/2 =
4950 covariance estimates
• Using the market model, we can work out the
covariance structure from the beta estimates, i.e.
from the N beta estimates
Covariance structure estimation
)
var(
)
,
cov(
)
,
cov(
)
,
cov(
)
var(
)
,
cov(
)
,
cov(
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
~
f
b
b
f
b
f
b
f
b
b
f
b
f
b
r
r
f
b
a
r
j
i
j
i
i
j
j
i
j
i
j
j
i
i
j
i
i
i
i
i


















Variance estimation
)
var(
)
var(
)
var(
~
~
2
~
i
i
i f
b
r 


Tracking Portfolio
• Objective: to design a portfolio that has certain
factor betas (or factor loadings)
• Why? The use of tracking portfolios are many
– Risk management: if the company is subject to risks
beyond its control, e.g. currency risk, it may create a
tracking portfolio that offsets the risk
– Capital allocation: the company may wish to allocate
capital to investments that yield a greater return than
their tracking portfolio and to reduce its exposure to
investments that yield a smaller return than their
tracking portfolio
Designing a Tracking Portfolio
• First, determine the number of relevant factors
(guesswork, statistical analysis)
• Second, determine the factor betas of the
investment you wish to track (statistical analysis,
comparison with existing traded companies)
• Third, gather a collection of different assets with
known factor loadings
• Forth, calibrate your portfolio such that the
portfolio factor beta equals the target factor beta
for each factor
Example
8
.
0
,
3
.
0
,
1
.
0
:
Output
2
2
4
1
5
.
1
3
1
:
n
Calibratio
2
factor
for
0
2,
4,
-
and
1
factor
for
1.5
3,
1,
beta
factor
with
assets
Three
ly
respective
2
and
1
factor
for
2
and
1
betas
target
portfolio,
cking
factor tra
-
Two
3
2
1
2
1
3
2
1
3
2
1













x
x
x
x
x
x
x
x
x
x
x
Applying Pricing Theory
• Use pricing models to investment analysis
(optimal investment strategies in financial
markets – diversification)
• Use pricing models to calibrate
investments (design of tracking portfolios)
• Use pricing models as a benchmark for
real investment (comparing real
investment returns to the return on
tracking portfolios)
Readings
• Chapter 6 in Grinblatt/Titman
Problem
• There are three relevant factors driving
asset returns
– The factor structure of the debt of the
company is (0.01, 0,0)
– The factor structure of the equity of the
company is (2,5,1)
– The company consists of 1/3 debt and 2/3
equity
• What is the factor structure of the
company’s real assets (investments)?
Week 5: Investment Analysis – the
case of Risk Free Projects
• Apply pricing technology to real
investment analysis
• Net Present Value Rule
• Complications
– Sunk cost
– Opportunity cost
– EVA and IRR
Fisher Separation
• With different tastes, why should investors agree
on investment policy?
– Long-term vs short term
– Risky vs Risk free
• Fisher separation
– Agreement is optimal regardless of taste
– Net present value rule: Invest in all projects that cost
less than the value of the project’s tracking portfolio
– NPV = PV(future investment) – Investment cost
Ingredients
• Cash flows of our investment
• Investment cost
• Discount rates (if risk free projects – use a
risk free discount rate)
Present Value = sum of discounted
cash flows
T
T
r
C
r
C
r
C
C
r
r
C
C
r
r
C
C
C
C
)
1
(
)
1
(
)
1
(
portfolios
tracking
of
value
the
of
sum
lue
Present va
etc...
2
year
in
)
1
(
)
1
(
to
grows
r)
(1
C
1
year
in
)
1
(
)
1
(
to
grows
r)
(1
C
:
portfolios
Tracking
,
,
,
:
flows
Cash
3
2
2
1
2
2
2
2
2
2
1
1
1
2
1


































Net Present Value
T
T
r
C
r
C
r
C
I
NPV
)
1
(
)
1
(
1 2
2
1
0








 
NPV and Arbitrage
3.
period
in
30
paying
bond
a
buying
2,
period
in
10
paying
bond
a
selling
1,
period
in
40
paying
bond
a
buying
project,
the
g
undertakin
to
Equivalent
94
.
34
05
.
1
30
05
.
1
10
05
.
1
40
20
30
,
10
,
40
,
20
:
flows
Cash
arbitrage
ugh
money thro
making
to
equivalent
is
NPV
positive
has
it
en
project wh
Adopt the
3
2








NPV
Value Additivity of NPVs
B
A
B
A
B
A
NPV
NPV
NPV
NPV
NPV




:
lue
present va
net
has
projects)
two
the
of
flows
cash
combined
the
(i.e.
B
A
Project
has
B
Project
has
A
Project
Mutually Exclusive Projects
• This is an “either-or” situation – you can invest in
project A or you can invest in project B, but you
cannot invest in both at the same time
• Both projects may have positive NPV so are
worthwhile on their own
• “Either-or” situations often arise naturally. For
instance, all timing decisions are mutually
exclusive. You can invest now or you can invest
in the future, but you cannot invest both now and
in the future.
Which project to choose when they
are mutually exclusive
• The choice criterion is to maximize the net
present value of investment.
• Therefore, if you have two or more
mutually exclusive projects to choose from
you should choose the one with the most
positive NPV.
Capital Constraints
• There are situations in which you may
have more projects with positive NPV
available than you have funds for
investment – i.e. you have a budget
constraint
• Then the choice criterion is to invest in the
projects that offer the greatest profitability
index
Profitability Index
0
0
0
Index
ity
Profitabil
lue
present va
Net
cost
Investment
flow
cash
Value
Present
I
PV
PI
I
PV
NPV
I
PV




Example
budget?
within
staying
to
subject
policy
investment
optimal
the
is
What
.
100
budget
investment
Total
exclusive?
mutually
are
projects
the
if
policy
investment
optimal
the
is
What
t?
independen
are
projects
the
if
policy
investment
optimal
the
is
What
950
,
1000
:
C
Project
90
,
100
:
B
Project
8
,
10
:
A
Project
m
B
m
I
m
PV
m
I
m
PV
m
I
m
PV
C
C
B
B
A
A







Example cont.
11
.
12
)
950
1000
(
950
2
)
90
100
(
)
8
10
(
:
NPV
Total
C
of
%
2105
.
0
950
2
plus
C)
in
invest
to
2
leaving
budget,
of
90
additional
(using
B
of
all
plus
budget)
100
of
8
(using
A
of
All
:
mix
Optimal
C.
and
B
then
first,
A
in
Invest
0526
.
1
950
1000
1111
.
1
90
100
25
.
1
8
10
:
indexes
ity
Profitabil













C
B
A
PI
PI
PI
Economic Value Added
• EVA is a profitability measure that has become
widely used in corporations – initially to replace
accounting earnings or profit measures
• Accounting measures do not always measure
economic performance (depreciation cost, for
instance, is not a cash flow and should not be
included in project evaluation)
• Accounting measures are therefore not directly
consistent with NPV
• Economic Value Added is consistent with NPV
EVA: Definition
• Three components
– Cash flow
– Change in asset base
– Economic return on assets
• EVA(t) = Ct + (It – It-1) – rIt-1
• EVA(t) = Ct + It – (1+r)It-1
• Discounted sum of EVA(t) = Net Present
Value
EVA, cont.
• Investment of 100
• The first year cash flow is 50
• The second year cash flow is 150
• Discount rate is 10%
• Assets are depreciated by 50% in the first
year and by 100% in the second year.
• NPV = -100 + 50/1.1+150/1.12=69.42
EVA, cont.
• EVA(0) = -100(cash flow)+(100-0)(change in assets)-
0(0.1)(economic cost of initial assets) = 0
• EVA(1)=50(cash flow)+(50-100)(change in assets)-
100(0.1)(economic cost of initial assets) = -10
• EVA(2)=150(cash flow)+(0-50)(change in assets-
50(0.1)(economic cost of initial assets)= 95
• Discounted EVA = EVA(0)+EVA(1)/1.1+EVA(2)/1.12 =
69.42 = NPV
IRR: Internal Rate of Return
• Often managers base investment decision on
the IRR instead of the NPV
• The rule is: if IRR is greater than the discount
rate (i.e. the cost of capital) then adopt the
project
• In many cases this leads to the same investment
decision, as IRR is greater than the discount rate
only if the NPV is positive
• In other cases this is not true however, so to be
safe always use NPV or EVA calculations
IRR
T
T
T
T
IRR
C
IRR
C
IRR
C
I
r
C
r
C
r
C
I
NPV
)
1
(
)
1
(
1
0
)
1
(
)
1
(
1
2
2
1
0
2
2
1
0




















Example
• Investment cost = 100
• First year’s cash flow = 150
• Discount rate 10%
• NPV = -100+150/1.1=36.36
• IRR: 0=-100+150/(1+IRR) yields 50%
• Since 50% > 10% (IRR > discount rate) it is
optimal to adopt the project
Projects that have the cash flow
profile of a loan
• “Investment cost” = 150
• Next year’s cash flow = -100
• Discount rate = 10%
• NPV = 150 – 100/1.1 = 59.09
• IRR: 0 = 150 – 100/(1+IRR) yields a negative
IRR of -33.33% but this project is clearly
profitable even though IRR < discount rate
Problems with IRR
• IRR criterion is sensitive to the type of cash flow
(asset or liability?)
• IRR is not unique in general (for T period
projects there can be up to T different IRRs)
• IRR is not appropriate for mutually exclusive
projects as small projects with high IRR and
small NPV might then be preferred to large
projects with low IRR and large NPV
IRR and mutually exclusive
projects
• Discount rate 2%
• Project A: -10, -16, +30
• Project B: -10, 2, 11
• NPV(A) = 3.149
• NPV(B) = 2.534
• IRR(A) = 10.79%
• IRR(B) = 15.36%
Important points
• Fisher separation
• NPV definition
• NPV with mutually exclusive projects
(either-or)
• NPV with budget constraints
• EVA and NPV
• IRR
• IRR pitfalls
Readings
• Grinblatt/Titman chapter 10
Test for next week:
• Readings chapter 4, 5, 6 and 10
• Important formulas
– CAPM: exp return = risk free plus risk adjustment
– Beta-factor: covariance/variance
– Factor models: exp return = risk free plus risk
adjustment
• Risk free real investments
– NPV rule
– Profitability Index
– EVA
– IRR
Very important formulas
T
T
K
K
F
M
M
F
M
F
r
C
r
C
I
NPV
r
r
E
r
Var
)
Cov(r,r
r
r
E
r
r
E
)
1
(
1
:
lue
present va
Net
premium)
risk
denotes
(where
)
(
:
models
Factor
)
(
:
Beta
)
)
(
(
)
(
:
CAPM
1
0
1
1
























Sample test questions
1. The risk free return is 5% and the market index has an
average return of 12%. What is the expected return for
an asset with beta 1.5?
2. An investment costs 100,000 and offers a cash flow of
50,000 in year 1 and 150,000 in year 2. The discount
rate is 5%. What is the net present value of the
investment? Should you adopt the investment?
Explain.
3. In a two-factor market, the factor betas of asset A are 1
and 0, and the factor betas of asset B are 0 and 1,
respectively. The risk free return is 5%, and the
average return on asset A and B are 10% and 15%,
respectively. What are the risk premia associated with
factor 1 and 2?
Week 6: Investing in Risky Projects
• Applying the CAPM and APT in the capital
budgeting process
• Key problem: estimating the cost of capital
for risky projects
– Applying CAPM and APT
– Using comparison firms
– The dividend discount model
Risk Adjusted Discounting
t
t
t
F
M
F
t
r
C
E
C
E
PV
r
r
E
r
r
C
E
)
1
(
)
(
))
(
(
:
Discount
)
(
(
flow
cash
the
of
return
market
expected
the
Compute
return
market
the
of
variance
over the
return,
market
the
h
return wit
the
of
covariance
the
is
beta
(the
flow
cash
with this
associated
risk
beta
the
Compute
t
period
in
)
(
get)
ll
at we'
exactly wh
know
not
do
(we
flow
cash
future
expected
the
Compute




 

Fundamental problem: Estimating
the beta factor
• Betas for traded equity are easy to estimate –
we simply regress equity returns on the index
return, and possibly adjust to take into account
estimation error (e.g. Bloomberg adjustment)
• Betas for projects are much more difficult to
estimate as there simply does not exist a trading
history
• Possible solution: use comparison firms (firms
we imagine has similar risk profile to the project
in question)
Using comparison firms
• Asset base needs to be sufficiently similar
to the planned investment
• We need to adjust for leverage effects (the
comparison firm may have debt)
– In general, it is only the equity beta of the
comparison firm we can estimate but we are
really interested in the asset beta
– The more the firm borrows, the higher the
equity beta (even though the asset beta
remains the same)
Adjusting for leverage
term
leverage
a
plus
beta
asset
the
equals
beta
equity
Estimated
)
(
beta
equity
and
debt
of
sum
weighted
-
value
beta
Asset
D
A
A
E
E
D
A
E
D
E
D
V
V
E
V
D















Example
9
.
0
60
40
1
5
.
1
implies
)
0
(
60
40
5
.
1
0
beta
debt
Estimated
1.5
beta
equity
Estimated
60.
equity
value
and
40,
debt
value
100,
assets
Value






A
A
A



Implementing risk adjusted
discounting with comparison firms
08
.
1
0
.
1
79
.
0
85
.
0
s
Wendy'
00
.
1
10
7
.
7
77
.
0
McDonalds
75
.
0
100
.
0
096
.
0
72
.
0
Chicken
s
Church'
are
betas
asset
The
zero.
to
equal
assumed
is
companes
these
of
debt
the
of
beta
the
and
ly,
respective
s),
(Wendy'
0.790
and
0.210
and
)
(McDonalds
7.700
and
2.300
Chicken),
s
(Church'
0.096
and
0.004
are
companies
these
of
ues
equity val
and
debt
The
ly.
respective
1.08
and
1.00,
0.75,
are
companies
three
these
of
betas
equity
The
s.
Wendy'
and
s
McDonald'
Chicken,
s
Church'
of
beta
average
the
has
project
A



Cont…
)
084
.
0
(
78
.
0
04
.
0
1055
.
0
is
project
for the
rate)
(discount
capital
of
Cost
8.4%.
premium
risk
market
and
4%
rate
free
Risk
3
85
.
0
77
.
0
72
.
0
78
.
0
beta
project
beta
Average







Applying APT
t
K
K
F
t
t
r
C
E
C
E
PV
)
1
(
)
(
))
(
(
by
given
are
lues
present va
so
model,
factor
a
by
capital
of
cost
the
estimates
model
APT
The
1
1 


 





APT and CAPM vs Alternative
methods
• A drawback with the APT and CAPM
models is that they require a number of
estimates: the risk free rate of return, the
beta factor(s), the market risk premium
and the factor risk premia.
• It can in some circumstances be better to
work with simpler model. The dividend
growth model is an alternative to the APT
and CAPM.
Dividend Discount Model
yield
dividend
dividends
in
growth
)
1
(
)
1
(
)
1
(
)
1
(
)
1
(
etc...
,
)
1
(
)
1
(
0
1
1
0
2
1
1
2
2
1
0
2
2
1
1
1
0























S
div
g
r
g
r
div
S
r
g
div
r
div
r
div
r
div
S
r
S
div
S
r
S
div
S


What if comparison firms don’t
exist?
• In general there is little we can do
• However, if there exist firms where one
division is similar to our project we may be
able to identify the relevant betas.
• For instance, if you want to estimate the
beta of the network division of television
companies you can use the fact that these
divisions play a varying role in generating
the asset beta for these companies
Network division example
36
.
0
78
.
0
5
.
0
5
.
0
99
.
0
75
.
0
25
.
0
that
know
we
similar,
ly
sufficient
are
divisions
network
-
non
If
divisions.
network
-
non
from
50%
division,
network
from
value
of
50%
0.78,
beta
asset
:
Viacom
divisions.
network
-
non
from
75%
division,
network
from
value
of
25%
0.99,
beta
asset
:
Electric
General










Network
network
Non
Network
Viacom
network
Non
Network
GE







Pitfalls in using the comparison
method
• Project betas not the same as firm betas:
mature projects generally lower beta than
R&D projects etc
• Growth opportunities are usually the
source of high betas: company value often
significantly linked to future growth
opportunities as opposed to current
investments
Example
• Investment cost 100,000
• Annual running cost 5,000 for 5 years
• Expected revenue stream 50,000 for 5
years
• Beta-risk of revenue stream 1.2
• Risk free return 5%
• Expected market return 12%
Example cont…
project.
adopt
Therefore,
0
51
.
52
51
.
152
100
51
.
152
16
.
174
65
.
21
)
134
.
1
(
50
)
134
.
1
(
50
)
134
.
1
(
50
)
134
.
1
(
50
)
134
.
1
(
50
)
05
.
1
(
5
)
05
.
1
(
5
)
05
.
1
(
5
)
05
.
1
(
5
)
05
.
1
(
5
%
4
.
13
%)
5
%
12
(
2
.
1
%
5
:
stream
revenue
for the
rate
discount
The
free?)
risk
assumed
be
can
costs
the
(as
5%
:
costs
running
for
rate
discount
The
5
4
3
2
1
5
4
3
2
1

































NPV
PV
Comparison method, example
• A firm with equity currently valued at 100,000
and outstanding debt worth 50,000 holds 25%
cash and 75% of a risky asset on its balance
sheet
• The equity beta is 1.5
• You consider investing in a project very similar to
the risky asset owned by this firm
• The risk free rate is 5% and the expected return
on the market is 12%
• Work out the project beta and the cost of capital
for your project
Comparison method cont…
14.33%
5%)
-
1.33(12%
5%
capital
of
Cost
33
.
1
75
.
0
1
75
.
0
)
0
(
25
.
0
beta
asset
Total
1
100
50
1
5
.
1
beta
asset
total
The
0
to
close
beta
a
has
balance
cash
that the
assume
also
and
0,
to
close
very
is
beta
debt
Assume
A
A










RiskyAsset
RiskyAsset




Readings
• Grinblatt & Titman chapter 11
• I have not emphasized the certainty
equivalent method
Week 7: Taxes and Financing
• Irrelevance in the absence of transaction
costs and taxes (Modigliani-Miller)
• Financing choices not neutral to taxation:
– Level: corporate vs private tax rates
– Timing: dividends can be deferred whereas
interest payments on debt cannot
Modigliani-Miller
• The operating cash flow is divided into two
components
– Cash flow to debt holders
– Cash flow to equity holders
• Fundamental question: Does it matter how
the split is made?
• If it does we can create value also through
financing choices (not only through
investment choices)
MM cont…
• Modigliani-Miller proved that capital structure
choices are irrelevant – the split does not matter
• This proof rests on the absence of transaction
costs of any kind: taxes, trading costs, and
bankruptcy costs
• The proof of the MM theorem uses a “no
arbitrage” argument – financial markets do not
admit “free lunches”, or trading strategies giving
you a positive cash flow with no prior investment
MM cont…
• Consider two “versions” of the same firm –
one version is U for unlevered (with no
debt) and the other version L for levered
(with debt)
• The firms have otherwise the same
operating cash flow X
• The unlevered firm has value VU and the
levered firm value VL
MM cont…
• The fundamental question is whether VU and VL
differ
• The cash flows of firm U’s equity holders is
simply X
• The cash flow of firm L’s debt holders is (1+r)D
to the firm’s debt holders and X-(1+r)D to the
firm’s equity holders, in total a cash flow of X
also
• The value of L is the combined value of the debt
and the equity
MM cont…
• Suppose VL is smaller than VU
• Then an investor can buy a 10% holding of L’s debt and
a 10% holding of L’s equity, which entitles the investor to
a 10% share in the total cash flow X. He would then go
to the market and sell 10% of the cash flow X, which is
valued at 10% of the value of U. This leaves him with
zero future liability.
• His trading gains are 10% of the difference between VU
and VL, which we have assumed is positive
• This cannot be possible in an arbitrage free market, so
we can conclude that VL must be equal to or greater than
VU
MM cont…
• Now suppose VU is smaller than VL
• An investor buys 10% of the cash flow X and sells 10%
of a claim that promises the cash flow (1+r)D. The net
cash flow is 10% of a claim that pays X-(1+r)D at
maturity, which is priced at 10% of the equity in L
• The net future liability is zero, and the trading gains
equal 10% of the difference between VL and VU, which
we have assumed positive
• Again, this is not consistent with arbitrage free markets
• In conclusion, it must be the case that VU = VL and that
capital structure is irrelevant
What about risky debt?
• When the corporate debt contract is risky it may
be difficult to find a “synthetic” corporate debt
contract if a real one does not exist
• We must assume, therefore, that the markets
are sufficiently complete in order to conclude
that financing does not matter
• Complete market = a market where the
dimensionality of the asset structure equals the
dimensionality of the uncertainty structure
• If there are two states of nature (e.g. “good” and
“bad”) then it suffices with two distinct assets to
make the market complete
Bankruptcy costs
• The Modigliani-Miller theorem also assumes that
there are no deadweight costs of bankruptcy
• The debt holders may not get all their money
back if the firm defaults, but this is not in itself
enough to jeopardise the MM-theorem
• There must also be deadweight costs or
liquidation costs (i.e. the value of the assets in
default is less than the value of the assets as a
going concern)
Taxes: Another important factor
• The tax system is generally fairly complex
with different tax rates for different
individuals and institutions, and for
different types of income
• Therefore, it may be scope for “tax
arbitrage” profits in financing
After tax cash flow analysis
• A constant after tax discount rate r
• Tax rate for personal income from debt tD
• Tax rate for personal income from equity tE
• Corporate tax rate tC
• Earnings before taxes and interest payments X
• Earnings before taxes (X – kD) (k coupon rate, D
nominal amount borrowed)
• After tax personal income from debt kD(1-tD)
• After tax earnings (X-kD)(1-tC)
• After tax personal income from equity (X-kD)(1-tC)(1-tE)
Algebra
benefits
tax
discounted
firm
unlevered
Value
1
)
1
)(
1
(
1
1
)
1
(
1
)
1
)(
1
(
flow
cash
after tax
Discounted
1
)
1
)(
1
(
1
)
1
(
)
1
)(
1
(
)
1
(
)
1
)(
1
)(
(
e
perspectiv
investor
from
flow
cash
After tax












































D
E
C
D
E
C
D
E
C
D
E
C
D
E
C
t
t
t
r
t
kD
r
t
t
X
DC
t
t
t
t
kD
t
t
X
t
kD
t
t
kD
X
C
Equilibrium
• If there is a positive discounted tax benefit firms
choose to borrow more, and investors with
higher personal tax rate on debt income is
encouraged to enter the market. This implies a
reduction of tax benefits of borrowing.
• Reverse effect is there is a negative discounted
tax benefit of borrowing
• In equilibrium, we expect the tax benefit from
borrowing to be equal to zero
• This is the so-called “Miller’s equilibrium”
described in Appendix 14A in the textbook
Preferred stock
• Preferred stock: dividends on preferred stock are
not tax deductible at the corporate level as are
interest payments on debt
• This implies that corporate junior debt may be
tax efficient relative to preferred stock
• However, the US tax code allows a 70% tax
exclusion for preferred dividends paid to
corporate holders, so the yield on preferred
stock is often lower (before tax) than on junior
debt even though the debt has seniority over the
preferred stock
Investor conflicts?
• Tax exempt equity holders prefer in general to reduce
the borrowing of the firm so as to transfer income from
debt repayments to dividend payments
• High-tax bracket investor prefer the opposite
• Often tax-exempt municipal bonds (or similar
investments) offer yields that are greater than the after
tax yield on corporate bonds for high-tax bracket
investors
• Thus, the firm can give these investors an advantage by
increasing the firm’s borrowing, as this frees capital that
the investors can use to invest in tax-exempt municipal
bonds
Inflation
• We expect to see a one-to-one relationship
between inflation and nominal interest rates - if
inflation increases by one percentage point then
so do nominal interest rates
• Higher inflation, therefore, leads to higher
nominal borrowing costs that yield in turn greater
tax deductions
• Therefore, the tax effect has greater bite in
periods of high inflation
Empirical evidence
• Do firms with greater taxable earnings borrow more?
– No, but this may be because firms in general rarely issue equity
– Firms that perform poorly, therefore, tend to accumulate debt to
meet their investments
• Tax code changes that affect the relative tax benefit of
borrowing should have an impact on corporate financing
– Yes, US tax reform of 1986 which reduced the tax benefits of
other things than debt (such as depreciation rules and
investment tax credits) gave rise to an increase in borrowing
among firms most affected
– The firms less affected did not increase their borrowing to the
same extent
• Taxes matter but don’t explain everything
Readings
• Grinblatt/Titman chapter 14, including the
appendix
• 14.10 Are There Tax Advantages to
Leasing not so relevant
Exercises
1. A firm has assets valued at 100, and debt valued at 50.
It plans to restructure its liability side by increasing its
borrowing to 70 and paying a dividend of 20 to its
shareholders. The debt has zero beta before and
0.001 beta after the recapitalization. The beta of the
equity is 2 before the recapitalization.
a) What are the values of the equity before and after the
recapitalization?
b) What is the beta of the assets of the firm?
c) What is the beta of the equity after recapitalization?
d) The recapitalization has increased the beta of the debt (and
therefore the cost of debt capital). Has it also increased the
beta of the equity? Does this mean that the total cost of
financing has increased? Explain.
Week 8: Taxes and Dividends
• In frictionless markets dividends don’t
matter
• Why do firms nonetheless pay dividends?
• Taxes and dividends
• Stock returns and dividend yields – what is
the connection?
• Investment distortions caused by taxes in
dividends
Cash flow to shareholders
• Shareholders earn money through holding equity that
earns a cash flow (such as dividends) and capital gains
(which can be realized through selling stock)
• The cash distribution to shareholders is normally
discretional – the company can decide how much cash
flow to give their shareholders
• Cash distribution comes in two forms – dividend
payments and share repurchase schemes
• Dividend payments do not affect the number of shares
but will reduce the value of each share
• Share repurchases do normally not affect the value of
each share but will reduce the number of shares
outstanding
How much of earnings is cash flow
to shareholders?
• Dividend payout ratio: the ratio of dividends to
earnings
• In the US, this ratio has declined from about
22% in 1980 to about 14% in 1998
• Over the same period, the ratio of share
repurchases to earnings increased from 3% to
about 14%
• The total ratio of cash flow to earnings has been
relatively stable at about 25% of earnings
Dividend yields
• Dividend yield is the ratio of dividends per
share over price per share
• Typical pattern is that high-tech growth
firms have low dividend yield and dividend
payout ratios (Microsoft paid its very first
dividend this year)
• Stable, old economy companies such as
mining, oil and manufacturing pay about
half their earnings as dividends
What is the optimal dividend payout
ratio?
• Assumption: frictionless economy (no
transaction costs, taxes, or other frictions)
• Investment policy unaffected by dividend
payments
• Modigliani-Miller Dividend Irrelevance
Theorem:
– The choice between paying dividends and
repurchasing shares is a matter of
indifference to shareholders
Modigliani-Miller Irrelevance
• Consider two identical equity financed
firms, the only difference is dividend policy
• Firm 1 pays 10m as dividends
• Firm 2 repurchases stock worth 10m
• After the end of the year, the firms are
worth X
• In the beginning each firm has 1m shares
outstanding
MM cont…
• Each share eventually sells for X divided by the number of shares
• Firm 2 buys back 10m worth of stock
• If share price is p, and firm 2 buys back n shares, we know that
pn=10m
• We also know that p=X/(1m-n)
• Suppose X = 150m
• Solving both equations gives us n = (10m1m)/(X+10m), so we get n
= 62,500, and p = 150m/(1m-62,500) = 160
• Firm 1: stock price is p = 150m/1m = 150, but each stock gives a
dividend worth 10m/1m = 10, so the total value of each stock is
150+10 = 160
• Since shareholders get the same cash flow eventually, the shares
must sell at the same price initially, i.e. dividend policy does not
matter
Taxes and cash distribution to
shareholders
• Classical tax system
– Dividends taxed as ordinary income and capital gains at a lower
rate than ordinary income
– Dividends are not tax deductible at corporate level, so dividends
are also subject to corporate taxation
• Imputation system
– Dividends are taxed as ordinary income but investors get a
partial tax credit for corporate taxes (to offset personal taxes)
– Dividends are not tax deductible at corporate level
• Systems that eliminate double taxation
– Dividends are tax deductible at corporate level and taxed as
ordinary income at investor level
Classical tax system
• The classical tax system implies a tax
disadvantage of dividend payments
• Dividend $100, 35% tax implies an immediate
tax liability of $35
• Share repurchase scheme: an investor sells
$100 worth of shares. Suppose original cost was
$76. This implies a taxable capital gain of $24.
Taxed at 20%, this implies an immediate tax
liability of $4.8
• Share repurchase scheme much cheaper than
paying dividends
Tax avoidance schemes
• In theory, investors can often invest in a scheme
that gives an immediate tax relief against a
deferred future tax liability
• In practice, investors do not take advantage of
these schemes but instead choose to pay taxes
(or are unable to invest in tax avoidance
schemes) on the received dividends
• The question is, therefore, why corporations
continue to pay dividends when they are so tax
inefficient
Dividend clienteles
• Some investors do not pay taxes
• These investors will, everything else being
equal, prefer high dividend yield firms to low
dividend yield firms as they do not pay tax on the
dividend
• Firms might adopt different dividend policies to
attract different investor clienteles
• Empirical evidence suggests that investors’
portfolios have dividend yields that are related to
their tax status (high tax bracket investors
choose low dividend yield stocks and vice versa)
Dividend payments and stock
returns
• Do stocks with high dividend yield compensate
investors for the tax disadvantage?
• Higher returns should then lead to lower values,
reflecting the higher discount rates applied to
future cash flows
• Research has focused on two returns effects
– Ex-dividend day behaviour of stock prices
– Whether cross-sectional dividend yield differences
affect expected returns
Ex-dividend day price drop
• If you buy the stock on the day before the ex-dividend day, you are
entitled to the future value of the stock and the current dividend
payment
• If you buy the stock on the ex-dividend day, you are entitled only to
the future value of the stock
• The stock price should, therefore, drop on the ex-dividend day to
reflect the dividend payment
• Empirical results from the 1960s indicate that the ex-dividend day
price drop is about 77.7% of the dividend payment on average, but
was higher (90%) for dividend payments greater than 5% of the
stock price, and lower (50%) for the smallest dividends.
• These results indicate a tax effect (investors discount a tax rate of
around 22.3% on dividends), and a clientele effect (investors with
different tax rates hold portfolios with different dividend yields)
Ex-dividend day cont…
• Transaction cost argument
– Consider buying a stock at $20 before the ex-div day, receive a $1
dividend, then sell the stock for $19.20. This yields $1 taxable profits
and $(20-19.20) = $0.80 tax deductible losses. The net profit is $0.20
less taxes, but it is still arbitrage profits. The stock needs to drop by the
full amount to preclude arbitrage profits.
– If there is a $0.10 per share transaction cost, the investor receives
taxable profits of $1 in dividends, and incur $0.80 in tax deductible
losses. The net profit is $0.20, but the investor must also pay $0.10 in
transaction costs, so the net profit is only $0.10 less taxes. If the stock
drops to $19.10, therefore, there are no arbitrage profits to be made.
– If the dividend payment is only $0.40, the necessary price drop is $0.30
to prevent arbitrage profits. That is, the price drop is greater for high
dividend yielding stocks in percentage terms (as the clientele effect
predicts).
• Price drop less than the dividend payment is also observed in
countries that do not have a classical tax system, suggesting this is
not a tax driven phenomenon at all
Cross-sectional relation between
dividend yield and stock returns
• If dividends are more heavily taxed than capital
gains, the expected return must be greater for
high dividend yield stocks.
• Empirically, stocks with high dividend yields
have higher returns, but the relationship is not
straightforward
• The relationship is U-shaped, with zero dividend
yield stocks have higher expected return than
stocks with low dividend yield, but for stocks
paying dividends, the expected return increases
with the dividend yield
How dividend taxes affect financing
and investment decisions
• Marginal tax rate of 50%
• Company has a choice between paying $1m in dividends or retain
the earnings
• Retained earnings yield 6% after corporate taxes (alternative II)
• Dividends yield 7% before personal taxes in corporate bonds
(alternative I)
• Alternative I yields $500,000 to invest at 7%, which after tax yields
$17,500 per year
• Alternative II yields $60,000 in extra dividend payments per year,
which yields $30,000 after tax to the investor
• If you are a zero tax payer, however, alternative I yields $1,000,000
to invest at 7%, which equals $70,000, and alternative II only
$60,000 in additional dividends per year.
• Investors with different tax rates are likely to disagree with regard to
the dividend policy the firm should pursue
The general principle
• Investors prefer retained earnings if (1-corporate
tax rate) x (pretax return internally at corporate
level) > (after tax return at investor level)
• This has implications for investment policy as
well
– Tax-exempt and tax-paying investors agree on
externally funded projects but may disagree on
internally funded ones (tax exempt investors require
higher return on internal investment than tax-paying
investors)
Readings
• Grinblatt/Titman chapter 15
Exercises
1. A stock trades at 100p per share (prior to ex-dividend
day) and the firm will pay a dividend of 10p per share.
a) Work out the ex-dividend day price if investors pay 40% tax on
dividends and the ex-dividend day price equals the initial price
less after-tax dividend payment
b) Work out the minimum transaction cost per share that
prevents tax-arbitrage by a tax-paying investor
c) Suppose the dividend payment was 50p per share. What is
your answer to a) and b) now?
d) Suppose the actual transaction cost is 2p per share. What are
the arbitrage free price drops in a) and c) above now?
e) What are the “implied” tax rates on dividends in d)?
Week 9: Managerial Incentives and
Corporate Finance
• Manager – shareholder conflicts
– Occidental Petroleum and founder/CEO
Armand Hammer case in the textbook
– Maxwell Communications and Robert Maxwell
• How such conflicts affect investment,
financing, and ownership structure
• How such conflicts can be mitigated by
executive compensation schemes
Separation of ownership and
control
• The separation of ownership and control is beneficial in
terms of diversification and optimal investment while
keeping a stable management team in control of the firm
• But it can be harmful if the management team is more
interested in pursuing their own interest as opposed to
their shareholders’ interests
• In what way do their interests differ?
– Managers represent investors, customers, suppliers, and
employees – not just investors
– Managers get utility from non-financial benefits such as status,
perks, job-security etc and are willing to spend corporate
resources on these even though they are likely to be negative
NPV projects
Factors that determine the
manager-shareholder conflict
• Proportions of stock owned by the manager
• Managerial entrenchment and lack of means to
control managers
– Diffuse ownership structure (no individual manager
benefits enough to take action)
– Proxy fights (shareholder revolt at general meeting)
are very expensive and difficult to organize
• Bonus schemes not performance sensitive
enough
• Changes in corporate governance have made
managers more accountable in recent years
Ownership structure
• Ownership structure is on the whole more concentrated than we would
expect (CAPM advocates diversification), particularly outside the US/UK
• Ownership concentration a response to weak legal protection of
shareholders’ interests
• UK/US have the strongest protection and the most diffuse ownership
structure
• Managers tend to keep a significant ownership stake in firms where the
incentive conflict with the shareholders is the greatest
• In many internet IPOs, the managers kept a large share of their holding in
order to get a higher price in the IPO (lock in clauses)
• Eg. Lastminute.com – Martha Lane-Fox and Brent Hoberman (founders –
Hoberman still manager) were still large owners after IPO and were
prevented from selling their share for a given time period after the IPO
• Firms with higher concentration of management ownership have higher
market values relative to their book values, provided management share is
not too big. If it gets above 5%, managers become “entrenched” which
allows them to pursue own interests more
How managers distort investment
decisions
• Managers prefer investments that fit the manager’s
expertise
– Makes him (her) more indispensable
• Investments in visible/fun industries
– Raising the manager’s external profile (and his potential future
job opportunities and wages)
• Investments that pay off early
– Financial success in the short run can increase bonus, reduce
the risk of losing job, increase the possibility of raising more
capital
• Investments that reduce risk and increase the scope of
the firm
– To avoid bankruptcy the manager seeks relatively safe
investments and may take a portfolio approach to investments
Capital structure and managerial
control
• Managers are likely to prefer equity to debt because they
are interested in minimizing the probability of default
• Shareholders may, therefore, prefer debt financing as
debt is a good way to discipline managers (the fear of
losing job is a good motivator)
• Empirical investigations show there is a positive
relationship between leverage and
– Percentage of executive pay tied to performance
– Percentage of equity owned by managers
– Percentage of investment bankers on the board of directors
– Percentage of equity owned by large individual investors
• Debt is a good way to curb overinvestment
• Debt engages often a bank who is a good monitor of
management
Executive compensation
• The problem of incentivizing managers is often called a
principal-agent problem
– Tenant farmer works the land of a land-owner. If compensated
too much in terms of output, the tenant farmer must bear all the
risk influencing output (weather etc). If compensated too little in
terms of output, the tenant farmer doesn’t put in the required
effort.
– Compensation is a matter of balancing the two concerns: Called
the problem of designing the optimal incentive contract
– Effort (input) cannot be observed, otherwise compensation could
be tied to effort instead of output
– Design objective is to minimize the agency costs of delegated
control
Performance based executive
compensation
• Jensen and Murphy (1990) found that a $1000 increase in firm value is
associated with a $3 increase in CEO bonus (a $10m jet costs the CEO
$30,000 just in lost bonus payments)
• Some disagreement about this result, as it may have underestimated the
real sensitivity by ignoring longer term impact on bonus payments
• Substantial differences in pay-for-performance sensitivity across firms
– Some explained by the agency costs of delegated control
– Some explained by the risk of the firm
• Over time, the pay-for-performance sensitivity has been increasing
• Adoption of performance-based pay is generally a positive signal to the
investors
• What about relative performance sensitivity (pay linked to the position of the
company relative to the average for the industry)? Relative performance-
pay is rarely observed, but can be costly to investors in terms of price wars
and overly aggressive competition.
• Stock-based performance versus earnings-based performance. Stock
based performance is much noisier than earnings-based performance, but
in return earnings can be manipulated by the manager
Mergers, Spin-offs, Carve Outs
• It may be easier to design an optimal compensation contract for a
small, single-unit, firm than for a multi-divisional conglomerate
• Solution may be a spin-off (a division set up as an independent firm
by distributing shares in the new firm to the existing investors) or a
carve-out (do an IPO of the division and sell to new investors)
• Spin-offs and carve-outs are positive signals
• Mergers create the opposite effect, and in particular conglomerate
mergers can be seen as a negative signal to investors as they affect
managerial incentives negatively (conglomerate mergers are
relatively rare now but were popular in the 1960s and 70s)
• Many spin-offs and carve-outs are reversing prior conglomerate
mergers
Readings
• Grinblatt/Titman chapter 18
Exercises
1. The manager of a firm considers investing £1m
of free cash flow (earnings currently held in a
bank account) in a project that has private
value £10,000 to the manager but NPV of -
£200,000 to the investors. What is the optimal
decision for the manager if
a) He has fixed pay?
b) He has in addition a bonus scheme where an
increase of £1000 in the stock value leads to an
increase of £10 to the manager?
c) What is the optimal bonus scheme for the manager
in this case?
Week 10: Information and Financial
Decisions
• Key premise: managers have better information
than investors
• What managers do, therefore, conveys
information to the market
• Managers can
– Distort accounts to manipulate the information flow
– Reveal information through dividend policy, capital
structure choice, and investment decisions
• Empirical evidence: how stock prices react to
various financial decisions
What can better informed
individuals do?
• Signals: they act in a way that conveys their information
– Difference between “cheap talk” and “credible action”
– Signals need to be costly
• Pooling: they act in a way that everybody else act in
order not to reveal information
– It is too expensive to send a signal
• Manipulation
– Actions: Investors overestimate the true cost of signalling
– Reporting: “Bad” reports attract attention – it may be easier to
disguise bad outcomes by submitting an “average” report
Distortions to managerial incentives
• Managers seek to maximize the share price
• The share price may, however, deviate from the “intrinsic
value” (the full information price)
• Long term investors prefer that managers maximize the
intrinsic value (which eventually transpires)
• Short term investors prefer that managers maximize the
current share price (which may be distorted due to lack
of information)
• The conflict is, therefore, essentially one of short-
termism versus long-termism
Why do managers care about the
current share price?
• New issues or the managers may plan to
sell private stock
• Low prices attract bidders in takeovers
• Managerial compensation directly linked to
stock price
• Customers or employees may flee the
company if the stock price goes too low
Earnings manipulation
• The same underlying profits can be reported in different
ways as earnings
– Depends on the choice of depreciation method
– Choice of inventory valuation method (FIFO LIFO)
– The estimates of the economic value of assets, the estimates of
the cost of guarantees or warranties issued, the estimates of the
pension liability of the firm, the discount rates used for valuation
of leases and pensions etc.
• There is a tendency to inflate reported earnings to
increase the current stock price
• But managers may also find it useful sometimes to
deflate reported earnings
– For instance when the manager has just been hired
– When applying for government subsidies or tariff protection
against foreign competitors
Short-termism in investment
• Bias towards short term projects because these makes it clear very
quickly whether the investment is a good one
• Example:
– Project A: yr 1 cash flow 40; yr 2-11 cash flow 80 per year; PV 840
– Project B: yr 1 cash flow 60; yr 2-11 cash flow 50 per year; PV 560
– Project C: yr 1 cash flow 40; yr 2-11 cash flow 40; PV 440
• Investors think C is much more realistic than A or B
• If company chooses A, the stock price is close to 440 after yr 1
earnings are revealed, why?
• If company chooses B, the stock price is close to 560 after yr 1
earnings are revealed, why?
• Company has a disincentive to choose the best project which is A
because it is too similar to C in the first year
• If managers seek to maximize the intrinsic value they should choose
A regardless
Dividends and Stock Repurchases:
Announcement Effects
• An announcement of a dividend increase normally
increases the stock price by about 2%
• If a company announces it is to cut its dividend
completely, the stock price decreases by about 9.5%
• Is paying dividends therefore a good decision?
– Dividends may be a costly signal conveying information that is
hidden from investors
– Paying dividends is, in effect, a cost to the shareholders to
ensure that current information is reflected in current prices
– The alternative: long term savings in signalling costs against the
cost of deviations between the current stock price and the
intrinsic value of equity
Dividends and Investment
Opportunities
• News may be
– Increased cash flow
– Increase in investment opportunities
• An increase in dividends signals increased cash flow (as
dividends then are more affordable) but is not consistent
with an increase in investment opportunities (as they are
then needed for investments)
• An increase/cut in dividends is, therefore, a more
complex signal than is suggested in previous slides
• Empirical evidence suggests that cuts are viewed more
favourably when the firms experience an increase in
investment opportunities
Capital Structure and Information
• Borrowing can also be thought of as a
costly signal:
– If mangers are convinced that future cash flow
is high then the most credible way of
communicating this information is to borrow
– If the manager is “lying”, the firm is going to
default on its debt liability and the manager
will be out of a job
• Firms with poor prospects find it hard to
“mimic” the same borrowing decisions
Empirical Evidence
• Event study methodology
• Leverage increasing transactions (debt-for-equity swaps)
have positive stock price response
• Leverage neutral transactions (debt-for-debt) have zero
response
• Leverage decreasings (equity-for-debt) have negative
stock price response
• Security sales (equity, debt) have negative stock price
response, and more so for equity than for debt
• Empirical evidence is consistent with information
theories (this week) but is also consistent with incentive
theories (last week)
Adverse Selection
• Sick people tend to see health/life insurance as cheap –
consequently they will be over-represented in the group
of buyers of this type of insurance
• Example: very expensive insurance that covers 100% of
all costs – or – cheap insurance that covers only 80% of
all costs
– In this case the sick people might migrate to the expensive type
of insurance and the healthy ones to the cheap type
• This is called adverse selection – buyers or sellers do
not always select themselves randomly but rather
according to their “type”
• This also plays a role in the sale of corporate securities
Managers have inside knowledge
and at the same time sell or buy
corporate securities
• Corporation can be expected to sell equity when
the stock is overvalued and buy back equity
when the stock is undervalued
• This makes sell transactions a bad signal and
buy transactions a good signal
• This makes equity a bad source of capital for
new investment, since it must be sold at a
discount to the current stock price (why?)
• Pecking-order theory: firms prefer retained
earnings to external capital, and external debt to
external equity, when financing investments
Readings
• Grinblatt/Titman chapter 19
Exercise
• A firm has already made an investment and is considering an
additional investment opportunity
– State of nature is good or bad, equal probabilities. Assume risk neutral
valuation with zero discount rates. Manager knows the true state of
nature
– Current investment has value 150 (good) or 50 (bad)
– NPV investment opportunity is 20 (good) or 10 (bad)
– Currently the firm is financed by equity only
– It plans to issue equity to finance the new investment, which costs 100
– To do:
• Set up the balance sheet before and after investment @ expected values
• Work out how much of the existing equity the firm needs to sell in order to
finance the investment
• Compare the value of the existing (old) equity with investment and without
investment in the good and the bad state
• If the manager acts in the interests of the existing shareholders, should he
always go ahead with investment. Explain.

Más contenido relacionado

Similar a Corporate Finance.ppt

How security are trade
How security are tradeHow security are trade
How security are tradesufyanraza1
 
David durand 1959 report
David durand 1959 reportDavid durand 1959 report
David durand 1959 reportAli Al-bada
 
Ucla mfe fis_-_2011_02_17_-_pension_fund_quant_-_ash
Ucla mfe fis_-_2011_02_17_-_pension_fund_quant_-_ashUcla mfe fis_-_2011_02_17_-_pension_fund_quant_-_ash
Ucla mfe fis_-_2011_02_17_-_pension_fund_quant_-_ashArthur Han CFA, FRM, CAIA
 
Chapter-1 & 2-Role-of-Financial-Markets-and-Institutions.ppt
Chapter-1 & 2-Role-of-Financial-Markets-and-Institutions.pptChapter-1 & 2-Role-of-Financial-Markets-and-Institutions.ppt
Chapter-1 & 2-Role-of-Financial-Markets-and-Institutions.pptWaelOmran4
 
Portfolio selection final
Portfolio selection finalPortfolio selection final
Portfolio selection finalsumit payal
 
Frank k. reilly &amp; keith132
Frank k. reilly &amp; keith132Frank k. reilly &amp; keith132
Frank k. reilly &amp; keith132saminamanzoor1
 
1stunit 090721112103-phpapp02
1stunit 090721112103-phpapp021stunit 090721112103-phpapp02
1stunit 090721112103-phpapp02artipradhan
 
Portfolio Risk & Return Part 2.pdf
Portfolio Risk & Return Part 2.pdfPortfolio Risk & Return Part 2.pdf
Portfolio Risk & Return Part 2.pdfRahul das
 
Pricing options by mathematics and probability
Pricing options by mathematics and probabilityPricing options by mathematics and probability
Pricing options by mathematics and probabilityVTrnMinh3
 
Capital structure
Capital structureCapital structure
Capital structureBhaskar T
 
3. risk and return
3. risk and return3. risk and return
3. risk and returnPooja Sakhla
 
Capital structure 1
Capital structure 1Capital structure 1
Capital structure 1Rakesh Kumar
 

Similar a Corporate Finance.ppt (20)

derivatives.ppt
derivatives.pptderivatives.ppt
derivatives.ppt
 
How security are trade
How security are tradeHow security are trade
How security are trade
 
David durand 1959 report
David durand 1959 reportDavid durand 1959 report
David durand 1959 report
 
Ch04
Ch04Ch04
Ch04
 
Lecture 01 F-409 Portfolio.pptx
Lecture 01 F-409 Portfolio.pptxLecture 01 F-409 Portfolio.pptx
Lecture 01 F-409 Portfolio.pptx
 
Ucla mfe fis_-_2011_02_17_-_pension_fund_quant_-_ash
Ucla mfe fis_-_2011_02_17_-_pension_fund_quant_-_ashUcla mfe fis_-_2011_02_17_-_pension_fund_quant_-_ash
Ucla mfe fis_-_2011_02_17_-_pension_fund_quant_-_ash
 
Chapter-1 & 2-Role-of-Financial-Markets-and-Institutions.ppt
Chapter-1 & 2-Role-of-Financial-Markets-and-Institutions.pptChapter-1 & 2-Role-of-Financial-Markets-and-Institutions.ppt
Chapter-1 & 2-Role-of-Financial-Markets-and-Institutions.ppt
 
Week2.pdf
Week2.pdfWeek2.pdf
Week2.pdf
 
Portfolio selection final
Portfolio selection finalPortfolio selection final
Portfolio selection final
 
Frank k. reilly &amp; keith132
Frank k. reilly &amp; keith132Frank k. reilly &amp; keith132
Frank k. reilly &amp; keith132
 
capstruc.ppt
capstruc.pptcapstruc.ppt
capstruc.ppt
 
SAPM.pptx
SAPM.pptxSAPM.pptx
SAPM.pptx
 
Sa ii
Sa iiSa ii
Sa ii
 
1stunit 090721112103-phpapp02
1stunit 090721112103-phpapp021stunit 090721112103-phpapp02
1stunit 090721112103-phpapp02
 
Portfolio Risk & Return Part 2.pdf
Portfolio Risk & Return Part 2.pdfPortfolio Risk & Return Part 2.pdf
Portfolio Risk & Return Part 2.pdf
 
Corporate Finance
Corporate FinanceCorporate Finance
Corporate Finance
 
Pricing options by mathematics and probability
Pricing options by mathematics and probabilityPricing options by mathematics and probability
Pricing options by mathematics and probability
 
Capital structure
Capital structureCapital structure
Capital structure
 
3. risk and return
3. risk and return3. risk and return
3. risk and return
 
Capital structure 1
Capital structure 1Capital structure 1
Capital structure 1
 

Más de MuhammadWaliUllah10

Enhancing Financial Management.ppt
Enhancing Financial Management.pptEnhancing Financial Management.ppt
Enhancing Financial Management.pptMuhammadWaliUllah10
 
Egypt Corporate & Regulatory Compliance by Dr._Khaled. PPP.ppt
Egypt Corporate & Regulatory Compliance by Dr._Khaled. PPP.pptEgypt Corporate & Regulatory Compliance by Dr._Khaled. PPP.ppt
Egypt Corporate & Regulatory Compliance by Dr._Khaled. PPP.pptMuhammadWaliUllah10
 
Bond Markert & Alternative Investment Ruls.ppt
Bond Markert & Alternative Investment Ruls.pptBond Markert & Alternative Investment Ruls.ppt
Bond Markert & Alternative Investment Ruls.pptMuhammadWaliUllah10
 
IFA Lecture 12 Current Liabilities, Provision and Contingencies.pptx
IFA Lecture 12 Current Liabilities, Provision and Contingencies.pptxIFA Lecture 12 Current Liabilities, Provision and Contingencies.pptx
IFA Lecture 12 Current Liabilities, Provision and Contingencies.pptxMuhammadWaliUllah10
 
IFA Lecture 11 Accounting for Taxes.pptx
IFA Lecture 11 Accounting for Taxes.pptxIFA Lecture 11 Accounting for Taxes.pptx
IFA Lecture 11 Accounting for Taxes.pptxMuhammadWaliUllah10
 
IFA Lecture 08 Revenue REcognition.pptx
IFA Lecture 08 Revenue REcognition.pptxIFA Lecture 08 Revenue REcognition.pptx
IFA Lecture 08 Revenue REcognition.pptxMuhammadWaliUllah10
 

Más de MuhammadWaliUllah10 (20)

BCommManagers_02.pptx
BCommManagers_02.pptxBCommManagers_02.pptx
BCommManagers_02.pptx
 
BCommManagers_01.pptx
BCommManagers_01.pptxBCommManagers_01.pptx
BCommManagers_01.pptx
 
RMPS_Forecasting.pdf
RMPS_Forecasting.pdfRMPS_Forecasting.pdf
RMPS_Forecasting.pdf
 
Finance and Accounting .ppt
Finance and Accounting .pptFinance and Accounting .ppt
Finance and Accounting .ppt
 
Final Web Presentation.ppt
Final Web Presentation.pptFinal Web Presentation.ppt
Final Web Presentation.ppt
 
Enhancing Financial Management.ppt
Enhancing Financial Management.pptEnhancing Financial Management.ppt
Enhancing Financial Management.ppt
 
Egypt Corporate & Regulatory Compliance by Dr._Khaled. PPP.ppt
Egypt Corporate & Regulatory Compliance by Dr._Khaled. PPP.pptEgypt Corporate & Regulatory Compliance by Dr._Khaled. PPP.ppt
Egypt Corporate & Regulatory Compliance by Dr._Khaled. PPP.ppt
 
Corporate finance2.ppt
Corporate finance2.pptCorporate finance2.ppt
Corporate finance2.ppt
 
Capital Investment Decision.ppt
Capital Investment Decision.pptCapital Investment Decision.ppt
Capital Investment Decision.ppt
 
Bond Markert & Alternative Investment Ruls.ppt
Bond Markert & Alternative Investment Ruls.pptBond Markert & Alternative Investment Ruls.ppt
Bond Markert & Alternative Investment Ruls.ppt
 
Basic Corporate Finance.ppt
Basic Corporate Finance.pptBasic Corporate Finance.ppt
Basic Corporate Finance.ppt
 
FFA Lecture Part D c.pptx
FFA Lecture Part D c.pptxFFA Lecture Part D c.pptx
FFA Lecture Part D c.pptx
 
FFA Lecture Part C.pptx
FFA Lecture Part C.pptxFFA Lecture Part C.pptx
FFA Lecture Part C.pptx
 
COA B2.pptx
COA B2.pptxCOA B2.pptx
COA B2.pptx
 
IFA Lecture 12 Current Liabilities, Provision and Contingencies.pptx
IFA Lecture 12 Current Liabilities, Provision and Contingencies.pptxIFA Lecture 12 Current Liabilities, Provision and Contingencies.pptx
IFA Lecture 12 Current Liabilities, Provision and Contingencies.pptx
 
IFA Lecture 11 Accounting for Taxes.pptx
IFA Lecture 11 Accounting for Taxes.pptxIFA Lecture 11 Accounting for Taxes.pptx
IFA Lecture 11 Accounting for Taxes.pptx
 
IFA Lecture 08 Revenue REcognition.pptx
IFA Lecture 08 Revenue REcognition.pptxIFA Lecture 08 Revenue REcognition.pptx
IFA Lecture 08 Revenue REcognition.pptx
 
IFA Lecture 07 lease.pptx
IFA Lecture 07 lease.pptxIFA Lecture 07 lease.pptx
IFA Lecture 07 lease.pptx
 
IFA Lecture 05.pptx
IFA Lecture 05.pptxIFA Lecture 05.pptx
IFA Lecture 05.pptx
 
IFA Lecture 04.pptx
IFA Lecture 04.pptxIFA Lecture 04.pptx
IFA Lecture 04.pptx
 

Último

PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docx
PROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docxPROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docx
PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docxPoojaSen20
 
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104misteraugie
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxheathfieldcps1
 
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across SectorsAPM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across SectorsAssociation for Project Management
 
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptxUnit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptxVishalSingh1417
 
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.pptApplication orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.pptRamjanShidvankar
 
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SDMeasures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SDThiyagu K
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionMaksud Ahmed
 
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphZ Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphThiyagu K
 
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17Celine George
 
fourth grading exam for kindergarten in writing
fourth grading exam for kindergarten in writingfourth grading exam for kindergarten in writing
fourth grading exam for kindergarten in writingTeacherCyreneCayanan
 
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..Disha Kariya
 
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdfMaking and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdfChris Hunter
 
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfKey note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfAdmir Softic
 
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdfAn Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdfSanaAli374401
 
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptxICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptxAreebaZafar22
 
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfHoldier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfagholdier
 

Último (20)

PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docx
PROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docxPROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docx
PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docx
 
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
 
Advance Mobile Application Development class 07
Advance Mobile Application Development class 07Advance Mobile Application Development class 07
Advance Mobile Application Development class 07
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
 
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across SectorsAPM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
 
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
 
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
 
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptxUnit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
 
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.pptApplication orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
 
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SDMeasures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphZ Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
 
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
 
fourth grading exam for kindergarten in writing
fourth grading exam for kindergarten in writingfourth grading exam for kindergarten in writing
fourth grading exam for kindergarten in writing
 
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
 
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdfMaking and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
 
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfKey note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
 
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdfAn Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
 
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptxICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
 
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfHoldier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
 

Corporate Finance.ppt

  • 1. AC210: Corporate Finance Norvald Instefjord ninstef@essex.ac.uk 5NW.4.9
  • 2. Introduction to Corporate Finance • What is finance? • What is the distinction between financial and real assets? • What is corporate finance? • What is the role of financial assets in corporate finance?
  • 3. Week 1 Financial Markets and Financial Instruments • How do firms finance their investments? – Earnings (free cash flow, internal capital) – Equity capital (external – public or private) – Debt capital (external) • Public and private capital • Trading of public capital – New issues – Secondary trading
  • 4. Equity Issues • First time a firm seeks public equity is called an initial public offering (IPO) – Primary issue: new equity is issued – Secondary issue: existing private equity is sold to outside investors (most privatisations take this form) – Legal and underwriting services provided by investment banks
  • 5. Debt Issues • Bank loans – not publicly traded • Corporate Bonds – traded actively in the secondary market • Debt capital and equity capital account for most of the firm’s financial capital
  • 6. Definition of Debt • Fixed claim – Specifies what needs to be repaid to the investor and when – Default risk – risk that the repayment plan is not fulfilled – Conversion options – covenants that allow debt to be reclassified as equity
  • 7. Definition of Equity • Residual claim – Does not specify a repayment plan – Repayment is defined as the residual: whatever is not claimed by other claim holders should go to the equity holders – Voting rights: Equity holders normally have a right to vote on important corporate decisions • Mergers, takeovers • Large investments • Board representation
  • 8. Trends in Corporate Finance • Globalisation • Deregulation • Financial innovation • Technological advances in the financial system • Securitization
  • 9. What you should take home • You should be able to – Understand the distinction between a fixed claim and a residual claim – List the main attributes of a debt claim – List the main attributes of an equity claim – Describe the ways in which firms raise funds for new investment – Describe the difference between private and public equity – Describe the difference between bank loans and corporate bonds
  • 10. Readings • Grinblatt/Titman: Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy – Ch 1: overview of the process of raising capital for investment – Ch 2: overview of the process of raising debt capital – Ch 3: overview of the process of raising equity capital
  • 11. Problems 1. Why do firms use underwriters when they issue new equity? 2. In what ways do you think it matters that debt holders have a fixed claim when equity holders have not? 3. In what ways do you think it matters that equity holders have voting rights when debt holders have not?
  • 12. Review problems 1. Invest 95 and sell for 102 – what is the return? 2. Invest 95 and sell for 102. Each transaction is charged a 1% trading commission – what is the return? 3. Invest 95 and sell for 102. You receive additional interest payments/dividends of 2 during the holding period. What is the return? 4. Invest 95 and sell for 110 three years later – what is the annual return on your investment? 5. Invest 95 now and another 98 next year. In the following year you sell your investment for a total of 202. What is the annual return on your investment?
  • 13. Week 2: Valuing Financial Assets: Portfolio Tools • Tool box – Expected portfolio return – Portfolio variance – Covariance between the return on two assets • Optimal investment – “Fair” price of an asset means that the value equals the purchasing price – Even if prices are “fair” there are still ways of investing your money that is better than others • Risk Aversion – Investors demand compensation for including risk in their portfolio
  • 14. Portfolio weights • A portfolio of financial assets can be represented in a number of ways – The number of shares held in the various stocks (e.g. 1000 shares in BT, 250 shares in Marks&Spencer etc.) – The dollar-value held in the various stocks (e.g. £2,500 in Lloyds Bank, £10,000 in Jarvis etc.) – As portfolio weights: the dollar-weight of the various stocks (e.g. if total portfolio is £100,000, then the portfolio weight of Lloyds is 0.025 and the portfolio weight of Jarvis is 0.1 etc.)
  • 15. From portfolio weights to portfolio expected return and variance • To determine the expected return and variance of a portfolio we need to know – The portfolio weights – The expected return on the individual assets – The variance of the return on the individual assets – The covariance between the return on any pair of assets
  • 16. Expectation, Variance and Covariance • Expected return (“average” return) is a location measure • Variance of return is a spread measure • Covariance is a measure of how the return of two assets are “related” (they can move in the same or opposite directions, or they can be uncorrelated) • If the returns move in the same directions, covariance is positive, if the returns move in the opposite directions, covariance is negative, and if uncorrelated, covariance is zero
  • 17. The input data for a portfolio of N assets • N expected returns • N variances • N(N-1)/2 covariances • Plus N portfolio weights • For FTSE100 there are therefore 100+100+100(99)/2 = 5150 data points that need to be estimated even before working out the portfolio weights
  • 18. Formulas              N i j i j i j i i i P N i N j j i j i P N i i i P r r Cov w w r Var w r Var r r Cov w w r Var r E w r E 1 2 1 1 1 ) , ( 2 ) ( ) ( ) , ( ) ( ) ( ) (
  • 19. Covariance and Correlation • Covariance is a measure of relatedness that depends on the unit of measurement, so if the return is measured as a percent (e.g. 10 percent) or as a desimal (e.g. 0.10) the covariance will be different • Correlation is a measure of relatedness that is normalized to be independent of the unit of measurement
  • 21. The Mean-Standard Deviation Approach to Investment • Risk averse investors don’t like risk • Variance averse investors don’t like risk that comes as variance • This is not the same in general – variance aversion is a special case of risk aversion • Portfolio theory takes the variance aversion approach – which in practice means that we assume investors wish to maximize their expected return given a certain variance, or minimize their variance given a certain expected return
  • 22. Mean-Standard Deviation for Two-Asset Investments ) , ( ) 1 ( 2 ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ) ( 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 1 r r Cov w w r Var w r Var w r Var r E w r wE r E P P        
  • 24. Mean-Std Dev for Portfolios of the Risk Free Asset and a Risky Asset w r Var r Var w r Var r r E w r r w r wE r E P F F F P ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ) ( ( ) 1 ( ) ( ) ( 2        
  • 25. Covariance as Marginal Variance • We can interpret the covariance between the return on a stock and the return on a portfolio as the stock’s marginal variance • That is, if we increase the stock’s portfolio weight marginally, the portfolio variance will increase by approximately twice the stock’s covariance with the portfolio
  • 27. What to take home • Understanding of expected values, variances, and covariances • Understanding of expected return and variance for a portfolio • Understanding of risk aversion and variance aversion • Understanding of the portfolio frontier • Appreciation of the linearity of expected return and standard deviation for portfolios consisting of the risk free asset and a risky portfolio
  • 28. Readings • Chapter 4 in Grinblatt/Titman
  • 29. Problems 1. Variance: Prove that E(x-E(x))2=Ex2- (E(x))2 2. Covariance: Prove that E(x-E(x))(y- E(y))=Exy-E(x)E(y) 3. Take a time series of returns 0.05, -0.03, 0.10, 0.04, -0.10, 0.20. Estimate the expected return and the variance of return.
  • 30. Week 3: From Mean-Variance to the CAPM • Capital Market Line – Finding the market portfolio • Two-fund Separation – Optimal diversification – Market vs idiosyncratic risk • CAPM expected returns relationship – Expected return on assets depend on their covariance (i.e. their relatedness) with the market portfolio – Estimating beta risk
  • 31. Capital Market Line • The line that goes through the risk free asset and the tangency portfolio • Identification? – Maximization procedure – Simplifying “trick”, the excess return on any asset divided by its covariance with the tangency portfolio, is constant
  • 32. Maximization programme to find the Capital Market Line • We can identify the frontier portfolios of risky assets • Consider investments consisting of the risk free asset and a frontier portfolio – these are represented by straight lines • For the frontier portfolio that is the tangency portfolio, the angle of the straight line is the steepest
  • 33. Capital Market Line cont.. ) ( ) ) ( ( )) ( ) ( ( max ) ( ) 1 ( ) , ( ) 1 ( 2 ) ( ) ( ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( max 2 2 T F B B A w B B A A T B A T T F T w r Var r r E r E r E w r Var w r r Cov w w r Var w r Var r E w r wE r E r Var r r E            
  • 34. Capital Market Line cont.. • The maximization programme normally leads to a fairly complicated equation – with two risky assets we get a quadratic equation to solve • In the class exercises you will be asked to have a go at such a problem
  • 35. Simplifying “trick”: finding the Capital Market Line • We know the expected return on all risky assets and the risk free return • The difference between the two is called the “excess return” for the asset • The excess return, divided by its covariance with the tangency portfolio, is always constant
  • 39. CAPM: Risk and Return • Since the excess return divided by the covariance with the tangency portfolio is constant across assets, we can derive important relationships between risk and return • The covariance with the tangency portfolio is, if solved for the tangency portfolio itself, equal to the variance of the tangency portfolio
  • 40. Risk and Return     F T i F i F T T T i F i T F T T i F i T F T T i F i r r E r r E r r E r Var r r Cov r r E r Var r r E r r Cov r r E r Var r r E r r Cov r r E              ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) , ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) , ( ) ( constant ) ( ) ( constant ) , ( ) ( 
  • 41. Security Market Line • The expected return of securities is linear in their beta-factors • In the (beta,expected return) plane, the line crossing through (0,rF) and (1,E(rT)) is called the security market line
  • 42. Properties of betas • Beta is linear: the beta of a portfolio of securities equals the portfolio-weighted average of the betas of the individual securities • An implication is that the beta of the assets of the company equals the value- weighted beta of the liabilities of the company
  • 43. Tracking portfolios • A portfolio tracks another perfectly if the difference in the returns of the portfolios is a constant (possibly zero) • Imperfect tracking: A portfolio consisting of a weight (1-b) in the risk free asset and a weight b in the tangency portfolio tracks a stock with beta β=b, because the two should have the same expected return
  • 44. Tracking Errors • The two investments should have the same expected return, which implies that the tracking error has zero expectation and zero value • Of course, investors do not like risk so they choose to hold the tracking portfolio instead of the stock • Because such diversification is free of cost, the tracking error is also free of cost (i.e. it has zero value)
  • 45. Estimating the risk free return • For risk free return use government bond or government bill data (long or short term instruments backed by the government) • The return offered on such instruments is a good proxy for the actual risk free return • Alternative, use the average return of a zero-beta risky stock, or the intercept with the y-axis if no zero-beta stock exists
  • 46. Estimating market risk premia • Estimate the long-run average return on a broad stock market index and subtract the risk free rate • Both the average stock market index return and the risk free return change over time • The change in the difference is more volatile than the changes in the individual time series. • Therefore, estimate the long-run average index return first. Do not estimate the difference between the market return and the risk free rate directly
  • 47. Beta estimation • A raw beta estimate can be obtained from historical covariance and variance estimates (or by a regression) • Average beta is one (this is the beta of the market index) • If the raw estimate exceeds (is below) one, we know there is a possibility that the raw beta is an overestimate (underestimate) • Raw beta estimates should be adjusted – i.e. they should be pulled down if they are above one or be bumped up if they are below one. • There are ways of optimally adjust beta estimates
  • 48. Beta Adjustment • Bloomberg adjustment – Adjusted beta = .66 times Unadjusted beta + .34 times One • Rosenberg adjustment – Adjustment also incorporates fundamental variables (industry variables, company characteristics such as size, etc..) • Also betas are adjusted sometimes to take into account infrequent trading problems
  • 49. What to take home • Two-fund separation • Capital Market Line vs Security Market Line • Risk-Return relationships • Tracking portfolio • Parameter estimation: problems and current practice
  • 51. Problems • What is the tracking portfolio for a real asset? • How would you estimate the beta of the assets of a firm that has traded debt and equity? • How would you estimate the beta of a company that has never traded?
  • 52. Week 4: From CAPM to Arbitrage Pricing Theory • Main purpose is to extend the valuation approach into more advanced and flexible valuation models • CAPM can be thought of as a “one-factor” model (returns are determined by movements in the market portfolio only) but has important empirical problems (systematic deviations from predictions) • APT extends to “multi-factor” pricing that can mitigate some of the CAPM’s empirical problems
  • 53. Risk Decomposition • The Market Model – One-factor (the return on the market portfolio) – Related to the CAPM model – The regression estimates of the market model generates raw beta-estimates for the CAPM • Risk Decomposition – Systematic (market) risk: asset risk that is explained by market movements – Unsystematic (diversifiable, idiosyncratic) risk: asset risk that cannot be explained by market movements
  • 56. APT: The arbitrage principle behind factor models F j i j j i i j j i j j j i j j i i j i i i i r r b b b r b b b b b b w b w wb f b a w f b a w r w r w f b a r                             free risk 1 solution has which 0 ) 1 ( Set ) )( 1 ( ) ( ) 1 ( ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~
  • 59. We do not know what the factors are! • Can be evaluated statistically – using a method called factor analysis • The output generates portfolios associated with each factor • Can use firm characteristics or macroeconomic variables as proxies for the factors
  • 60. Factor betas • The betas determine the asset’s sensitivity to the factors • A high loading on factor number 2 means that the asset is particularly sensitive to risks associated with factor 2 • Factor models extends into portfolio analysis since the factor betas of portfolio is just the value-weighted average factor beta for the individual assets in the portfolio
  • 61. Factor models: computing the variance-covariance structure • Recall that computing the variance-covariance structure requires a large number of estimates • For N assets, N variance estimates and N(N-1)/2 covariance estimates • N=100, 100 variance estimates and 100(99)/2 = 4950 covariance estimates • Using the market model, we can work out the covariance structure from the beta estimates, i.e. from the N beta estimates
  • 64. Tracking Portfolio • Objective: to design a portfolio that has certain factor betas (or factor loadings) • Why? The use of tracking portfolios are many – Risk management: if the company is subject to risks beyond its control, e.g. currency risk, it may create a tracking portfolio that offsets the risk – Capital allocation: the company may wish to allocate capital to investments that yield a greater return than their tracking portfolio and to reduce its exposure to investments that yield a smaller return than their tracking portfolio
  • 65. Designing a Tracking Portfolio • First, determine the number of relevant factors (guesswork, statistical analysis) • Second, determine the factor betas of the investment you wish to track (statistical analysis, comparison with existing traded companies) • Third, gather a collection of different assets with known factor loadings • Forth, calibrate your portfolio such that the portfolio factor beta equals the target factor beta for each factor
  • 67. Applying Pricing Theory • Use pricing models to investment analysis (optimal investment strategies in financial markets – diversification) • Use pricing models to calibrate investments (design of tracking portfolios) • Use pricing models as a benchmark for real investment (comparing real investment returns to the return on tracking portfolios)
  • 68. Readings • Chapter 6 in Grinblatt/Titman
  • 69. Problem • There are three relevant factors driving asset returns – The factor structure of the debt of the company is (0.01, 0,0) – The factor structure of the equity of the company is (2,5,1) – The company consists of 1/3 debt and 2/3 equity • What is the factor structure of the company’s real assets (investments)?
  • 70. Week 5: Investment Analysis – the case of Risk Free Projects • Apply pricing technology to real investment analysis • Net Present Value Rule • Complications – Sunk cost – Opportunity cost – EVA and IRR
  • 71. Fisher Separation • With different tastes, why should investors agree on investment policy? – Long-term vs short term – Risky vs Risk free • Fisher separation – Agreement is optimal regardless of taste – Net present value rule: Invest in all projects that cost less than the value of the project’s tracking portfolio – NPV = PV(future investment) – Investment cost
  • 72. Ingredients • Cash flows of our investment • Investment cost • Discount rates (if risk free projects – use a risk free discount rate)
  • 73. Present Value = sum of discounted cash flows T T r C r C r C C r r C C r r C C C C ) 1 ( ) 1 ( ) 1 ( portfolios tracking of value the of sum lue Present va etc... 2 year in ) 1 ( ) 1 ( to grows r) (1 C 1 year in ) 1 ( ) 1 ( to grows r) (1 C : portfolios Tracking , , , : flows Cash 3 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 1                                  
  • 74. Net Present Value T T r C r C r C I NPV ) 1 ( ) 1 ( 1 2 2 1 0          
  • 76. Value Additivity of NPVs B A B A B A NPV NPV NPV NPV NPV     : lue present va net has projects) two the of flows cash combined the (i.e. B A Project has B Project has A Project
  • 77. Mutually Exclusive Projects • This is an “either-or” situation – you can invest in project A or you can invest in project B, but you cannot invest in both at the same time • Both projects may have positive NPV so are worthwhile on their own • “Either-or” situations often arise naturally. For instance, all timing decisions are mutually exclusive. You can invest now or you can invest in the future, but you cannot invest both now and in the future.
  • 78. Which project to choose when they are mutually exclusive • The choice criterion is to maximize the net present value of investment. • Therefore, if you have two or more mutually exclusive projects to choose from you should choose the one with the most positive NPV.
  • 79. Capital Constraints • There are situations in which you may have more projects with positive NPV available than you have funds for investment – i.e. you have a budget constraint • Then the choice criterion is to invest in the projects that offer the greatest profitability index
  • 83. Economic Value Added • EVA is a profitability measure that has become widely used in corporations – initially to replace accounting earnings or profit measures • Accounting measures do not always measure economic performance (depreciation cost, for instance, is not a cash flow and should not be included in project evaluation) • Accounting measures are therefore not directly consistent with NPV • Economic Value Added is consistent with NPV
  • 84. EVA: Definition • Three components – Cash flow – Change in asset base – Economic return on assets • EVA(t) = Ct + (It – It-1) – rIt-1 • EVA(t) = Ct + It – (1+r)It-1 • Discounted sum of EVA(t) = Net Present Value
  • 85. EVA, cont. • Investment of 100 • The first year cash flow is 50 • The second year cash flow is 150 • Discount rate is 10% • Assets are depreciated by 50% in the first year and by 100% in the second year. • NPV = -100 + 50/1.1+150/1.12=69.42
  • 86. EVA, cont. • EVA(0) = -100(cash flow)+(100-0)(change in assets)- 0(0.1)(economic cost of initial assets) = 0 • EVA(1)=50(cash flow)+(50-100)(change in assets)- 100(0.1)(economic cost of initial assets) = -10 • EVA(2)=150(cash flow)+(0-50)(change in assets- 50(0.1)(economic cost of initial assets)= 95 • Discounted EVA = EVA(0)+EVA(1)/1.1+EVA(2)/1.12 = 69.42 = NPV
  • 87. IRR: Internal Rate of Return • Often managers base investment decision on the IRR instead of the NPV • The rule is: if IRR is greater than the discount rate (i.e. the cost of capital) then adopt the project • In many cases this leads to the same investment decision, as IRR is greater than the discount rate only if the NPV is positive • In other cases this is not true however, so to be safe always use NPV or EVA calculations
  • 89. Example • Investment cost = 100 • First year’s cash flow = 150 • Discount rate 10% • NPV = -100+150/1.1=36.36 • IRR: 0=-100+150/(1+IRR) yields 50% • Since 50% > 10% (IRR > discount rate) it is optimal to adopt the project
  • 90. Projects that have the cash flow profile of a loan • “Investment cost” = 150 • Next year’s cash flow = -100 • Discount rate = 10% • NPV = 150 – 100/1.1 = 59.09 • IRR: 0 = 150 – 100/(1+IRR) yields a negative IRR of -33.33% but this project is clearly profitable even though IRR < discount rate
  • 91. Problems with IRR • IRR criterion is sensitive to the type of cash flow (asset or liability?) • IRR is not unique in general (for T period projects there can be up to T different IRRs) • IRR is not appropriate for mutually exclusive projects as small projects with high IRR and small NPV might then be preferred to large projects with low IRR and large NPV
  • 92. IRR and mutually exclusive projects • Discount rate 2% • Project A: -10, -16, +30 • Project B: -10, 2, 11 • NPV(A) = 3.149 • NPV(B) = 2.534 • IRR(A) = 10.79% • IRR(B) = 15.36%
  • 93. Important points • Fisher separation • NPV definition • NPV with mutually exclusive projects (either-or) • NPV with budget constraints • EVA and NPV • IRR • IRR pitfalls
  • 95. Test for next week: • Readings chapter 4, 5, 6 and 10 • Important formulas – CAPM: exp return = risk free plus risk adjustment – Beta-factor: covariance/variance – Factor models: exp return = risk free plus risk adjustment • Risk free real investments – NPV rule – Profitability Index – EVA – IRR
  • 96. Very important formulas T T K K F M M F M F r C r C I NPV r r E r Var ) Cov(r,r r r E r r E ) 1 ( 1 : lue present va Net premium) risk denotes (where ) ( : models Factor ) ( : Beta ) ) ( ( ) ( : CAPM 1 0 1 1                        
  • 97. Sample test questions 1. The risk free return is 5% and the market index has an average return of 12%. What is the expected return for an asset with beta 1.5? 2. An investment costs 100,000 and offers a cash flow of 50,000 in year 1 and 150,000 in year 2. The discount rate is 5%. What is the net present value of the investment? Should you adopt the investment? Explain. 3. In a two-factor market, the factor betas of asset A are 1 and 0, and the factor betas of asset B are 0 and 1, respectively. The risk free return is 5%, and the average return on asset A and B are 10% and 15%, respectively. What are the risk premia associated with factor 1 and 2?
  • 98. Week 6: Investing in Risky Projects • Applying the CAPM and APT in the capital budgeting process • Key problem: estimating the cost of capital for risky projects – Applying CAPM and APT – Using comparison firms – The dividend discount model
  • 99. Risk Adjusted Discounting t t t F M F t r C E C E PV r r E r r C E ) 1 ( ) ( )) ( ( : Discount ) ( ( flow cash the of return market expected the Compute return market the of variance over the return, market the h return wit the of covariance the is beta (the flow cash with this associated risk beta the Compute t period in ) ( get) ll at we' exactly wh know not do (we flow cash future expected the Compute       
  • 100. Fundamental problem: Estimating the beta factor • Betas for traded equity are easy to estimate – we simply regress equity returns on the index return, and possibly adjust to take into account estimation error (e.g. Bloomberg adjustment) • Betas for projects are much more difficult to estimate as there simply does not exist a trading history • Possible solution: use comparison firms (firms we imagine has similar risk profile to the project in question)
  • 101. Using comparison firms • Asset base needs to be sufficiently similar to the planned investment • We need to adjust for leverage effects (the comparison firm may have debt) – In general, it is only the equity beta of the comparison firm we can estimate but we are really interested in the asset beta – The more the firm borrows, the higher the equity beta (even though the asset beta remains the same)
  • 104. Implementing risk adjusted discounting with comparison firms 08 . 1 0 . 1 79 . 0 85 . 0 s Wendy' 00 . 1 10 7 . 7 77 . 0 McDonalds 75 . 0 100 . 0 096 . 0 72 . 0 Chicken s Church' are betas asset The zero. to equal assumed is companes these of debt the of beta the and ly, respective s), (Wendy' 0.790 and 0.210 and ) (McDonalds 7.700 and 2.300 Chicken), s (Church' 0.096 and 0.004 are companies these of ues equity val and debt The ly. respective 1.08 and 1.00, 0.75, are companies three these of betas equity The s. Wendy' and s McDonald' Chicken, s Church' of beta average the has project A   
  • 107. APT and CAPM vs Alternative methods • A drawback with the APT and CAPM models is that they require a number of estimates: the risk free rate of return, the beta factor(s), the market risk premium and the factor risk premia. • It can in some circumstances be better to work with simpler model. The dividend growth model is an alternative to the APT and CAPM.
  • 109. What if comparison firms don’t exist? • In general there is little we can do • However, if there exist firms where one division is similar to our project we may be able to identify the relevant betas. • For instance, if you want to estimate the beta of the network division of television companies you can use the fact that these divisions play a varying role in generating the asset beta for these companies
  • 111. Pitfalls in using the comparison method • Project betas not the same as firm betas: mature projects generally lower beta than R&D projects etc • Growth opportunities are usually the source of high betas: company value often significantly linked to future growth opportunities as opposed to current investments
  • 112. Example • Investment cost 100,000 • Annual running cost 5,000 for 5 years • Expected revenue stream 50,000 for 5 years • Beta-risk of revenue stream 1.2 • Risk free return 5% • Expected market return 12%
  • 114. Comparison method, example • A firm with equity currently valued at 100,000 and outstanding debt worth 50,000 holds 25% cash and 75% of a risky asset on its balance sheet • The equity beta is 1.5 • You consider investing in a project very similar to the risky asset owned by this firm • The risk free rate is 5% and the expected return on the market is 12% • Work out the project beta and the cost of capital for your project
  • 115. Comparison method cont… 14.33% 5%) - 1.33(12% 5% capital of Cost 33 . 1 75 . 0 1 75 . 0 ) 0 ( 25 . 0 beta asset Total 1 100 50 1 5 . 1 beta asset total The 0 to close beta a has balance cash that the assume also and 0, to close very is beta debt Assume A A           RiskyAsset RiskyAsset    
  • 116. Readings • Grinblatt & Titman chapter 11 • I have not emphasized the certainty equivalent method
  • 117. Week 7: Taxes and Financing • Irrelevance in the absence of transaction costs and taxes (Modigliani-Miller) • Financing choices not neutral to taxation: – Level: corporate vs private tax rates – Timing: dividends can be deferred whereas interest payments on debt cannot
  • 118. Modigliani-Miller • The operating cash flow is divided into two components – Cash flow to debt holders – Cash flow to equity holders • Fundamental question: Does it matter how the split is made? • If it does we can create value also through financing choices (not only through investment choices)
  • 119. MM cont… • Modigliani-Miller proved that capital structure choices are irrelevant – the split does not matter • This proof rests on the absence of transaction costs of any kind: taxes, trading costs, and bankruptcy costs • The proof of the MM theorem uses a “no arbitrage” argument – financial markets do not admit “free lunches”, or trading strategies giving you a positive cash flow with no prior investment
  • 120. MM cont… • Consider two “versions” of the same firm – one version is U for unlevered (with no debt) and the other version L for levered (with debt) • The firms have otherwise the same operating cash flow X • The unlevered firm has value VU and the levered firm value VL
  • 121. MM cont… • The fundamental question is whether VU and VL differ • The cash flows of firm U’s equity holders is simply X • The cash flow of firm L’s debt holders is (1+r)D to the firm’s debt holders and X-(1+r)D to the firm’s equity holders, in total a cash flow of X also • The value of L is the combined value of the debt and the equity
  • 122. MM cont… • Suppose VL is smaller than VU • Then an investor can buy a 10% holding of L’s debt and a 10% holding of L’s equity, which entitles the investor to a 10% share in the total cash flow X. He would then go to the market and sell 10% of the cash flow X, which is valued at 10% of the value of U. This leaves him with zero future liability. • His trading gains are 10% of the difference between VU and VL, which we have assumed is positive • This cannot be possible in an arbitrage free market, so we can conclude that VL must be equal to or greater than VU
  • 123. MM cont… • Now suppose VU is smaller than VL • An investor buys 10% of the cash flow X and sells 10% of a claim that promises the cash flow (1+r)D. The net cash flow is 10% of a claim that pays X-(1+r)D at maturity, which is priced at 10% of the equity in L • The net future liability is zero, and the trading gains equal 10% of the difference between VL and VU, which we have assumed positive • Again, this is not consistent with arbitrage free markets • In conclusion, it must be the case that VU = VL and that capital structure is irrelevant
  • 124. What about risky debt? • When the corporate debt contract is risky it may be difficult to find a “synthetic” corporate debt contract if a real one does not exist • We must assume, therefore, that the markets are sufficiently complete in order to conclude that financing does not matter • Complete market = a market where the dimensionality of the asset structure equals the dimensionality of the uncertainty structure • If there are two states of nature (e.g. “good” and “bad”) then it suffices with two distinct assets to make the market complete
  • 125. Bankruptcy costs • The Modigliani-Miller theorem also assumes that there are no deadweight costs of bankruptcy • The debt holders may not get all their money back if the firm defaults, but this is not in itself enough to jeopardise the MM-theorem • There must also be deadweight costs or liquidation costs (i.e. the value of the assets in default is less than the value of the assets as a going concern)
  • 126. Taxes: Another important factor • The tax system is generally fairly complex with different tax rates for different individuals and institutions, and for different types of income • Therefore, it may be scope for “tax arbitrage” profits in financing
  • 127. After tax cash flow analysis • A constant after tax discount rate r • Tax rate for personal income from debt tD • Tax rate for personal income from equity tE • Corporate tax rate tC • Earnings before taxes and interest payments X • Earnings before taxes (X – kD) (k coupon rate, D nominal amount borrowed) • After tax personal income from debt kD(1-tD) • After tax earnings (X-kD)(1-tC) • After tax personal income from equity (X-kD)(1-tC)(1-tE)
  • 129. Equilibrium • If there is a positive discounted tax benefit firms choose to borrow more, and investors with higher personal tax rate on debt income is encouraged to enter the market. This implies a reduction of tax benefits of borrowing. • Reverse effect is there is a negative discounted tax benefit of borrowing • In equilibrium, we expect the tax benefit from borrowing to be equal to zero • This is the so-called “Miller’s equilibrium” described in Appendix 14A in the textbook
  • 130. Preferred stock • Preferred stock: dividends on preferred stock are not tax deductible at the corporate level as are interest payments on debt • This implies that corporate junior debt may be tax efficient relative to preferred stock • However, the US tax code allows a 70% tax exclusion for preferred dividends paid to corporate holders, so the yield on preferred stock is often lower (before tax) than on junior debt even though the debt has seniority over the preferred stock
  • 131. Investor conflicts? • Tax exempt equity holders prefer in general to reduce the borrowing of the firm so as to transfer income from debt repayments to dividend payments • High-tax bracket investor prefer the opposite • Often tax-exempt municipal bonds (or similar investments) offer yields that are greater than the after tax yield on corporate bonds for high-tax bracket investors • Thus, the firm can give these investors an advantage by increasing the firm’s borrowing, as this frees capital that the investors can use to invest in tax-exempt municipal bonds
  • 132. Inflation • We expect to see a one-to-one relationship between inflation and nominal interest rates - if inflation increases by one percentage point then so do nominal interest rates • Higher inflation, therefore, leads to higher nominal borrowing costs that yield in turn greater tax deductions • Therefore, the tax effect has greater bite in periods of high inflation
  • 133. Empirical evidence • Do firms with greater taxable earnings borrow more? – No, but this may be because firms in general rarely issue equity – Firms that perform poorly, therefore, tend to accumulate debt to meet their investments • Tax code changes that affect the relative tax benefit of borrowing should have an impact on corporate financing – Yes, US tax reform of 1986 which reduced the tax benefits of other things than debt (such as depreciation rules and investment tax credits) gave rise to an increase in borrowing among firms most affected – The firms less affected did not increase their borrowing to the same extent • Taxes matter but don’t explain everything
  • 134. Readings • Grinblatt/Titman chapter 14, including the appendix • 14.10 Are There Tax Advantages to Leasing not so relevant
  • 135. Exercises 1. A firm has assets valued at 100, and debt valued at 50. It plans to restructure its liability side by increasing its borrowing to 70 and paying a dividend of 20 to its shareholders. The debt has zero beta before and 0.001 beta after the recapitalization. The beta of the equity is 2 before the recapitalization. a) What are the values of the equity before and after the recapitalization? b) What is the beta of the assets of the firm? c) What is the beta of the equity after recapitalization? d) The recapitalization has increased the beta of the debt (and therefore the cost of debt capital). Has it also increased the beta of the equity? Does this mean that the total cost of financing has increased? Explain.
  • 136. Week 8: Taxes and Dividends • In frictionless markets dividends don’t matter • Why do firms nonetheless pay dividends? • Taxes and dividends • Stock returns and dividend yields – what is the connection? • Investment distortions caused by taxes in dividends
  • 137. Cash flow to shareholders • Shareholders earn money through holding equity that earns a cash flow (such as dividends) and capital gains (which can be realized through selling stock) • The cash distribution to shareholders is normally discretional – the company can decide how much cash flow to give their shareholders • Cash distribution comes in two forms – dividend payments and share repurchase schemes • Dividend payments do not affect the number of shares but will reduce the value of each share • Share repurchases do normally not affect the value of each share but will reduce the number of shares outstanding
  • 138. How much of earnings is cash flow to shareholders? • Dividend payout ratio: the ratio of dividends to earnings • In the US, this ratio has declined from about 22% in 1980 to about 14% in 1998 • Over the same period, the ratio of share repurchases to earnings increased from 3% to about 14% • The total ratio of cash flow to earnings has been relatively stable at about 25% of earnings
  • 139. Dividend yields • Dividend yield is the ratio of dividends per share over price per share • Typical pattern is that high-tech growth firms have low dividend yield and dividend payout ratios (Microsoft paid its very first dividend this year) • Stable, old economy companies such as mining, oil and manufacturing pay about half their earnings as dividends
  • 140. What is the optimal dividend payout ratio? • Assumption: frictionless economy (no transaction costs, taxes, or other frictions) • Investment policy unaffected by dividend payments • Modigliani-Miller Dividend Irrelevance Theorem: – The choice between paying dividends and repurchasing shares is a matter of indifference to shareholders
  • 141. Modigliani-Miller Irrelevance • Consider two identical equity financed firms, the only difference is dividend policy • Firm 1 pays 10m as dividends • Firm 2 repurchases stock worth 10m • After the end of the year, the firms are worth X • In the beginning each firm has 1m shares outstanding
  • 142. MM cont… • Each share eventually sells for X divided by the number of shares • Firm 2 buys back 10m worth of stock • If share price is p, and firm 2 buys back n shares, we know that pn=10m • We also know that p=X/(1m-n) • Suppose X = 150m • Solving both equations gives us n = (10m1m)/(X+10m), so we get n = 62,500, and p = 150m/(1m-62,500) = 160 • Firm 1: stock price is p = 150m/1m = 150, but each stock gives a dividend worth 10m/1m = 10, so the total value of each stock is 150+10 = 160 • Since shareholders get the same cash flow eventually, the shares must sell at the same price initially, i.e. dividend policy does not matter
  • 143. Taxes and cash distribution to shareholders • Classical tax system – Dividends taxed as ordinary income and capital gains at a lower rate than ordinary income – Dividends are not tax deductible at corporate level, so dividends are also subject to corporate taxation • Imputation system – Dividends are taxed as ordinary income but investors get a partial tax credit for corporate taxes (to offset personal taxes) – Dividends are not tax deductible at corporate level • Systems that eliminate double taxation – Dividends are tax deductible at corporate level and taxed as ordinary income at investor level
  • 144. Classical tax system • The classical tax system implies a tax disadvantage of dividend payments • Dividend $100, 35% tax implies an immediate tax liability of $35 • Share repurchase scheme: an investor sells $100 worth of shares. Suppose original cost was $76. This implies a taxable capital gain of $24. Taxed at 20%, this implies an immediate tax liability of $4.8 • Share repurchase scheme much cheaper than paying dividends
  • 145. Tax avoidance schemes • In theory, investors can often invest in a scheme that gives an immediate tax relief against a deferred future tax liability • In practice, investors do not take advantage of these schemes but instead choose to pay taxes (or are unable to invest in tax avoidance schemes) on the received dividends • The question is, therefore, why corporations continue to pay dividends when they are so tax inefficient
  • 146. Dividend clienteles • Some investors do not pay taxes • These investors will, everything else being equal, prefer high dividend yield firms to low dividend yield firms as they do not pay tax on the dividend • Firms might adopt different dividend policies to attract different investor clienteles • Empirical evidence suggests that investors’ portfolios have dividend yields that are related to their tax status (high tax bracket investors choose low dividend yield stocks and vice versa)
  • 147. Dividend payments and stock returns • Do stocks with high dividend yield compensate investors for the tax disadvantage? • Higher returns should then lead to lower values, reflecting the higher discount rates applied to future cash flows • Research has focused on two returns effects – Ex-dividend day behaviour of stock prices – Whether cross-sectional dividend yield differences affect expected returns
  • 148. Ex-dividend day price drop • If you buy the stock on the day before the ex-dividend day, you are entitled to the future value of the stock and the current dividend payment • If you buy the stock on the ex-dividend day, you are entitled only to the future value of the stock • The stock price should, therefore, drop on the ex-dividend day to reflect the dividend payment • Empirical results from the 1960s indicate that the ex-dividend day price drop is about 77.7% of the dividend payment on average, but was higher (90%) for dividend payments greater than 5% of the stock price, and lower (50%) for the smallest dividends. • These results indicate a tax effect (investors discount a tax rate of around 22.3% on dividends), and a clientele effect (investors with different tax rates hold portfolios with different dividend yields)
  • 149. Ex-dividend day cont… • Transaction cost argument – Consider buying a stock at $20 before the ex-div day, receive a $1 dividend, then sell the stock for $19.20. This yields $1 taxable profits and $(20-19.20) = $0.80 tax deductible losses. The net profit is $0.20 less taxes, but it is still arbitrage profits. The stock needs to drop by the full amount to preclude arbitrage profits. – If there is a $0.10 per share transaction cost, the investor receives taxable profits of $1 in dividends, and incur $0.80 in tax deductible losses. The net profit is $0.20, but the investor must also pay $0.10 in transaction costs, so the net profit is only $0.10 less taxes. If the stock drops to $19.10, therefore, there are no arbitrage profits to be made. – If the dividend payment is only $0.40, the necessary price drop is $0.30 to prevent arbitrage profits. That is, the price drop is greater for high dividend yielding stocks in percentage terms (as the clientele effect predicts). • Price drop less than the dividend payment is also observed in countries that do not have a classical tax system, suggesting this is not a tax driven phenomenon at all
  • 150. Cross-sectional relation between dividend yield and stock returns • If dividends are more heavily taxed than capital gains, the expected return must be greater for high dividend yield stocks. • Empirically, stocks with high dividend yields have higher returns, but the relationship is not straightforward • The relationship is U-shaped, with zero dividend yield stocks have higher expected return than stocks with low dividend yield, but for stocks paying dividends, the expected return increases with the dividend yield
  • 151. How dividend taxes affect financing and investment decisions • Marginal tax rate of 50% • Company has a choice between paying $1m in dividends or retain the earnings • Retained earnings yield 6% after corporate taxes (alternative II) • Dividends yield 7% before personal taxes in corporate bonds (alternative I) • Alternative I yields $500,000 to invest at 7%, which after tax yields $17,500 per year • Alternative II yields $60,000 in extra dividend payments per year, which yields $30,000 after tax to the investor • If you are a zero tax payer, however, alternative I yields $1,000,000 to invest at 7%, which equals $70,000, and alternative II only $60,000 in additional dividends per year. • Investors with different tax rates are likely to disagree with regard to the dividend policy the firm should pursue
  • 152. The general principle • Investors prefer retained earnings if (1-corporate tax rate) x (pretax return internally at corporate level) > (after tax return at investor level) • This has implications for investment policy as well – Tax-exempt and tax-paying investors agree on externally funded projects but may disagree on internally funded ones (tax exempt investors require higher return on internal investment than tax-paying investors)
  • 154. Exercises 1. A stock trades at 100p per share (prior to ex-dividend day) and the firm will pay a dividend of 10p per share. a) Work out the ex-dividend day price if investors pay 40% tax on dividends and the ex-dividend day price equals the initial price less after-tax dividend payment b) Work out the minimum transaction cost per share that prevents tax-arbitrage by a tax-paying investor c) Suppose the dividend payment was 50p per share. What is your answer to a) and b) now? d) Suppose the actual transaction cost is 2p per share. What are the arbitrage free price drops in a) and c) above now? e) What are the “implied” tax rates on dividends in d)?
  • 155. Week 9: Managerial Incentives and Corporate Finance • Manager – shareholder conflicts – Occidental Petroleum and founder/CEO Armand Hammer case in the textbook – Maxwell Communications and Robert Maxwell • How such conflicts affect investment, financing, and ownership structure • How such conflicts can be mitigated by executive compensation schemes
  • 156. Separation of ownership and control • The separation of ownership and control is beneficial in terms of diversification and optimal investment while keeping a stable management team in control of the firm • But it can be harmful if the management team is more interested in pursuing their own interest as opposed to their shareholders’ interests • In what way do their interests differ? – Managers represent investors, customers, suppliers, and employees – not just investors – Managers get utility from non-financial benefits such as status, perks, job-security etc and are willing to spend corporate resources on these even though they are likely to be negative NPV projects
  • 157. Factors that determine the manager-shareholder conflict • Proportions of stock owned by the manager • Managerial entrenchment and lack of means to control managers – Diffuse ownership structure (no individual manager benefits enough to take action) – Proxy fights (shareholder revolt at general meeting) are very expensive and difficult to organize • Bonus schemes not performance sensitive enough • Changes in corporate governance have made managers more accountable in recent years
  • 158. Ownership structure • Ownership structure is on the whole more concentrated than we would expect (CAPM advocates diversification), particularly outside the US/UK • Ownership concentration a response to weak legal protection of shareholders’ interests • UK/US have the strongest protection and the most diffuse ownership structure • Managers tend to keep a significant ownership stake in firms where the incentive conflict with the shareholders is the greatest • In many internet IPOs, the managers kept a large share of their holding in order to get a higher price in the IPO (lock in clauses) • Eg. Lastminute.com – Martha Lane-Fox and Brent Hoberman (founders – Hoberman still manager) were still large owners after IPO and were prevented from selling their share for a given time period after the IPO • Firms with higher concentration of management ownership have higher market values relative to their book values, provided management share is not too big. If it gets above 5%, managers become “entrenched” which allows them to pursue own interests more
  • 159. How managers distort investment decisions • Managers prefer investments that fit the manager’s expertise – Makes him (her) more indispensable • Investments in visible/fun industries – Raising the manager’s external profile (and his potential future job opportunities and wages) • Investments that pay off early – Financial success in the short run can increase bonus, reduce the risk of losing job, increase the possibility of raising more capital • Investments that reduce risk and increase the scope of the firm – To avoid bankruptcy the manager seeks relatively safe investments and may take a portfolio approach to investments
  • 160. Capital structure and managerial control • Managers are likely to prefer equity to debt because they are interested in minimizing the probability of default • Shareholders may, therefore, prefer debt financing as debt is a good way to discipline managers (the fear of losing job is a good motivator) • Empirical investigations show there is a positive relationship between leverage and – Percentage of executive pay tied to performance – Percentage of equity owned by managers – Percentage of investment bankers on the board of directors – Percentage of equity owned by large individual investors • Debt is a good way to curb overinvestment • Debt engages often a bank who is a good monitor of management
  • 161. Executive compensation • The problem of incentivizing managers is often called a principal-agent problem – Tenant farmer works the land of a land-owner. If compensated too much in terms of output, the tenant farmer must bear all the risk influencing output (weather etc). If compensated too little in terms of output, the tenant farmer doesn’t put in the required effort. – Compensation is a matter of balancing the two concerns: Called the problem of designing the optimal incentive contract – Effort (input) cannot be observed, otherwise compensation could be tied to effort instead of output – Design objective is to minimize the agency costs of delegated control
  • 162. Performance based executive compensation • Jensen and Murphy (1990) found that a $1000 increase in firm value is associated with a $3 increase in CEO bonus (a $10m jet costs the CEO $30,000 just in lost bonus payments) • Some disagreement about this result, as it may have underestimated the real sensitivity by ignoring longer term impact on bonus payments • Substantial differences in pay-for-performance sensitivity across firms – Some explained by the agency costs of delegated control – Some explained by the risk of the firm • Over time, the pay-for-performance sensitivity has been increasing • Adoption of performance-based pay is generally a positive signal to the investors • What about relative performance sensitivity (pay linked to the position of the company relative to the average for the industry)? Relative performance- pay is rarely observed, but can be costly to investors in terms of price wars and overly aggressive competition. • Stock-based performance versus earnings-based performance. Stock based performance is much noisier than earnings-based performance, but in return earnings can be manipulated by the manager
  • 163. Mergers, Spin-offs, Carve Outs • It may be easier to design an optimal compensation contract for a small, single-unit, firm than for a multi-divisional conglomerate • Solution may be a spin-off (a division set up as an independent firm by distributing shares in the new firm to the existing investors) or a carve-out (do an IPO of the division and sell to new investors) • Spin-offs and carve-outs are positive signals • Mergers create the opposite effect, and in particular conglomerate mergers can be seen as a negative signal to investors as they affect managerial incentives negatively (conglomerate mergers are relatively rare now but were popular in the 1960s and 70s) • Many spin-offs and carve-outs are reversing prior conglomerate mergers
  • 165. Exercises 1. The manager of a firm considers investing £1m of free cash flow (earnings currently held in a bank account) in a project that has private value £10,000 to the manager but NPV of - £200,000 to the investors. What is the optimal decision for the manager if a) He has fixed pay? b) He has in addition a bonus scheme where an increase of £1000 in the stock value leads to an increase of £10 to the manager? c) What is the optimal bonus scheme for the manager in this case?
  • 166. Week 10: Information and Financial Decisions • Key premise: managers have better information than investors • What managers do, therefore, conveys information to the market • Managers can – Distort accounts to manipulate the information flow – Reveal information through dividend policy, capital structure choice, and investment decisions • Empirical evidence: how stock prices react to various financial decisions
  • 167. What can better informed individuals do? • Signals: they act in a way that conveys their information – Difference between “cheap talk” and “credible action” – Signals need to be costly • Pooling: they act in a way that everybody else act in order not to reveal information – It is too expensive to send a signal • Manipulation – Actions: Investors overestimate the true cost of signalling – Reporting: “Bad” reports attract attention – it may be easier to disguise bad outcomes by submitting an “average” report
  • 168. Distortions to managerial incentives • Managers seek to maximize the share price • The share price may, however, deviate from the “intrinsic value” (the full information price) • Long term investors prefer that managers maximize the intrinsic value (which eventually transpires) • Short term investors prefer that managers maximize the current share price (which may be distorted due to lack of information) • The conflict is, therefore, essentially one of short- termism versus long-termism
  • 169. Why do managers care about the current share price? • New issues or the managers may plan to sell private stock • Low prices attract bidders in takeovers • Managerial compensation directly linked to stock price • Customers or employees may flee the company if the stock price goes too low
  • 170. Earnings manipulation • The same underlying profits can be reported in different ways as earnings – Depends on the choice of depreciation method – Choice of inventory valuation method (FIFO LIFO) – The estimates of the economic value of assets, the estimates of the cost of guarantees or warranties issued, the estimates of the pension liability of the firm, the discount rates used for valuation of leases and pensions etc. • There is a tendency to inflate reported earnings to increase the current stock price • But managers may also find it useful sometimes to deflate reported earnings – For instance when the manager has just been hired – When applying for government subsidies or tariff protection against foreign competitors
  • 171. Short-termism in investment • Bias towards short term projects because these makes it clear very quickly whether the investment is a good one • Example: – Project A: yr 1 cash flow 40; yr 2-11 cash flow 80 per year; PV 840 – Project B: yr 1 cash flow 60; yr 2-11 cash flow 50 per year; PV 560 – Project C: yr 1 cash flow 40; yr 2-11 cash flow 40; PV 440 • Investors think C is much more realistic than A or B • If company chooses A, the stock price is close to 440 after yr 1 earnings are revealed, why? • If company chooses B, the stock price is close to 560 after yr 1 earnings are revealed, why? • Company has a disincentive to choose the best project which is A because it is too similar to C in the first year • If managers seek to maximize the intrinsic value they should choose A regardless
  • 172. Dividends and Stock Repurchases: Announcement Effects • An announcement of a dividend increase normally increases the stock price by about 2% • If a company announces it is to cut its dividend completely, the stock price decreases by about 9.5% • Is paying dividends therefore a good decision? – Dividends may be a costly signal conveying information that is hidden from investors – Paying dividends is, in effect, a cost to the shareholders to ensure that current information is reflected in current prices – The alternative: long term savings in signalling costs against the cost of deviations between the current stock price and the intrinsic value of equity
  • 173. Dividends and Investment Opportunities • News may be – Increased cash flow – Increase in investment opportunities • An increase in dividends signals increased cash flow (as dividends then are more affordable) but is not consistent with an increase in investment opportunities (as they are then needed for investments) • An increase/cut in dividends is, therefore, a more complex signal than is suggested in previous slides • Empirical evidence suggests that cuts are viewed more favourably when the firms experience an increase in investment opportunities
  • 174. Capital Structure and Information • Borrowing can also be thought of as a costly signal: – If mangers are convinced that future cash flow is high then the most credible way of communicating this information is to borrow – If the manager is “lying”, the firm is going to default on its debt liability and the manager will be out of a job • Firms with poor prospects find it hard to “mimic” the same borrowing decisions
  • 175. Empirical Evidence • Event study methodology • Leverage increasing transactions (debt-for-equity swaps) have positive stock price response • Leverage neutral transactions (debt-for-debt) have zero response • Leverage decreasings (equity-for-debt) have negative stock price response • Security sales (equity, debt) have negative stock price response, and more so for equity than for debt • Empirical evidence is consistent with information theories (this week) but is also consistent with incentive theories (last week)
  • 176. Adverse Selection • Sick people tend to see health/life insurance as cheap – consequently they will be over-represented in the group of buyers of this type of insurance • Example: very expensive insurance that covers 100% of all costs – or – cheap insurance that covers only 80% of all costs – In this case the sick people might migrate to the expensive type of insurance and the healthy ones to the cheap type • This is called adverse selection – buyers or sellers do not always select themselves randomly but rather according to their “type” • This also plays a role in the sale of corporate securities
  • 177. Managers have inside knowledge and at the same time sell or buy corporate securities • Corporation can be expected to sell equity when the stock is overvalued and buy back equity when the stock is undervalued • This makes sell transactions a bad signal and buy transactions a good signal • This makes equity a bad source of capital for new investment, since it must be sold at a discount to the current stock price (why?) • Pecking-order theory: firms prefer retained earnings to external capital, and external debt to external equity, when financing investments
  • 179. Exercise • A firm has already made an investment and is considering an additional investment opportunity – State of nature is good or bad, equal probabilities. Assume risk neutral valuation with zero discount rates. Manager knows the true state of nature – Current investment has value 150 (good) or 50 (bad) – NPV investment opportunity is 20 (good) or 10 (bad) – Currently the firm is financed by equity only – It plans to issue equity to finance the new investment, which costs 100 – To do: • Set up the balance sheet before and after investment @ expected values • Work out how much of the existing equity the firm needs to sell in order to finance the investment • Compare the value of the existing (old) equity with investment and without investment in the good and the bad state • If the manager acts in the interests of the existing shareholders, should he always go ahead with investment. Explain.