SlideShare una empresa de Scribd logo
1 de 233
MGB Portfolio Management I 
MARKET EFFICIENCY
MGB Portfolio Management I 
RANDOM WALK
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Random Walk 
In 1973 when author Burton Malkiel wrote "A Random Walk Down Wall Street", which 
remains on the top-seller list for finance books. 
 Strict Definition 
─ Successive stock returns are independent and identically distributed. This implies that past 
movement or trend of a stock price or market cannot be used to predict its future movement. 
 Common Definition 
─ Price changes are essentially unpredictable 
This is the idea that stocks take a random and unpredictable path. A follower of the 
random walk theory believes it's impossible to outperform the market without 
assuming additional risk. 
Critics of the theory, however, contend that stocks do maintain price trends over time 
- in other words, that it is possible to outperform the market by carefully selecting 
entry and exit points for equity investments.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Random Walk 
Financial Economists were disturbed as this seemed to 
imply that stock markets were dominated by some 
erratic market psychology or some “animal spirit” that 
followed no logical rules. 
It soon became apparent however, that random price 
movements indicated a well-functioning or efficient market, 
not an irrational one.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Random Walk 
And why is that? 
Because any new information that could be used to predict stock performance must 
already reflect in the stock price. As soon as any new information is available that can 
impact stock prices, investors will buy/sell the security immediately to its fair level 
where only ordinary return can be expected (rate of return commensurate with the 
risk). 
However, if prices are bid immediately to fair levels. On getting new information, it 
must be that the increase/decrease is due to only that new information. But New 
information, by definition, must be unpredictable. If not, then the information would 
already be priced into the price of the security! 
So, stock prices should follow a random walk, that is, price changes should be random 
and unpredictable. Randomly evolving prices are a result of intelligent investors 
discovering relevant information and by their action moving the prices.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The Efficient Market Hypothesis 
 Expectations are very important in our financial system. 
─ Expectations of returns, risk, and liquidity impact asset demand 
─ Inflationary expectations impact bond prices 
─ Expectations not only affect our understanding of markets, but also 
how financial institutions operate. 
 To better understand expectations, we examine the efficient 
markets hypothesis. 
─ Framework for understanding what information is useful and what is 
not 
─ However, we need to validate the hypothesis with real market data. 
The results are mixed, but generally supportive of the idea.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The Efficient Market Hypothesis 
 In sum, we will look at the basic reasoning behind the efficient 
market hypothesis. We also examine empirical evidence 
examining this idea: 
─ The Efficient Market Hypothesis 
─ Evidence on the Efficient Market Hypothesis 
─ Behavioral Finance
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Market Hypothesis 
• The rate of return for any position is the sum of the capital gains (Pt+1 – Pt) 
plus any cash payments (C): 
• At the start of a period, the unknown element is the future price: Pt+1. But, 
investors do have some expectation of that price, thus giving us an 
expected rate of return.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Market Hypothesis 
The Efficient Market Hypothesis views the expectations as equal 
to optimal forecasts using all available information. This implies: 
Assuming the market is in equilibrium: 
Re = R* [market’s equilibrium return] 
Put these ideas together: efficient market hypothesis 
Rof = R*
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Market Hypothesis 
Rof = R* 
•This equation tells us that current prices in a financial market 
will be set so that the optimal forecast of a security’s return 
using all available information equals the security’s 
equilibrium return. 
•As a result, a security’s price fully reflects all available 
information in an efficient market. 
•Note, R* depends on risk, liquidity, other asset returns …
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Rationale Behind the Hypothesis 
 When an unexploited profit opportunity arises on a 
security (so-called because, on average, people would 
be earning more than they should, given the 
characteristics of that security), investors will rush to 
buy until the price rises to the point that the returns 
are normal again. 
 Investors do not leave $ bills lying on the sidewalk.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Rationale Behind the Hypothesis 
• Why efficient market hypothesis makes sense 
If Rof > R* → Pt ↑ → Rof ↓ 
If Rof < R* → Pt ↓ → Rof ↑ 
Until Rof = R* 
• All unexploited profit opportunities eliminated 
• Efficient market condition holds even if there are uninformed, 
irrational participants in market
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Rationale Behind the Hypothesis 
 In an efficient market, all unexploited profit 
opportunities will be eliminated. 
 Not every investor need be aware of every security 
and situation. 
 Only a few investors (even 1 big one) are needed to 
eliminate unexploited profit opportunities and push 
the market price to its equilibrium level.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Capital Markets 
• In an efficient capital market, security prices adjust rapidly to 
the arrival of new information, therefore the current prices of 
securities reflect all information about the security 
• Whether markets are efficient has been extensively 
researched and remains controversial
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Why Should Capital Markets Be Efficient? 
The premises of an efficient market 
– A large number of competing profit-maximizing participants analyze and 
value securities, each independently of the others 
– New information regarding securities comes to the market in a random 
fashion 
– Profit-maximizing investors adjust security prices rapidly to reflect the 
effect of new information 
Conclusion: the expected returns implicit in the current price of a 
security should reflect its risk
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Alternative Efficient Market Hypotheses (EMH) 
• Random Walk Hypothesis – changes in security prices occur 
randomly 
• Fair Game Model – current market price reflect all available 
information about a security and the expected return based 
upon this price is consistent with its risk 
• Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) - divided into three sub-hypotheses 
depending on the information set involved
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Market Hypotheses (EMH) 
• Weak-Form EMH - prices reflect all security-market 
information 
• Semistrong-form EMH - prices reflect all public 
information 
• Strong-form EMH - prices reflect all public and 
private information
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Weak-Form EMH 
• Current prices reflect all security-market information, 
including the historical sequence of prices, rates of return, 
trading volume data, and other market-generated information 
• This implies that past rates of return and other market data 
should have no relationship with future rates of return
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Current security prices reflect all public information, 
including market and non-market information 
• This implies that decisions made on new information 
after it is public should not lead to above-average 
risk-adjusted profits from those transactions
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Strong-Form EMH 
• Stock prices fully reflect all information from public 
and private sources 
• This implies that no group of investors should be able 
to consistently derive above-average risk-adjusted 
rates of return 
• This assumes perfect markets in which all 
information is cost-free and available to everyone at 
the same time
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Weak-Form EMH 
• Statistical tests of independence between rates of 
return 
– Autocorrelation tests have mixed results 
– Runs tests indicate randomness in prices
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Weak-Form EMH 
• Comparison of trading rules to a buy-and-hold policy is 
difficult because trading rules can be complex and 
there are too many to test them all 
– Filter rules yield above-average profits with small filters, but 
only before taking into account transactions costs 
– Trading rule results have been mixed, and most have not 
been able to beat a buy-and-hold policy
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Weak-Form EMH 
• Testing constraints 
– Use only publicly available data 
– Include all transactions costs 
– Adjust the results for risk
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Weak-Form EMH 
• Results generally support the weak-form EMH, but results are 
not unanimous
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests of the Semistrong Form of Market Efficiency 
Two sets of studies 
• Time series analysis of returns or the cross section 
distribution of returns for individual stocks 
• Event studies that examine how fast stock prices 
adjust to specific significant economic events
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Test results should adjusted a security’s rate of return for the 
rates of return of the overall market during the period 
considered 
Arit = Rit - Rmt 
where: 
Arit = abnormal rate of return on security i during period t 
Rit = rate of return on security i during period t 
Rmt =rate of return on a market index during period t
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Time series tests for abnormal rates of return 
– short-horizon returns have limited results 
– long-horizon returns analysis has been quite successful 
based on 
• dividend yield (D/P) 
• default spread 
• term structure spread 
– Quarterly earnings reports may yield abnormal returns due 
to 
• unanticipated earnings change
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Quarterly Earnings Reports 
– Large Standardized Unexpected Earnings (SUEs) result in 
abnormal stock price changes, with over 50% of the 
change happening after the announcement 
– Unexpected earnings can explain up to 80% of stock drift 
over a time period 
• These results suggest that the earnings surprise is 
not instantaneously reflected in security prices
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• The January Anomaly 
– Stocks with negative returns during the prior year had 
higher returns right after the first of the year 
– Tax selling toward the end of the year has been mentioned 
as the reason for this phenomenon 
– Such a seasonal pattern is inconsistent with the EMH
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Other calendar effects 
– All the market’s cumulative advance occurs during the 
first half of trading months 
– Monday/weekend returns were significantly negative 
– For large firms, the negative Monday effect occurred 
before the market opened (it was a weekend effect), 
whereas for smaller firms, most of the negative 
Monday effect occurred during the day on Monday (it 
was a Monday trading effect)
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Predicting cross-sectional returns 
– All securities should have equal risk-adjusted returns 
• Studies examine alternative measures of size or 
quality as a tool to rank stocks in terms of risk-adjusted 
returns 
– These tests involve a joint hypothesis and are dependent 
both on market efficiency and the asset pricing model 
used
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Price-earnings ratios and returns 
– Low P/E stocks experienced superior risk-adjusted results 
relative to the market, whereas high P/E stocks had 
significantly inferior risk-adjusted results 
– Publicly available P/E ratios possess valuable information 
regarding future returns 
– This is inconsistent with semistrong efficiency
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Price-Earnings/Growth Rate (PEG) ratios 
– Studies have hypothesized an inverse relationship between 
the PEG ratio and subsequent rates of return. This is 
inconsistent with the EMH 
– However, the results related to using the PEG ratio to 
select stocks are mixed
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• The size effect (total market value) 
– Several studies have examined the impact of size on the 
risk-adjusted rates of return 
– The studies indicate that risk-adjusted returns for 
extended periods indicate that the small firms consistently 
experienced significantly larger risk-adjusted returns than 
large firms 
– Firm size is a major efficient market anomaly 
– Could this have caused the P/E results previously studied?
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• The P/E studies and size studies are dual tests of the 
EMH and the CAPM 
• Abnormal returns could occur because either 
– markets are inefficient or 
– market model is not properly specified and provides 
incorrect estimates of risk and expected returns
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Adjustments for riskiness of small firms did not 
explain the large differences in rate of return 
• The impact of transactions costs of investing in small 
firms depends on frequency of trading 
– Daily trading reverses small firm gains 
• The small-firm effect is not stable from year to year
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Neglected Firms 
– Firms divided by number of analysts following a stock 
– Small-firm effect was confirmed 
– Neglected firm effect caused by lack of information 
and limited institutional interest 
– Neglected firm concept applied across size classes 
– Another study contradicted the above results
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of Semistrong-form EMH 
• Trading volume 
– Studied relationship between returns, market value, and 
trading activity. 
– Size effect was confirmed. But no significant difference 
was found between the mean returns of the highest and 
lowest trading activity portfolios
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Ratio of Book Value of a firm’s Equity to Market Value of 
its equity 
– Significant positive relationship found between current 
values for this ratio and future stock returns 
– Results inconsistent with the EMH 
• Size and BV/MV dominate other ratios such as E/P ratio or 
leverage 
• This combination only works during expansive monetary 
policy
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Firm size has emerged as a major predictor of future returns 
• This is an anomaly in the efficient markets literature 
• Attempts to explain the size anomaly in terms of superior risk 
measurements, transactions costs, analysts attention, trading 
activity, and differential information have not succeeded
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Event studies 
– Stock split studies show that splits do not result in 
abnormal gains after the split announcement, but 
before 
– Initial public offerings seems to be underpriced by 
almost 18%, but that varies over time, and the price is 
adjusted within one day after the offering 
– Listing of a stock on an national exchange such as the 
NYSE may offer some short term profit opportunities 
for investors
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Event studies (continued) 
– Stock prices quickly adjust to unexpected world events 
and economic news and hence do not provide 
opportunities for abnormal profits 
– Announcements of accounting changes are quickly 
adjusted for and do not seem to provide opportunities 
– Stock prices rapidly adjust to corporate events such as 
mergers and offerings 
– The above studies provide support for the semistrong-form 
EMH
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Summary on the 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Evidence is mixed 
• Strong support from numerous event studies with 
the exception of exchange listing studies
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Summary on the 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Studies on predicting rates of return for a cross-section 
of stocks indicates markets are not 
semistrong efficient
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Summary on the 
Semistrong-Form EMH 
• Studies on predicting rates of return for a cross-section 
of stocks indicates markets are not 
semistrong efficient 
– Dividend yields, risk premiums, calendar patterns, and 
earnings surprises 
• This also included cross-sectional predictors such as 
size, the BV/MV ratio (when there is expansive 
monetary policy), E/P ratios, and neglected firms.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Tests and Results of 
Strong-Form EMH 
• Strong-form EMH contends that stock prices fully 
reflect all information, both public and private 
• This implies that no group of investors has access to 
private information that will allow them to 
consistently earn above-average profits
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Testing Groups of Investors 
• Corporate insiders 
• Stock exchange specialists 
• Security analysts 
• Professional money managers
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Corporate Insider Trading 
• Corporate insiders include major corporate officers, 
directors, and owners of 10% or more of any equity 
class of securities 
• Insiders must report to the SEC each month on their 
transactions in the stock of the firm for which they 
are insiders 
• These insider trades are made public about six weeks 
later and allowed to be studied
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Corporate Insider Trading 
• Corporate insiders generally experience above-average 
profits especially on purchase transaction 
• This implies that many insiders had private 
information from which they derived above-average 
returns on their company stock
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Corporate Insider Trading 
• Studies showed that public investors who traded 
with the insiders based on announced transactions 
would have enjoyed excess risk-adjusted returns 
(after commissions), but the markets now seem to 
have eliminated this inefficiency (soon after it was 
discovered)
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Corporate Insider Trading 
• Other studies indicate that you can increase returns 
from using insider trading information by combining 
it with key financial ratios and considering what 
group of insiders is doing the buying and selling
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Stock Exchange Specialists 
• Specialists have monopolistic access to information 
about unfilled limit orders 
• You would expect specialists to derive above-average 
returns from this information 
• The data generally supports this expectation
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Security Analysts 
• Tests have considered whether it is possible to 
identify a set of analysts who have the ability to 
select undervalued stocks 
• This looks at whether, after a stock selection by an 
analyst is made known, a significant abnormal return 
is available to those who follow their 
recommendations
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The Value Line Enigma 
• Value Line (VL) publishes financial information on 
about 1,700 stocks 
• The report includes a timing rank from 1 down to 5 
• Firms ranked 1 substantially outperform the market 
• Firms ranked 5 substantially underperform the 
market
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The Value Line Enigma 
• Changes in rankings result in a fast price adjustment 
• Some contend that the Value Line effect is merely 
the unexpected earnings anomaly due to changes in 
rankings from unexpected earnings
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Security Analysts 
• There is evidence in favor of existence of superior 
analysts who apparently possess private information
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Professional Money Managers 
• Trained professionals, working full time at 
investment management 
• If any investor can achieve above-average returns, it 
should be this group 
• If any non-insider can obtain inside information, it 
would be this group due to the extensive 
management interviews that they conduct
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Performance of 
Professional Money Managers 
• Most tests examine mutual funds 
• New tests also examine trust departments, insurance 
companies, and investment advisors 
• Risk-adjusted, after expenses, returns of mutual 
funds generally show that most funds did not match 
aggregate market performance
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Conclusions Regarding the 
Strong-Form EMH 
• Mixed results, but much support 
• Tests for corporate insiders and stock exchange 
specialists do not support the hypothesis (Both 
groups seem to have monopolistic access to 
important information and use it to derive above-average 
returns)
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Conclusions Regarding the 
Strong-Form EMH 
• Tests results for analysts are concentrated on Value Line 
rankings 
– Results have changed over time 
– Currently tend to support EMH 
• Individual analyst recommendations seem to contain 
significant information 
• Performance of professional money managers seem to 
provide support for strong-form EMH
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Behavioral Finance 
It is concerned with the analysis of various 
psychological traits of individuals and how these 
traits affect the manner in which they act as 
investors, analysts, and portfolio managers
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Implications of 
Efficient Capital Markets 
• Overall results indicate the capital markets are 
efficient as related to numerous sets of information 
• There are substantial instances where the market 
fails to rapidly adjust to public information
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Markets 
and Technical Analysis 
• Assumptions of technical analysis directly oppose the 
notion of efficient markets 
• Technicians believe that new information is not 
immediately available to everyone, but disseminated 
from the informed professional first to the aggressive 
investing public and then to the masses
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Markets 
and Technical Analysis 
• Technicians also believe that investors do not analyze 
information and act immediately - it takes time 
• Therefore, stock prices move to a new equilibrium after the 
release of new information in a gradual manner, causing 
trends in stock price movements that persist for periods
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Markets 
and Technical Analysis 
• Technical analysts develop systems to detect 
movement to a new equilibrium (breakout) and 
trade based on that 
• Contradicts rapid price adjustments indicated by the 
EMH 
• If the capital market is weak-form efficient, a trading 
system that depends on past trading data can have 
no value
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Markets 
and Fundamental Analysis 
• Fundamental analysts believe that there is a basic 
intrinsic value for the aggregate stock market, 
various industries, or individual securities and these 
values depend on underlying economic factors 
• Investors should determine the intrinsic value of an 
investment at a point in time and compare it to the 
market price
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Markets 
and Fundamental Analysis 
• If you can do a superior job of estimating intrinsic value you 
can make superior market timing decisions and generate 
above-average returns 
• This involves aggregate market analysis, industry analysis, 
company analysis, and portfolio management 
• Intrinsic value analysis should start with aggregate market 
analysis
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Aggregate Market Analysis with Efficient Capital 
Markets 
• EMH implies that examining only past economic events is not 
likely to lead to outperforming a buy-and-hold policy because 
the market adjusts rapidly to known economic events 
• Merely using historical data to estimate future values is not 
sufficient 
• You must estimate the relevant variables that cause long-run 
movements
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Industry and Company Analysis with Efficient Capital 
Markets 
• Wide distribution of returns from different industries and 
companies justifies industry and company analysis 
• Must understand the variables that effect rates of return and 
• Do a superior job of estimating future values of these relevant 
valuation variables, not just look at past data
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Industry and Company Analysis with Efficient 
Capital Markets 
• Important relationship between expected 
earnings and actual earnings 
• Accurately predicting earnings surprises 
• Strong-form EMH indicates likely existence of 
superior analysts 
• Studies indicate that fundamental analysis based 
on E/P ratios, size, and the BV/MV ratios can lead 
to differentiating future return patterns
MGB Portfolio Management I 
How to Evaluate Analysts or Investors 
• Examine the performance of numerous securities 
that this analyst recommends over time in relation to 
a set of randomly selected stocks in the same risk 
class 
• Selected stocks should consistently outperform the 
randomly selected stocks
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Markets 
and Portfolio Management 
• Portfolio Managers with Superior Analysts 
– concentrate efforts in mid-cap stocks that do not receive 
the attention given by institutional portfolio managers to 
the top-tier stocks 
– the market for these neglected stocks may be less efficient 
than the market for large well-known stocks
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Efficient Markets 
and Portfolio Management 
• Portfolio Managers without Superior Analysts 
– Determine and quantify your client's risk preferences 
– Construct the appropriate portfolio 
– Diversify completely on a global basis to eliminate all 
unsystematic risk 
– Maintain the desired risk level by rebalancing the portfolio 
whenever necessary 
– Minimize total transaction costs
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The Rationale and 
Use of Index Funds 
• Efficient capital markets and a lack of superior analysts imply 
that many portfolios should be managed passively (so their 
performance matches the aggregate market, minimizes the 
costs of research and trading) 
• Institutions created market (index) funds which duplicate the 
composition and performance of a selected index series
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Insights from Behavioral Finance 
• Growth companies will usually not be growth stocks 
due to the overconfidence of analysts regarding 
future growth rates and valuations 
• Notion of “herd mentality” of analysts in stock 
recommendations or quarterly earnings estimates is 
confirmed
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence on Efficient Market Hypothesis 
 Favorable Evidence 
1. Investment analysts and mutual funds don't beat 
the market 
2. Stock prices reflect publicly available info: 
anticipated announcements don't affect stock price 
3. Stock prices and exchange rates close to random walk; if 
predictions of DP big, Rof > R*  predictions 
of DP small 
4. Technical analysis does not outperform market
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency 
• Performance of Investment Analysts and Mutual Funds 
should not be able to consistently beat the market 
– The “Investment Dartboard” often beats investment managers. 
– Mutual funds not only do not outperform the market on average, but 
when they are separated into groups according to whether they had 
the highest or lowest profits in a chosen period, the mutual funds that 
did well in the first period do not beat the market in the second 
period. 
– Investment strategies using inside information is the only “proven 
method” to beat the market. In the U.S., it is illegal to trade on such 
information, but that is not true in all countries.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency 
 Do Stock Prices Reflect Publicly Available 
Information as the EMH predicts they will? 
─ Thus if information is already publicly available, a positive 
announcement about a company will not, on average, 
raise the price of its stock because this information is 
already reflected in the stock price. 
─ Early empirical evidence confirms: favorable earnings 
announcements or announcements of stock splits (a 
division of a share of stock into multiple shares, which is 
usually followed by higher earnings) do not, on average, 
cause stock prices to rise.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency 
 Random-Walk Behavior of Stock Prices that is, future 
changes in stock prices should, for all practical purposes, be 
unpredictable 
─ If stock is predicted to rise, people will buy to equilibrium 
level; if stock is predicted to fall, people will sell to 
equilibrium level (both in concert with EMH) 
─ Thus, if stock prices were predictable, thereby causing the 
above behavior, price changes would be near zero, which 
has not been the case historically
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency 
 Technical Analysis means to study past stock price data and 
search for patterns such as trends and regular cycles, 
suggesting rules for when to buy and sell stocks 
─ The EMH suggests that technical analysis is a waste of time 
─ The simplest way to understand why is to use the random-walk result 
that holds that past stock price data cannot help predict changes 
─ Therefore, technical analysis, which relies on such data to produce its 
forecasts, cannot successfully predict changes in stock prices
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency 
• 2: Empirical Evidence for TA is Negligible 
• Much of the faith in TA hinges on anecdotal experience, not any kind of long-term statistical 
evidence, unlike value investing or other quantitative/fundamental methodologies we discuss on 
this site. Most of the statistical work done by academics to determine whether the chart patterns 
are actually predictive has been inconclusive at best. Indeed, a recent study by finance professors at 
Massey University in New Zealand examined 49 developed and emerging markets to see if TA 
added value. They looked at more than 5,000 technical trading rules across four rule families : 
• Filter Rules - These rules involve opening long (short) positions after price increases (decreases) 
by x% and closing these positions when price decreases (increases) by x% from a subsequent high 
(low). 
• Moving Average Rules - These rules generate buy (sell) signals when the price or a short moving 
average moves above (below) a long moving average. 
• Channel Break-outs - These rules involve opening long (short) positions when the closing price 
moves above (below) a channel. A channel (sometimes referred to as a trading range) can be said to 
occur when the high over the previous n days is within x percent of the low over the 
previous n days, not including the current price. 
• Support and Resistance Rules - These “Trading Range Break” rules involve opening a long (short) 
position when the closing price breaches the maximum (minimum) price over the 
previous n periods. 
• The result? Using statistical methods to adjust for data snooping bias, the authors concluded that 
there wasno evidence that the profits [attributed] to the technical trading rules considered were 
greater than those that might be expected due to random data variation.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency 
But wait – it’s not all bad…. 
• As you can tell, trading purely on the basis of TA is a mug’s game. However, despite inconsistencies 
in predictive value, 
• 1. TA may be a useful tool as part of a broader strategy for managing holdings (e.g. to help you 
time any investments that are decided on other, hopefully fundamentally-focused, criteria).The fact 
is that many (misguided) market participants use TA to drive their investment decisions. These 
collective actions result in tangible changes in asset values, so they need to be understood even by 
less mis-guided investors. A fundamental investor need not agree that a stock should be moving but 
it’s worth understand why a stock is nevertheless moving. As Birinyi, a research and money-management 
firm, noted in a research note: 
• 2. “technical approaches can and should be a useful adjunct to every investor’s — amateur and 
professional — arsenal, if and only if used properly and with understanding… Technicals detail 
and hopefully illuminate, but do not predict.” 
• 3. TA may be particularly useful on the sell-side where it is deemed (according to William 
O’Neill) prudent to sell based on “unusual market action such as price and volume movement”… 
• 4. Good investing is about managing your losses too, and here TA can be a useful tool to 
determine where best to place a stop-loss (given the number of TA practitioners out there that are 
likely to be anchoring around certain price points).
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Case: Foreign Exchange Rates 
• Could you make a bundle if you could predict FX 
rates? Of course. 
• EMH predicts, then, that FX rates should be 
unpredictable. 
• That is exactly what empirical tests show—FX rates 
are not very predictable.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence on Efficient Market Hypothesis 
 Unfavorable Evidence 
1. Small-firm effect: small firms have abnormally high returns 
2. January effect: high returns in January 
3. Market overreaction 
4. Excessive volatility 
5. Mean reversion 
6. New information is not always immediately incorporated into stock 
prices 
 Overview 
─ Reasonable starting point but not whole story
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence Against Market Efficiency 
• The Small-Firm Effect is an anomaly. Many empirical studies 
have shown that small firms have earned abnormally high 
returns over long periods of time, even when the greater risk 
for these firms has been considered. 
– The small-firm effect seems to have diminished in recent years but is 
still a challenge to the theory of efficient markets 
– Various theories have been developed to explain the small-firm effect, 
suggesting that it may be due to rebalancing of portfolios by 
institutional investors, tax issues, low liquidity of small-firm stocks, 
large information costs in evaluating small firms, or an inappropriate 
measurement of risk for small-firm stocks
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence Against Market Efficiency 
 The January Effect is the tendency of stock prices to 
experience an abnormal positive return in the month of 
January that is predictable and, hence, inconsistent with 
random-walk behavior 
– Investors have an incentive to sell stocks before the end of the 
year in December because they can then take capital losses on 
their tax return and reduce their tax liability. Then when the 
new year starts in January, they can repurchase the stocks, 
driving up their prices and producing abnormally high returns. 
– Although this explanation seems sensible, it does not explain 
why institutional investors such as private pension funds, which 
are not subject to income taxes, do not take advantage of the 
abnormal returns in January and buy stocks in December, thus 
bidding up their price and eliminating the abnormal returns.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence Against Market Efficiency 
 Market Overreaction: recent research suggests that stock 
prices may overreact to news announcements and that the 
pricing errors are corrected only slowly 
─ When corporations announce a major change in earnings, say, a large 
decline, the stock price may overshoot, and after an initial large 
decline, it may rise back to more normal levels over a period of several 
weeks. 
─ This violates the EMH because an investor could earn abnormally high 
returns, on average, by buying a stock immediately after a poor 
earnings announcement and then selling it after a couple of weeks 
when it has risen back to normal levels.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence Against Market Efficiency 
 Excessive Volatility: the stock market appears to display 
excessive volatility; that is, fluctuations in stock prices may be 
much greater than is warranted by fluctuations in their 
fundamental value. 
─ Researchers have found that fluctuations in the S&P 500 stock index 
could not be justified by the subsequent fluctuations in the dividends 
of the stocks making up this index. 
─ Other research finds that there are smaller fluctuations in stock prices 
when stock markets are closed, which has produced a consensus that 
stock market prices appear to be driven by factors other than 
fundamentals.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence Against Market Efficiency 
 Mean Reversion: Some researchers have found that stocks 
with low returns today tend to have high returns in the future, 
and vice versa. 
─ Hence stocks that have done poorly in the past are more likely to do 
well in the future because mean reversion indicates that there will be 
a predictable positive change in the future price, suggesting that stock 
prices are not a random walk. 
─ Newer data is less conclusive; nevertheless, mean reversion remains 
controversial.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Evidence Against Market Efficiency 
 New Information Is Not Always Immediately Incorporated 
into Stock Prices 
─ Although generally true, recent evidence suggests that, inconsistent 
with the efficient market hypothesis, stock prices do not 
instantaneously adjust to profit announcements. 
─ Instead, on average stock prices continue to rise for some time after 
the announcement of unexpectedly high profits, and they continue to 
fall after surprisingly low profit announcements.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Implications for Investing 
1. How valuable are published reports by investment advisors? 
2. Should you be skeptical of hot tips? 
3. Do stock prices always rise when there is good news? 
4. Efficient Markets prescription for investor
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Implications for Investing 
 How valuable are published reports by investment advisors?
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Implications for Investing 
1. Should you be skeptical of hot tips? 
─ YES. The EMH indicates that you should be skeptical of hot tips since, if 
the stock market is efficient, it has already priced the hot tip stock so 
that its expected return will equal the equilibrium return. 
─ Thus, the hot tip is not particularly valuable and will not enable you to 
earn an abnormally high return. 
– As soon as the information hits the street, the unexploited profit 
opportunity it creates will be quickly eliminated. 
– The stock’s price will already reflect the information, and you should 
expect to realize only the equilibrium return.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Implications for Investing 
3. Do stock prices always rise when there is 
good news? 
– NO. In an efficient market, stock prices will respond to announcements 
only when the information being announced is new and unexpected. 
– So, if good news was expected (or as good as expected), there will be no 
stock price response. 
– And, if good news was unexpected (or not as good as expected), there 
will be a stock price response.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Implications for Investing 
 Efficient Markets prescription for investor 
─ Investors should not try to outguess the market by constantly buying 
and selling securities. This process does nothing but incur 
commissions costs on each trade. 
─ Instead, the investor should pursue a “buy and hold” strategy— 
purchase stocks and hold them for long periods of time. This will lead 
to the same returns, on average, but the investor’s net profits will be 
higher because fewer brokerage commissions will have to be paid. 
─ It is frequently a sensible strategy for a small investor, whose costs of 
managing a portfolio may be high relative to its size, to buy into a 
mutual fund rather than individual stocks. Because the EMH indicates 
that no mutual fund can consistently outperform the market, an 
investor should not buy into one that has high management fees or 
that pays sales commissions to brokers but rather should purchase a 
no-load (commission-free) mutual fund that has low management 
fees.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
All mutual funds sold to the public – performance of all 
general equity mutual funds compared to the Wilshire 
5000 Index. In most years more than ½ of the funds 
were outperformed by the index. Over the 26.5 year 
period about 2/3 of the funds proved inferior to the 
market as a whole. Same result holds for professional 
pension managers. 
Implications for Investing 
Cost Compare 
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 6-97
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Case: Any Efficient Markets Lessons from Black Monday of 1987 
and the Tech Crash of 2000? 
 Does any version of Efficient Markets Hypothesis (EMH) hold 
in light of sudden or dramatic market declines? 
 Strong version EMH? 
 Weaker version EMH? 
 A bubble is a situation in which the price of an asset differs 
from its fundamental market value? 
 Can bubbles be rational? 
 Role of behavioral finance
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Behavioral Finance 
BF argues that a few psychological phenomena pervade 
financial markets: 
1. Practitioners rely on rules of thumb called heuristics to process 
information. 
– Heuristic—a process by which people find things out for themselves, 
usually by trial and error. Leads to the development of rules of thumb 
which are imperfect and result in errors which lead to heuristic-driven 
bias. 
2. In addition to objective considerations, practitioners perception of risk 
& return are highly influenced by how decision problems are framed 
 frame dependence. 
3. Heuristic-driven bias and framing effects cause market prices to 
deviate from fundamental values, i.e. markets are inefficient.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Heuristic Driven Bias 
• Representativeness—reliance on stereotypes 
– Example of High School GPA as predictor of College GPA 
and reversion to the mean. 
• Overconfidence 
– People set overly narrow confidence bands, high guess is 
too low and low guess is too high. 
– Results in being surprised too often. 
• Anchoring to old information 
– Security analysts do not revise their earnings estimates 
enough to reflect new info.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Frame Dependence 
• EMH assumes framing is transparent—If you move a $ from your right pocket to 
your left pocket, you are no wealthier! (Merton Miller) 
… In other words, practitioners can see through all the different ways that cash 
flow might be described. 
• But if frame is opaque, a difference in form (which pocket) is also a difference in 
substance and affects behavior. 
• Loss Aversion 
– Choose between 
• Sure loss of $7,500 or 
• 75% chance of loosing $10K or 25% chance of loosing $0. 
• Hedonic editing 
– Organizing Gains and Losses in separate mental accounts. 
• One loss and one gain are netted against each other. 
• Two gains are savored separately 
• But multiple losses are difficult to net out against moderate gains.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Frame Dependence 
• Hedonic editing 
1. Imagine that you face the following choice. You can accept 
a guaranteed $1500 or play a lottery. The outcome of the 
lottery is determined by the toss of a fair coin. 
Heads—> you win $1950 
Tails—> you win $1050 
Which would you chose? 
Are you risk averse?
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Frame Dependence 
• Hedonic editing 
2. Imagine that you face the following choice. You can 
accept a guaranteed loss of $750 or play a lottery. The 
outcome of the lottery is determined by the toss of a fair 
coin. 
Heads—> you lose $750 
Tails—> you lose $525 
Which would you chose?
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Frame Dependence 
• Hedonic editing 
3. Now imagine that you have just won $1500 in one lottery, 
and you can choose to participate in another. The outcome 
of this second lottery is determined by the toss of a fair 
coin. 
Heads—> you win $450 
Tails—> you win $450 
Would you choose to participate in the second lottery?
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Frame Dependence 
• Hedonic editing has both cognitive and emotional 
causes 
– Main cognitive issue in choice 3 above—Do you ignore the 
preliminary $1500 winnings or not? 
– Those that begin by seeing themselves $1500 ahead then 
experience the emotion of loosing $450 as the equivalent 
of winning $1050 (i.e. a smaller gain, not a loss). 
– Those that ignore the $1500 are less prone to accept the 
gamble because they will feel a $450 loss as a loss.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Assignment 
Q1: If the weak form of the efficient market is valid must the strong 
form also hold? Conversely, does strong-form efficiency imply weak-form 
efficiency? 
Q2: What would happen to market efficiency if every investor followed 
a passive strategy? 
Q3. A portfolio manager outperforms the market in 11 of 14 years. 
Does this violate the concept of market efficiency? 
Q4. A segment of the market believes that continued economic worries 
brought about the stock market crash of 1987. Is this explanation for 
the crash consistent with the Efficient Market Hypothesis?
MGB Portfolio Management I 
PORTFOLIO THEORY
MGB Portfolio Management I
MGB Portfolio Management I 
cov(X,Y)=E(XY)−E(X)E(Y). 
Proof: 
Let μ=E(X) and ν=E(Y). Then 
cov(X,Y)=E[(X−μ)(Y−ν)]=E(XY−μY−νX+μν)=E(XY)−μE(Y)−νE(X)+μν=E(XY)−μν
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The "Population Standard 
Deviation": 
The "Sample Standard 
Deviation":
MGB Portfolio Management I 
In probability theory and statistics, the mathematical concepts of covariance and 
correlation are very similar. Both describe the degree to which two random 
variables or sets of random variables tend to deviate from their expected values in 
similar ways. 
correlation 
covariance 
where E is the expected value operator and σx and σy are the standard 
deviations of X and Y, respectively. Notably, correlation is dimensionless while 
covariance is in units obtained by multiplying the units of the two variables. The 
covariance of a variable with itself (i.e. σxx ) is called the variance and is more 
commonly denoted as σ2 
x the square of the standard deviation. The correlation 
of a variable with itself is always 1
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Last year, five randomly selected students took a math aptitude test before they began their statistics 
course. The Statistics Department has three questions. 
What linear regression equation best predicts statistics performance, based on math aptitude scores? 
If a student made an 80 on the aptitude test, what grade would we expect her to make in statistics? 
How well does the regression equation fit the data? 
How to Find the Regression Equation 
In the table below, the xi column shows scores on the aptitude test. Similarly, the yi column shows 
statistics grades. The last two rows show sums and mean scores that we will use to conduct the 
regression analysis. 
Student xi yi (xi - x) (yi - y) (xi - x)2 (yi - y)2 (xi - x)(yi - y) 
1 95 85 17 8 289 64 136 
2 85 95 7 18 49 324 126 
3 80 70 2 -7 4 49 -14 
4 70 65 -8 -12 64 144 96 
5 60 70 -18 -7 324 49 126 
Sum 390 385 730 630 470 
Mean 78 77 
The regression equation is a linear equation of the form: ŷ = b0 + b1x . To conduct a regression analysis, 
we need to solve for b0 and b1. Computations are shown below. 
b1 = Σ [ (xi - x)(yi - y) ] / Σ [ (xi - x)2] 
b1 = 470/730 = 0.644 
Therefore, the regression equation is: ŷ = 26.768 + 0.644x . 
b0 = y - b1 * x 
b0 = 77 - (0.644)(78) = 26.768
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The Coefficient of Determination 
Whenever you use a regression equation, you should ask how well the equation fits 
the data. One way to assess fit is to check the coefficient of determination, which can 
be computed from the following formula. 
R2 = { ( 1 / N ) * Σ [ (xi - x) * (yi - y) ] / (σx * σy ) }2 
where N is the number of observations used to fit the model, Σ is the summation 
symbol, xi is the x value for observation i, x is the mean x value, yi is the y value for 
observation i, y is the mean y value, σx is the standard deviation of x, and σy is the 
standard deviation of y. Computations for the sample problem of this lesson are shown 
below. 
σx = sqrt [ Σ ( xi - x )2 / N ] 
σx = sqrt( 730/5 ) = sqrt(146) = 12.083 
σy = sqrt [ Σ ( yi - y )2 / N ] 
σy = sqrt( 630/5 ) = sqrt(126) = 11.225 
R2 = { ( 1 / N ) * Σ [ (xi - x) * (yi - y) ] / (σx * σy ) }2 
R2 = [ ( 1/5 ) * 470 / ( 12.083 * 11.225 ) ]2 = ( 94 / 135.632 )2 = ( 0.693 )2 = 0.48 
A coefficient of determination equal to 0.48 indicates that about 48% of the variation 
in statistics grades (the dependent variable) can be explained by the relationship to 
math aptitude scores (the independent variable). This would be considered a good fit 
to the data, in the sense that it would substantially improve an educator's ability to 
predict student performance in statistics class.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Mathematics 
114 
• Of course, in practice, assets are not correlated in this 
simplistic way. Let us look at how portfolio risk is 
affected when we put two arbitrarily correlated assets in 
a portfolio. Let us call the two assets, a bond, D, and a 
stock (equity), E. 
• Then, we can write out the following relationship: 
r 
r 
w 
r 
w 
r 
p D D E E 
Portfolio Return 
Bond Weight 
Bond Return 
Equity Weight 
Equity Return 
P 
D 
D 
E 
E 
 w r w r 
 
 
 
 
 
( ) ( ) ( ) p D D E E E r  w E r  w E r
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Mathematics 
115 
The expected return 
on a portfolio 
consisting of several 
assets is simply a 
weighted average of 
the expected returns 
on the assets 
comprising the 
portfolio.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Mathematics 
116 
• If we denote variance by s2, then we have the 
relationship: 
D D E E D E  D E  w w 2w w Cov r ,r 2 2 2 2 2 
p s  s  s  
 where Cov(rD, rE) represents the covariance between the 
returns on assets D and E. 
 If we use DE to represent the correlation coefficient between 
the returns on the two assets, then 
 Cov(rD,rE) = DEsDsE 
 The formula for portfolio variance can be written either 
with covariance or with correlation.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Mathematics 
• The correlation coefficient can take values between 
+1 and -1. 
• If DE = +1, there is no diversification and the 
portfolio standard deviation equals wDsD + wEsE, 
i.e. a linear combination of the standard deviations 
of the two assets. 
• If DE= -1, the portfolio variance equals (wDsD – 
wEsE)2. In this case, we can construct a risk-free 
combination of D and E. 
• Setting this equal to zero and solving for wD and wE, 
we find 
117 
s 
E w   w 
D 
D 
 1 
s  
s 
D E
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Mathematics 
118 
For intermediate values of r, 
the portfolio standard 
deviations fall in the 
middle, as shown on the 
graph to the right. 
In this example, the stock 
asset has a standard 
deviation of returns of 20% 
and the bond asset, of 12%.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Problem 
Seventy-five percent of a portfolio is invested in Honeybell stock and the 
remaining 25% is invested in MBIB stock. Honeybell stock has an expected 
return of 6% and an expected standard deviation of returns of 9%. MBIB stock 
has an expected return of 20% and an expected standard deviation of 30%. 
The coefficient of correlation between returns of the two securities is 
expected to be 0.4. Determine the following: 
(a) the expected return of the portfolio; 
(b) the expected variance of the portfolio; 
(c) the expected standard deviation for the portfolio.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Measuring Mean: Scenario 
or Subjective Returns 
Subjective returns 
s 
 
 
E(r)  p  
r 
i i i 1 
‘s’ = number of scenarios considered 
pi = probability that scenario ‘i’ will occur 
ri = return if scenario ‘i’ occurs
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Numerical example: 
Scenario Distributions 
Scenario Probability Return 
1 0.1 -5% 
2 0.2 5% 
3 0.4 15% 
4 0.2 25% 
5 0.1 35% 
E(r) = (.1)(-.05)+(.2)(.05)...+(.1)(.35) 
E(r) = .15 = 15%
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Measuring Variance or 
Dispersion of Returns 
Subjective or Scenario Distributions 
s 2 
Variance  s 2  p(i)  [r(i)  
E(r)] 
i 1 
 
Standard deviation = [variance]1/2 = s 
Using Our Example: 
s 
2=[(.1)(-.05-.15)2+(.2)(.05- .15)2+…] 
=.01199 
s = [ .01199]1/2 = .1095 = 10.95%
MGB Portfolio Management I 
W = 100 
W1 = 150; Profit = 50 
W2 1-p = .4 = 80; Profit = -20 
E(W) = pW1 + (1-p)W2 = 122 
2 = p[W1 - E(W)]2 + (1-p) [W2 - E(W)]2 
s 
2 = 1,176 and s = 34.29% 
s 
Risk - Uncertain Outcomes
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risky Investments 
with Risk-Free Investment 
W1 = 150 Profit = 50 
1-p = .4 W2 = 80 Profit = -20 
100 
Risky 
Investment 
Risk Free T-bills Profit = 5 
Risk Premium = 22-5 = 17
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk Aversion & Utility 
• Investor’s view of risk 
– Risk Averse 
– Risk Neutral 
– Risk Seeking 
• Utility 
• Utility Function 
U = E ( r ) – .005 A s 2 
• A measures the degree of risk aversion
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk Aversion and Value: 
The Sample Investment 
U = E ( r ) - .005 A s 2 
= 22% - .005 A (34%) 2 
Risk Aversion A Utility 
High 5 -6.90 
3 4.66 
Low 1 16.22 
T-bill = 5%
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Dominance Principle 
2 3 
1 
4 
Expected Return 
Variance or Standard Deviation 
• 2 dominates 1; has a higher 
return 
• 2 dominates 3; has a lower risk 
• 4 dominates 3; has a higher
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Utility and Indifference Curves 
• Represent an investor’s willingness to trade-off return and 
risk 
Example (for an investor with A=4): 
Exp Return 
(%) 
St Deviation 
(%) 
10 20.0 
15 25.5 
20 30.0 
25 33.9 
U=E(r)-.005As2 
2 
2 
2 
2
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Indifference Curves 
Expected Return 
Increasing Utility 
Standard Deviation
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Mathematics: 
Assets’ Expected Return 
Rule 1 : The return for an asset is the 
probability weighted average return 
in all scenarios. 
s 
 
 
E(r)  p  
r 
i i i 1
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Mathematics: 
Assets’ Variance of Return 
Rule 2: The variance of an asset’s return is the 
expected value of the squared 
deviations from the expected return. 
s 2 
2 p [r E(r)] 
s    
i 1 
i i 

MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Mathematics: Return 
on a Portfolio 
Rule 3: The rate of return on a portfolio is a 
weighted average of the rates of 
return of each asset comprising the 
portfolio, with the portfolio 
proportions as weights. 
rp = w1r1 + w2r2
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Mathematics: 
Risk with Risk-Free Asset 
Rule 4: When a risky asset is combined with a 
risk-free asset, the portfolio standard 
deviation equals the risky asset’s 
standard deviation multiplied by the 
portfolio proportion invested in the 
risky asset. 
s  s 
p risky asset riskyasset w
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Mathematics: 
Risk with two Risky Assets 
Rule 5: When two risky assets with variances 
2 and s2 
s1 
2 respectively, are combined 
into a portfolio with portfolio weights 
w1 and w2, respectively, the portfolio 
variance is given by: 
sp 2 
 2 
s 2 
 2 
s 2 
1 
1 
2 
2 
 
w w 2w1w2Cov(r1,r2)
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Asset Mix Decision 
Asset mix decisions consider both investment opportunities and investor 
preferences. These are best described within a risk-reward framework. 
Investment Opportunities 
The goal of assessing investment opportunities can be expressed in terms 
of: 
• Expected investment returns and 
• Potential deviations from these expectations 
Asset returns are typically viewed in a probabilistic sense as: 
푛 
E(R) = 
푖=0 
푃푖*ri n= number of possible outcomes 
Pi is the probability that outcome I will occur 
ri= Realized returns if outcome I occurs
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Asset Mix Decision 
The expected return on portfolio is written as 
E(Rm) = 
푘 
푖=0 
푥푖*E(Ri) k= number of assets in the portfolio 
xi is the proportion of the portfolio invested in asset i 
E(Ri)= Realized returns if outcome i occurs 
The variability of the returns about the expectations is measured by the 
standard deviation of the returns: 
The right hand side of the equation is collectively known as the capital 
market conditions. The resulting risk return characteristics of each mix can 
be plotted on a return-standard deviation graph to get a chart of all the 
portfolios that are constructed.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Asset Mix Decision 
The Efficient Frontier 
It's clear that for any given value of standard deviation, you would like to choose a portfolio that gives you 
the greatest possible rate of return; so you always want a portfolio that lies up along the efficient frontier, 
rather than lower down, in the interior of the region. This is the first important property of the efficient 
frontier: it's where the best portfolios are. 
The second important property of the efficient frontier is that it's curved, not straight. This is actually 
significant -- in fact, it's the key to how diversification lets you improve your reward-to-risk ratio. To see why, 
imagine a 50/50 allocation between just two securities. Assuming that the year-to-year performance of these 
two securities is not perfectly in sync -- that is, assuming that the great years and the lousy years for Security 
1 don't correspond perfectly to the great years and lousy years for Security 2, but that their cycles are at least 
a little off -- then the standard deviation of the 50/50 allocation will be less than the average of the standard 
deviations of the two securities separately. Graphically, this stretches the possible allocations to the left of 
the straight line joining the two securities. 
In statistical terms, this effect is due to lack of covariance. The smaller the covariance between the two 
securities -- the more out of sync they are -- the smaller the standard deviation of a portfolio that combines 
them. The ultimate would be to find two securities with negative covariance.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Asset Mix Decision 
Investor Preferences 
Investor preference is quantified in terms of utility derived from owning a 
security. They 
• Like Return 
• Dislike Risk 
2 = Return – “Risk Penalty” 
tk 
• Umk = E(Rm) – σm 
Umk = Expected utility of asset mix m derived by investor k 
tk = Investor k’s risk tolerance
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Asset Mix Decision 
Utility Curves 
• An investor is indifferent between any two portfolios that lie on the same 
indifference curve. 
• Investors want to be on the highest indifference curve that is available given 
current capital market conditions. 
• Indifference curves do not intersect. 
• Flatter indifference curves indicate that the investor has higher tolerance for risk 
• Certainty equivalent rate of return is given by the y intercept and is greater than 
the risk free rate of return.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Utility Functions 
• Utility is a measure of well-being. 
• A utility function shows the relationship between utility 
and return (or wealth) when the returns are risk-free. 
• Risk-Neutral Utility Functions: Investors are 
indifferent to risk. They only analyze return when making 
investment decisions. 
• Risk-Loving Utility Functions: For any given rate of 
return, investors prefer more risk. 
• Risk-Averse Utility Functions: For any given rate of 
return, investors prefer less risk.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Utility Functions (Continued) 
• To illustrate the different types of utility functions, we will 
analyze the following risky investment for three different 
investors: 
Possible Return (%) 
(ri) 
_________ 
10% 
50% 
Probability 
(pi) 
_________ 
.5 
.5 
   
E(r ) .5(10%) .5(50%) 30% 
2 2 
i 
σ(r ) .5(10% 30%) .5(50% 30%) 20% 
i 
    
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk-Neutral Investor 
• Assume the following linear utility function: 
ui = 10ri 
Return (%) 
(ri) 
__________ 
0 
10 
20 
30 
40 
50 
Total Utility 
(ui) 
__________ 
0 
100 
200 
300 
400 
500 
Constant 
Marginal Utility 
__________ 
100 
100 
100 
100 
100
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk-Neutral Investor (Continued) 
• Expected Utility of the Risky Investment: 
  
E(u) .5*u(10%) .5*u(50%) 
   
E(u) .5(100) .5(500) 300 
• Note: The expected utility of the risky investment 
with an expected return of 30% (300) is equal to 
the utility associated with receiving 30% risk-free 
(300).
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk-Neutral Utility Function 
ui = 10ri 
Total Utility 
600 
500 
400 
300 
200 
100 
0 
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 
Percent Return
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk-Loving Investor 
• Assume the following quadratic utility function: 
ui = 0 + 5ri + .1ri 
2 
Return (%) 
(ri) 
__________ 
0 
10 
20 
30 
40 
50 
Total Utility 
(ui) 
__________ 
0 
60 
140 
240 
360 
500 
Increasing 
Marginal Utility 
__________ 
60 
80 
100 
120 
140
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk-Loving Investor (Continued) 
• Expected Utility of the Risky Investment: 
  
E(u) .5*u(10%) .5*u(50%) 
   
E(u) .5(60) .5(500) 280 
• Note: The expected utility of the risky investment with an 
expected return of 30% (280) is greater than the utility 
associated with receiving 30% risk-free (240). 
33.5% 
- 5 + 25- 4(.1)(-280) 
Certainty Equivalent :  
2(.1) 
• That is, the investor would be indifferent between 
receiving 33.5% risk-free and investing in a risky asset that 
has E(r) = 30% and s(r) = 20%
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk-Loving Utility Function 
2 
ui = 0 + 5ri + .1ri 
Total Utility 
600 
0 
0 60 
Percent Return 
500 
280 
240 
60 
10 30 33.5 50
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk-Averse Investor 
• Assume the following quadratic utility function: 
ui = 0 + 20ri - .2ri 
2 
Return (%) 
(ri) 
__________ 
0 
10 
20 
30 
40 
50 
Total Utility 
(ui) 
__________ 
0 
180 
320 
420 
480 
500 
Diminishing 
Marginal Utility 
__________ 
180 
140 
100 
60 
20
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk-Averse Investor (Continued) 
• Expected Utility of the Risky Investment: 
  
E(u) .5*u(10%) .5*u(50%) 
   
E(u) .5(180) .5(500) 340 
• Note: The expected utility of the risky investment with an 
expected return of 30% (340) is less than the utility 
associated with receiving 30% risk-free (420). 
- 20+ 400- 4(-.2)(-340) 
Certainty Equivalent :  
 
2( .2) 
• That is, the investor would be indifferent between 
21.7% 
receiving 21.7% risk-free and investing in a risky asset that 
has E(r) = 30% and s(r) = 20%.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk-Averse Utility Function 
2 
ui = 0 + 20ri - .2ri 
Total Utility 
600 
0 
0 60 
Percent Return 
500 
420 
340 
180 
10 21.7 30 50
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Indifference Curve 
• Given the total utility function, an indifference curve can 
be generated for any given level of utility. First, for 
quadratic utility functions, the following equation for 
expected utility is derived in the text: 
    
E(u) a a E(r) a E(r) a σ (r) 
2 
a E(r) 
2 
1 
0 
2 
Solving for σ(r) : 
E(u) 
2 
2 
2 
2 
0 1 2 
E(r) 
a 
a 
a 
a 
σ(r) = 
  
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Indifference Curve (Continued) 
• Using the previous utility function for the risk-averse 
investor, (ui = 0 + 20ri - .2ri 
2), and a given level of utility 
of 180: 
2 E(r) 
20E(r) 
σ(r)  
.2 
180 
.2 
 
 
 
 
• Therefore, the indifference curve would be: 
E(r) 
10 
20 
30 
40 
50 
s(r) 
0 
26.5 
34.6 
38.7 
40.0
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk-Averse Indifference Curve 
2 
When E(u) = 180, and ui = 0 + 20ri - .2ri 
Expected Return 
60 
50 
40 
30 
20 
10 
0 
0 10 20 30 40 50 
Standard Deviation of Returns
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Maximizing Utility 
• Given the efficient set of investment possibilities and a 
“mass” of indifference curves, an investor would maximize 
his/her utility by finding the point of tangency between an 
indifference curve and the efficient set. 
Expected Return 
60 
50 
40 
30 
20 
10 
0 
E(u) = 380 E(u) = 280 
Portfolio That 
Maximizes 
Utility 
E(u) = 180 
0 10 20 30 40 50 
Standard Deviation of Returns
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Problems With Quadratic Utility Functions 
Quadratic utility functions turn down after they reach a 
certain level of return (or wealth). This aspect is obviously 
unrealistic: 
Total Utility 
600 
500 
400 
300 
200 
100 
0 
Unrealistic 
0 20 40 60 80 
Percent Return
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Problems With Quadratic Utility 
Functions (Continued) 
• With a quadratic utility function, as your wealth level 
increases, your willingness to take on risk decreases (i.e., 
both absolute risk aversion [dollars you are willing to 
commit to risky investments] and relative risk aversion [% 
of wealth you are willing to commit to risky investments] 
increase with wealth levels). In general, however, rich 
people are more willing to take on risk than poor people. 
Therefore, other mathematical functions (e.g., 
logarithmic) may be more appropriate.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
What do you think about the move to a more active stock-picking strategy? 
stock standard deviation return 
Index fund 4.61% 1.10% 
California R.E.I.T. 9.23% -2.27% 
Brown Group 8.17% -0.67% 
Portfolio of 99% index 
4.57% 1.07% 
fund and 1 % California 
R.E.I.T. 
Portfolio of 99% index 
fund and 1 % Brown 
Group 
4.61% 1.08% 
Thus we see that the index fund has the highest return of 1.10% 
with the standard deviation of 4.61% 
By including California REIT the standard deviation (risk) is reduced to 4.57% 
but the return also reduces to 1.07% 
Thus there can be a tradeoff between these two strategies 
However including Brown Group is not a good idea as return drops but the risk (standard deviation remains the same)
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Asset Mix Decision 
Optimal Portfolio - Where the Efficient frontier and Utility curve meet
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Estimating Risk Aversion 
• Use questionnaires 
• Observe individuals’ decisions when 
confronted with risk 
• Observe how much people are willing to 
pay to avoid risk
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk Aversion and Capital Allocation to 
Risky Assets
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The Investment Decision 
• Top-down process with 3 steps: 
1. Capital allocation between the risky portfolio and 
risk-free asset 
2. Asset allocation across broad asset classes 
3. Security selection of individual assets within each 
asset class
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Allocation to Risky Assets 
• Investors will avoid risk unless there is a 
reward. 
– i.e. Risk Premium should be positive 
• Agents preference (taste) gives the 
optimal allocation between a risky 
portfolio and a risk-free asset.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Speculation vs. Gamble 
• Speculation 
– Taking considerable risk for a commensurate gain 
– Parties have heterogeneous expectations 
• Gamble 
– Bet or wager on an uncertain outcome for 
enjoyment 
– Parties assign the same probabilities to the possible 
outcomes
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Available Risky Portfolios (Risk-free Rate = 5%) 
Each portfolio receives a utility score to 
assess the investor’s risk/return trade off
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Utility Function 
U = utility of portfolio 
with return r 
E ( r ) = expected 
return portfolio 
A = coefficient of risk 
aversion 
s2 = variance of 
returns of portfolio 
½ = a scaling factor 
2 1 
U  E ( r ) 
 As 
2
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Utility Scores of Alternative Portfolios for Investors with 
Varying Degree of Risk Aversion 
IN CLASS EXERCISE. Answer: How high 
does the risk aversion coefficient (A) has to be 
so that L is preferred over M and H?
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Mean-Variance (M-V) Criterion 
• Portfolio A dominates portfolio B if: 
• And 
 A   B  E r  E r 
A B s s 
• As noted before: this does not determine the choice of one 
portfolio, but a whole set of efficient portfolios.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Capital Allocation Across Risky and Risk-Free Portfolios 
Asset Allocation: 
• Is a very important part 
of portfolio 
construction. 
• Refers to the choice 
among broad asset 
classes. 
– % of total Investment in risky 
vs. risk-free assets 
Controlling Risk: 
• Simplest way: 
Manipulate the fraction 
of the portfolio invested 
in risk-free assets versus 
the portion invested in 
the risky assets
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Basic Asset Allocation Example 
Total Amount Invested $300,000 
Risk-free money market 
$90,000 
fund 
Total risk assets $210,000 
Equities $113,400 
Bonds (long-term) $96,600 
$113,400 
W   0.54 
0.46 
E $210,000 
$96,600 
  B W 
$210,00 
Proportion of Risk assets 
on Equities 
Proportion of Risk assets 
on Bonds
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Basic Asset Allocation 
• P is the complete portfolio where we have y as 
the weight on the risky portfolio and (1-y) = 
weight of risk-free assets: 
$90,000 
1 y   
y   0.7 
0.3 
$210,000 
$300,000 
$113,400 
$96,600 
B :  
E :  .322 
• Complete Portfolio is: 
(0.3, 0.378, 0.322) 
$300,000 
.378 
$300,000 
$300,000
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The Risk-Free Asset 
• Only the government can issue default-free 
bonds. 
– Risk-free in real terms only if price indexed 
and maturity equal to investor’s holding 
period. 
• T-bills viewed as “the” risk-free asset 
• Money market funds also considered risk-free 
in practice
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Figure 6.3 Spread Between 3-Month 
CD and T-bill Rates
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolios of One Risky Asset and a Risk-Free Asset 
• It’s possible to create a complete portfolio by 
splitting investment funds between safe and 
risky assets. 
– Let y=portion allocated to the risky portfolio, P 
– (1-y)=portion to be invested in risk-free asset, F.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Example 
rf = 7% srf = 0% 
E(rp) = 15% sp = 22% 
y = % in p (1-y) = % in rf
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Example (Ctd.) 
The expected 
return on the 
complete portfolio 
is the risk-free 
rate plus the 
weight of P times 
the risk premium 
of P 
E(rc )  rf  y E(rP )  rf  
Er   7  y15  7 c
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Example (Ctd.) 
• The risk of the complete portfolio is 
the weight of P times the risk of P: 
y y C P s  s  22 
– This follows straight from the formulas we saw 
before and the fact that any constant random 
variable has zero variance.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Feasible (var, mean) 
• Taken together this determines the set 
of feasible (mean,variance) portfolio 
return: 
Er   7  y15  7 c 
y y C P s  s  22 
– This determines a straight line, which we call 
Capital Allocation Line. Next we derive it’s 
equation completely
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Example (Ctd.) 
• Rearrange and substitute y=sC/sP: 
s 
8 
  C 
    P f C 
E r  r  E r  r  7  
s 
C f s 
P 
22 
– The sub-index C is to stand for complete portfolio 
  
8 
22 
 
E r  
r 
P f  
s 
P 
Slope 
– The slope has a special name: Sharpe ratio.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The Investment Opportunity Set
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Capital Allocation Line - Changing Allocation 
Increasing he fraction of the overall portfolio 
invested in the risky asset increases the 
expected return by the risk premium of the 
equation (which is 8%) but also increases 
portfolio standard deviation at the rate of 22%. 
The extra return per extra risk is 8/22 = 0.36
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Capital Allocation Line Changing Allocation 
I have invested 300,000 risky assets and if I borrow 
120,000 and invest it into the risky asset as well 
y = 420,000/300,000 = 1.4 
1-y = 1-1.4 = -0.4 
E(rc) = 7% + (1.4 x 8%) = 18.2% 
σc = 1.4 X 22% = 30.8% 
S= E(rc) – rf = 18.2 – 7 = 0.36 
σc 30.8
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Capital Allocation Line with Leverage 
• Lend at rf=7% and borrow at rf=9% 
– Lending range slope = 8/22 = 0.36 
– Borrowing range slope = 6/22 = 0.27 
• CAL kinks at P
MGB Portfolio Management I 
The Opportunity Set with Differential Borrowing and Lending 
Rates
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Utility Levels for Various Positions in Risky Assets (y) for an 
Investor with Risk Aversion A = 4
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Utility as a Function of Allocation to the Risky Asset, y
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Table 6.5 Spreadsheet Calculations of 
Indifference Curves
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio problem 
• Agent’s problem with one risky and one risk-free 
asset is thus: 
• Pick portfolio (y, 1-y) to maximize utility U 
– U(y,1-y) = E(rC) -0.005*A*Var(rC) 
• Where rC is the complete portfolio 
– This is the same as 
– rf + y[E(r) – rf] -0.5*A*y2*Var(r) 
– Solution: y* = E(r) – rf )/0.01A*Var(rC)
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Indifference Curves for 
U = .05 and U = .09 with A = 2 and A = 4
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Finding the Optimal Complete Portfolio Using 
Indifference Curves
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Expected Returns on Four Indifference Curves and the CAL
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Risk Tolerance and Asset Allocation 
• The investor must choose one optimal 
portfolio, C, from the set of feasible choices 
– Expected return of the complete portfolio: 
E(rc )  rf  y E(rP )  rf  
– Variance: 
2 2 2 
C P s  y s
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Summary 
The Asset Allocation process has 2 steps: 
1. Determine the CAL 
2. Find the point of highest utility along that 
line
MGB Portfolio Management I 
One word on Indifference Curves 
• If you see the IC curves over (mean,st. dev) you will 
note that these are all nice smooth concave curves. 
– This is an assumption. 
– Note that investors have preference over random variables 
(representing payoff/return). A random variable, in general, is 
not completely described by (mean, variance). 
• That is, in general, we can have X and Y with mean(X) < mean (Y) 
and var(X)=var(Y) BUT X is ranked better than Y nonetheless.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Passive Strategies: 
The Capital Market Line 
• A natural candidate for a passively held risky 
asset would be a well-diversified portfolio of 
common stocks such as the S&P 500. 
• The capital market line (CML) is the capital 
allocation line formed from 1-month T-bills 
and a broad index of common stocks (e.g. the 
S&P 500).
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Passive Strategies: 
The Capital Market Line 
• The CML is given by a strategy that involves 
investment in two passive portfolios: 
1. virtually risk-free short-term T-bills (or a 
money market fund) 
2. a fund of common stocks that mimics a 
broad market index.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Passive Strategies: 
The Capital Market Line 
• From 1926 to 2009, the passive risky 
portfolio offered an average risk premium of 
7.9% with a standard deviation of 20.8%, 
resulting in a reward-to-volatility ratio of 
.38.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Diversification and Portfolio Risk 
• Suppose there is a single common source of risk in the economy. 
• All assets are exposed both to this single common source of risk and a separate 
197 
idiosyncratic source of risk that is uncorrelated across assets. 
• Then the insurance principle says that if we construct a portfolio of a very large 
number of these assets, the combined portfolio will only reflect the common 
risk. The idiosyncratic risk will average out and tend to zero as the number of 
securities grows very large. 
• Thus, if there are many home fire insurance policyholders and the risk of fire is 
uncorrelated across similarly sized homes, then if the number of policy holders 
is very large, the actual losses in the portfolio tends to the expected loss per 
home times the number of homes. 
• This means that homeowners, by pooling their risk, can remove their exposure 
to risk completely. 
• In practice, the risks are not completed uncorrelated across homes but a fair 
amount of risk reduction is possible. 
• The next slide shows graphically how portfolio risk would be affected in these 
conditions.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Diversification and Portfolio Risk 
198
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Diversification and Portfolio Risk 
199
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Investment Opportunity Sets: Risky Assets 
This graph shows the portfolio opportunity 
set for different values of . 
That is, the combination of portfolio E(r) 
and s than can be obtained by combining 
the two asset. 
In our example, the equity asset has an 
expected return of 13%, while the bond 
asset has an expected return of 8%. 
The curved line joining the two assets D 
and E is, in effect, part of the opportunity 
set of (E(R), s) combinations available to 
the investor. To get the entire opportunity 
set, we simply extend this curve both 
beyond E and beyond D.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Optimal Portfolio: Two Risky Assets
MGB Portfolio Management I 
7-202 
Covariance and Correlation 
• Portfolio risk depends on the correlation 
between the returns of the assets in the 
portfolio 
• Covariance and the correlation coefficient 
provide a measure of the way returns of 
two assets vary
MGB Portfolio Management I 
7-203 
Two-Security Portfolio: Return 
r 
 p w r w r 
D D E E 
r 
 
Portfolio Return 
P 
w 
 
Bond Weight 
D 
r 
 
Bond Return 
D 
w 
 
Equity Weight 
E 
r 
 
Equity Return 
E 
E ( r )  w E ( r )  w E ( r 
) p D D E E
MGB Portfolio Management I 
7-204 
Two-Security Portfolio: Risk 
D D E E D E  D E  w w 2w w Cov r ,r 2 2 2 2 2 
p s  s  s  
= Variance of Security D 
= Variance of Security E 
= Covariance of returns for 
Security D and Security E 
2 
D s 
2 
E s 
  D E Cov r , r
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Two-Security Portfolio: Risk 
• Another way to express variance of the 
portfolio: 
2 ( , ) ( , ) 2 ( , ) P D D D D E E E E D E D E w s  w Cov r r  w w Cov r r  w w Cov r r
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Covariance 
Cov(rD,rE) = DEsDsE 
D,E = Correlation coefficient of 
returns 
sD = Standard deviation of 
returns for Security D 
sE = Standard deviation of 
returns for Security E
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Correlation Coefficients: Possible Values 
Range of values for 1,2 
+ 1.0 >  > -1.0 
If  = 1.0, the securities are perfectly 
positively correlated 
If  = - 1.0, the securities are perfectly 
negatively correlated
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Correlation Coefficients 
• When ρDE = 1, there is no diversification 
P E E D D s  w s  w s 
• When ρDE = -1, a perfect hedge is possible 
s 
E w   w 
D 
D 
 1 
s  
s 
D E
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Computation of Portfolio Variance From the Covariance Matrix
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Three-Asset Portfolio 
1 1 2 2 3 3 E(rp )  w E(r )  w E(r )  w E(r ) 
2 s ws ws ws p    
2 
3 
2 
3 
2 
2 
2 
2 
2 
1 
2 
1 
1 2 1,2 1 3 1,3 2 3 2,3  2w ws  2w ws  2w ws
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Expected Return as a Function of Investment 
Proportions
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Standard Deviation as a Function of Investment 
Proportions
MGB Portfolio Management I 
7-213 
The Minimum Variance Portfolio 
• The minimum variance 
portfolio is the portfolio 
composed of the risky 
assets that has the 
smallest standard 
deviation, the portfolio 
with least risk. 
• When correlation is less 
than +1, the portfolio 
standard deviation may 
be smaller than that of 
either of the individual 
component assets. 
• When correlation is -1, 
the standard deviation 
of the minimum 
variance portfolio is 
zero.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Portfolio Expected Return as a Function of Standard Deviation
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Correlation Effects 
• The amount of possible risk reduction through 
diversification depends on the correlation. 
• The risk reduction potential increases as the 
correlation approaches -1. 
– If  = +1.0, no risk reduction is possible. 
– If  = 0, σP may be less than the standard deviation 
of either component asset. 
– If  = -1.0, a riskless hedge is possible.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Optimal Portfolio Selection 
• We can solve the optimization problem to 
compute the following useful formulas: 
• The minimum variance portfolio of risky assets 
D, E is given by the following formula: 
• The optimal portfolio for an investor with a risk 
aversion parameter, A, is given by this formula: 
푤퐷 = 
퐸 푟퐷 − 퐸 푟퐸 + 0.01퐴[휎2 
퐸 − 퐶표푣 푟퐷, 푟퐸 ] 
0.01퐴[휎2 
퐸 + 휎2 
퐷 − 퐶표푣 푟퐷, 푟퐸 ]
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Numerical Example 
Debt Equity 
2 mutual funds 
Expected Return, E(r) 8% 13% 
Standard deviation, σ 12% 20% 
Covariance, Cov (rD, rE) 72 
Correlation Coefficient, ρDE 0.30 
Wmin(D) = σ2 
E – Cov (rD,rE) = 202 -72 = 0.82 
σ2 
D + σ2 
E – 2Cov (rD,rE) 122 + 202 – 2x72 
Wmin(E) = 1-0.82 = 0.18 
The minimum variance portfolio 
σ = [0.822 x 122 + 0.182 x 202 + 2x0.82x0.18x72]1/2 = 11.45% 
Sharpe Ratio SA= E(rA) – rf = 8.9 – 5 = 0.34 
σA 11.45
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Optimal Portfolio Selection 
We now introduce a risk free asset. 
The expected return on a portfolio 
consisting of a risk free asset and a risky 
portfolio is, of course, a weighted 
average of the expected returns on the 
component assets. But the standard 
deviation of the portfolio is also linear in 
the standard deviation of the risky asset. 
Hence the CAL if there is one risk free 
asset and a risky portfolio is simply a 
straight line passing through the two 
assets, as shown in the figure on the 
right.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Numerical Example 
Debt Equity 
2 mutual funds 
Expected Return, E(r) 8% 13% 
Standard deviation, σ 12% 20% 
Covariance, Cov (rD, rE) 72 
Correlation Coefficient, ρDE 0.30 
B has an E(r) = 9.5% and a σ of 11.7% giving it a risk premium of 4.5% 
Its Sharpe Ratio is SB = 9.5 – 5.0 = 0.38 
11.7 
SB – SA = .38 - .34 = 0.04. We get 4 basis points per percentage point increase in risk.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Optimal Portfolio Selection 
The slope of each of the CALs drawn 
in the previous figure is a reward-to-volatility 
(Sharpe) ratio. Since we 
want this ratio to be maximized, the 
single CAL for the set of risky and risk 
free assets is the CAL with the 
steepest slope, i.e. the highest 
Sharpe ratio.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Optimal Portfolio Selection 
If we now superimpose the 
indifference curve map on the 
CAL, we can compute the 
complete optimal portfolio.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Optimal Portfolio Selection 
• The formula for the tangency portfolio (shown as 
portfolio C on the picture in the previous slide) is: 
Max Sp = 
퐸 푟푃 −푟푓 
휎푃 
• Note that the investor risk aversion coefficient does not 
show up in this formula. 
• Once the tangency portfolio is available, all investors 
choose a combination of this portfolio (denoted p in the 
formula below) and the risk-free asset. The formula for 
this, which we know already, is: 
푦 ∗ = 
퐸 푟푃 − 푟푓 
0.01퐴휎2 
푃
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Optimal Portfolio Selection 
• WD = (8-5)400 – (13-5)72__________ = 0.40 
(8-5)400 + (13-5)144 – (8-5+13-5)72 
• WE = 1-0.4 = 0.60 
• σp = (0.42 x 144 + 0.62x400 + 2 x 0.4 x 0.6 x 72)1/2 = 14.2 
• Sp = 11-5/14.2 = 0.42 
• Note that the investor risk aversion coefficient does not show up in 
this formula. 
• Once the tangency portfolio is available, all investors choose a 
combination of this portfolio (denoted p in the formula below) and 
the risk-free asset. The formula for this, which we know already, is: 
푦 ∗ = 
퐸 푟푃 −푟푓 
0.01퐴휎푃 
2 = 11 – 5 /(0.01 x 4 x 14.22) = -.7439
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Optimal Portfolio Selection 
224 
The investor will invest 74.39% of the wealth in Portfolio P and 25.62 in T-bills. 
Portfolio P consists of 40% bonds and 60% stocks so 0.4x74.39 = 29.76% of the 
wealth will be in bonds and 0.6 x 74.39 = 44.63% of the wealth will be in stocks.
MGB Portfolio Management I
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Numerical Example 
You have available to you, two mutual funds, whose returns have a correlation of 
0.23. Both funds belong to the fund category “Balanced – Domestic.” Here is 
some information on the fund returns for the last six years (obtained from 
http://www.financialweb.com/funds/): 
In addition, you can also invest in a risk free 1-year T-bill yielding 6.286%. The 
expected return on the market portfolio is 20%. 
a.If you have a risk aversion coefficient of 4, and you have a total of $20,000 to 
invest, how much should you invest in each of the three investment vehicles? 
b.What is the standard deviation of your optimal portfolio? 
226 
Year 
Capital Value 
Fund 
Green Century 
Balanced Year 
Capital Value 
Fund 
Green Century 
Balanced 
1999 21.32% -10.12% 1996 21.48% 18.26% 
1998 21.44% 18.91% 1995 0.91% -4.28% 
1997 9.86% 24.91% 1994 10.79% -0.47% 
average 14.30% 7.87% 
stdev 8.52% 14.57%
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Solution 
• a. Using the formula, we can find the portfolio weights for the tangent 
portfolio of risky assets as follows: 
which works out to 1641.13/1529.31 = 1.073. Hence wGCB = 1-(1.073) = - 
0.073. 
In order to find the optimal combination of the tangent portfolio and the 
risk free asset for our investor, we need to compute the expected return 
on the tangent portfolio and the variance of portfolio returns. 
E(Rtgtport) = 1.073(14.3) + (-0.073)(7.87) = 14.77% 
Var(Rtgtport) = (1.073)2(8.52)2 + (-0.073)2(14.57)2 + 
2(-0.073)(1.073)(8.52)(14.57)(0.23) = 82.47. Hence, stgtport = 9.08%
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Solution (Contd.) 
Using the formula y* = [E(Rport) – Rf]/0.01AVar(Rtgtport), we get y* = = 2.57; 
hence the proportion in the riskfree asset is -1.57. In other words, the 
investor borrows to invest in the tangent portfolio. 
If the investor’s total outlay is $20,000, the amount borrowed equals 
(20000)(1.57) = $31,400. This provides a total of $51,400 for investment 
in the tangent portfolio. However, the tangent portfolio itself consists of 
shortselling Green Century Balanced to the extent of (0.073)(51,400) = 
3752.20, providing a total of 51,400 + 3752.2 = $55,152.20 for investment 
in Capital Value Fund. 
b. The standard deviation of the optimal portfolio is 2.57(9.08) = 
23.34%. The expected return on the optimal portfolio is 2.57(14.77) + (- 
1.57)(6.286) = 28.09%
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Optimal Portfolio Selection 
• Until now, we have dealt with the case of two risky assets. We now 
increase the number of risky assets to more than two. 
• In this case, graphically, the situation remains the same, as we will 
see, except that the opportunity set instead of being a simple 
parabolic curve becomes an area, bounded by a parabolic curve. 
• However, since all investors are interested in higher expected return 
and lower variance of returns, only the northwestern frontier of this 
set is relevant, and so the graphic illustration remains comparable. 
• Mathematically, the computation of the tangency portfolio is a bit 
more complicated, and will require the solution of a system of n 
equations. We will not go further into it, here. 
• We now look at the graphical illustration of the problem
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Markowitz Portfolio Selection 
• The first step is to 
determine the risk-return 
opportunities 
available. 
• All portfolios that lie 
on the minimum-variance 
frontier 
from the global 
minimum-variance 
portfolio and 
upward provide the 
best risk-return 
combinations
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Markowitz Portfolio Selection 
• We now search 
for the CAL with 
the highest 
reward-to-variability 
ratio
MGB Portfolio Management I 
Markowitz Portfolio Selection 
• The separation property tells us that the portfolio choice 
problem may be separated into two independent tasks 
– Determination of the optimal risky portfolio is purely 
technical. 
– Allocation of the complete portfolio to T-bills versus the risky 
portfolio depends on personal preference. 
• Thus, everyone invests in P, regardless of their degree of risk 
aversion. 
– More risk averse investors put more in the risk-free asset. 
– Less risk averse investors put more in P.
MGB Portfolio Management I 
More on Diversification 
• We have seen that 
D D E E D E  D E  w w 2w w Cov r ,r 2 2 2 2 2 
p s  s  s  
• If we have three assets, portfolio variance is given by: 
2 s ws ws ws p    
2 
3 
2 
3 
2 
2 
2 
2 
2 
1 
2 
1 
1 2 1,2 1 3 1,3 2 3 2,3  2w ws  2w ws  2w ws 
• If we generalize it to n assets, we can write the formula as: 
• Defining the average variance and the average covariance, we then get 
• That is, the portfolio variance is a weighted average of the average variance and 
the average covariance. 
• However, as the number of assets increases, the relative weight on the variance 
goes to zero, while that on the covariance goes to 1. 
• Hence we see that it is the covariance between the returns on the component 
assets that is important for the determination of the portfolio variance.

Más contenido relacionado

La actualidad más candente

Efficient market hypothesis
Efficient market hypothesisEfficient market hypothesis
Efficient market hypothesis
Kamlesh Pawar
 
Chapter 06_ Are Financial Markets Efficient?
Chapter 06_ Are Financial Markets Efficient?Chapter 06_ Are Financial Markets Efficient?
Chapter 06_ Are Financial Markets Efficient?
Rusman Mukhlis
 
Chapter 10_The Bond Market
Chapter 10_The Bond MarketChapter 10_The Bond Market
Chapter 10_The Bond Market
Rusman Mukhlis
 
Investment portfolio of risky security and efficient frontier
Investment portfolio of risky security and efficient frontierInvestment portfolio of risky security and efficient frontier
Investment portfolio of risky security and efficient frontier
Ravi kumar
 
Updated fundamentals of investment.ppt
Updated   fundamentals of investment.pptUpdated   fundamentals of investment.ppt
Updated fundamentals of investment.ppt
Romy Cagampan
 

La actualidad más candente (20)

Efficient market hypothesis
Efficient market hypothesisEfficient market hypothesis
Efficient market hypothesis
 
Valuation of securities
Valuation of securitiesValuation of securities
Valuation of securities
 
Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs)
 Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs) Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs)
Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs)
 
Fundamental and Technical Analysis
Fundamental and Technical AnalysisFundamental and Technical Analysis
Fundamental and Technical Analysis
 
Chapter 06_ Are Financial Markets Efficient?
Chapter 06_ Are Financial Markets Efficient?Chapter 06_ Are Financial Markets Efficient?
Chapter 06_ Are Financial Markets Efficient?
 
Chapter 1 introduction to investment
Chapter 1 introduction to investmentChapter 1 introduction to investment
Chapter 1 introduction to investment
 
Chapter 10_The Bond Market
Chapter 10_The Bond MarketChapter 10_The Bond Market
Chapter 10_The Bond Market
 
EFFICIENT MARKET THEORY.pptx
EFFICIENT MARKET THEORY.pptxEFFICIENT MARKET THEORY.pptx
EFFICIENT MARKET THEORY.pptx
 
Derivatives market in india
Derivatives market in indiaDerivatives market in india
Derivatives market in india
 
Portfolio Evaluation and Revision
Portfolio Evaluation and RevisionPortfolio Evaluation and Revision
Portfolio Evaluation and Revision
 
Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH)
Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH)Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH)
Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH)
 
Determination of interest rate
Determination of interest rateDetermination of interest rate
Determination of interest rate
 
FUNCTIONS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS
FUNCTIONS OF FINANCIAL MARKETSFUNCTIONS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS
FUNCTIONS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS
 
Introduction of foreign exchange market, characteristics,
Introduction of foreign exchange market, characteristics,Introduction of foreign exchange market, characteristics,
Introduction of foreign exchange market, characteristics,
 
Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) and Insider Trading
Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) and Insider TradingEfficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) and Insider Trading
Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) and Insider Trading
 
Investment portfolio of risky security and efficient frontier
Investment portfolio of risky security and efficient frontierInvestment portfolio of risky security and efficient frontier
Investment portfolio of risky security and efficient frontier
 
Derivatives - Basics of Derivatives contract covered in this ppt
Derivatives - Basics of Derivatives contract covered in this pptDerivatives - Basics of Derivatives contract covered in this ppt
Derivatives - Basics of Derivatives contract covered in this ppt
 
Derivatives
DerivativesDerivatives
Derivatives
 
Efficient Market Hypothesis
Efficient Market HypothesisEfficient Market Hypothesis
Efficient Market Hypothesis
 
Updated fundamentals of investment.ppt
Updated   fundamentals of investment.pptUpdated   fundamentals of investment.ppt
Updated fundamentals of investment.ppt
 

Destacado

CIE39 Troyes
CIE39 TroyesCIE39 Troyes
CIE39 Troyes
sovvie
 
Master thesis presentation
Master thesis presentationMaster thesis presentation
Master thesis presentation
Sofia Nyyssönen
 
Portfolio Management
Portfolio ManagementPortfolio Management
Portfolio Management
ghanchifarhan
 

Destacado (14)

Market efficiency
Market efficiencyMarket efficiency
Market efficiency
 
CIE39 Troyes
CIE39 TroyesCIE39 Troyes
CIE39 Troyes
 
Ch10 final
Ch10 finalCh10 final
Ch10 final
 
Dea
DeaDea
Dea
 
Data Envelopment Analysis
Data Envelopment AnalysisData Envelopment Analysis
Data Envelopment Analysis
 
Random Walks, Efficient Markets & Stock Prices
Random Walks, Efficient Markets & Stock PricesRandom Walks, Efficient Markets & Stock Prices
Random Walks, Efficient Markets & Stock Prices
 
Efficient market hypothesis
Efficient market hypothesisEfficient market hypothesis
Efficient market hypothesis
 
DEA
DEADEA
DEA
 
Master thesis presentation
Master thesis presentationMaster thesis presentation
Master thesis presentation
 
Thesis presentation
Thesis presentationThesis presentation
Thesis presentation
 
Fundamental analysis and technical analysis
Fundamental analysis and technical analysisFundamental analysis and technical analysis
Fundamental analysis and technical analysis
 
Portfolio Management
Portfolio ManagementPortfolio Management
Portfolio Management
 
Sample 21Communication studies I.A / S.B.A
Sample 21Communication studies I.A / S.B.ASample 21Communication studies I.A / S.B.A
Sample 21Communication studies I.A / S.B.A
 
FS6 Episode 3: The Teacher in a School Setting
FS6 Episode 3: The Teacher in a School SettingFS6 Episode 3: The Teacher in a School Setting
FS6 Episode 3: The Teacher in a School Setting
 

Similar a Market efficiency and portfolio theory

Similar a Market efficiency and portfolio theory (20)

Efficient market hypothesis
Efficient market hypothesisEfficient market hypothesis
Efficient market hypothesis
 
Arbitrage pricing theory & Efficient market hypothesis
Arbitrage pricing theory & Efficient market hypothesisArbitrage pricing theory & Efficient market hypothesis
Arbitrage pricing theory & Efficient market hypothesis
 
Efficient market hypothesis
Efficient market hypothesisEfficient market hypothesis
Efficient market hypothesis
 
Chapter 6 Financial markets and institutions.pdf
Chapter 6 Financial markets and institutions.pdfChapter 6 Financial markets and institutions.pdf
Chapter 6 Financial markets and institutions.pdf
 
Market efficiency
Market efficiencyMarket efficiency
Market efficiency
 
Efficient market Hypothesis(EMH).pptx
Efficient market Hypothesis(EMH).pptxEfficient market Hypothesis(EMH).pptx
Efficient market Hypothesis(EMH).pptx
 
Ch06 efficient market
Ch06   efficient marketCh06   efficient market
Ch06 efficient market
 
Lecture 7 - Stock Market and EMF
Lecture 7 - Stock Market and EMFLecture 7 - Stock Market and EMF
Lecture 7 - Stock Market and EMF
 
Efficient market Hypothesis that explains the Capital asset pricing model
Efficient market Hypothesis that explains the Capital asset pricing modelEfficient market Hypothesis that explains the Capital asset pricing model
Efficient market Hypothesis that explains the Capital asset pricing model
 
Perspective on Active & Passive Manageemnt of Fund
Perspective on Active & Passive Manageemnt of FundPerspective on Active & Passive Manageemnt of Fund
Perspective on Active & Passive Manageemnt of Fund
 
value-1.ppt
value-1.pptvalue-1.ppt
value-1.ppt
 
Theories of nonrandom price motion
Theories of nonrandom price motionTheories of nonrandom price motion
Theories of nonrandom price motion
 
Lesson 23.ppt
Lesson 23.pptLesson 23.ppt
Lesson 23.ppt
 
V if
V ifV if
V if
 
market efficieny group4.pptx
market efficieny group4.pptxmarket efficieny group4.pptx
market efficieny group4.pptx
 
Market efficiency and emh
Market efficiency and emhMarket efficiency and emh
Market efficiency and emh
 
Mishkin fmi9ge ppt_c06
Mishkin fmi9ge ppt_c06Mishkin fmi9ge ppt_c06
Mishkin fmi9ge ppt_c06
 
Asset pricing models
Asset pricing modelsAsset pricing models
Asset pricing models
 
Efficient Capital Market.pptx
Efficient Capital Market.pptxEfficient Capital Market.pptx
Efficient Capital Market.pptx
 
Market Efficiency.pptx
Market Efficiency.pptxMarket Efficiency.pptx
Market Efficiency.pptx
 

Más de Aakash Kulkarni

Portfolio management sessions 4&5 (1)
Portfolio management sessions 4&5 (1)Portfolio management sessions 4&5 (1)
Portfolio management sessions 4&5 (1)
Aakash Kulkarni
 
Merger And Acquisition - Reasons for Failure and Counter Measures
Merger And Acquisition - Reasons for Failure and Counter MeasuresMerger And Acquisition - Reasons for Failure and Counter Measures
Merger And Acquisition - Reasons for Failure and Counter Measures
Aakash Kulkarni
 
Banking without banks group 1
Banking without banks group 1Banking without banks group 1
Banking without banks group 1
Aakash Kulkarni
 
The global business environment presentation slides - sessions 2-8
The global business environment   presentation slides - sessions 2-8The global business environment   presentation slides - sessions 2-8
The global business environment presentation slides - sessions 2-8
Aakash Kulkarni
 
Proctergamble 090329014100-phpapp02
Proctergamble 090329014100-phpapp02Proctergamble 090329014100-phpapp02
Proctergamble 090329014100-phpapp02
Aakash Kulkarni
 
Israel 100224205701-phpapp02
Israel 100224205701-phpapp02Israel 100224205701-phpapp02
Israel 100224205701-phpapp02
Aakash Kulkarni
 
Introduction to business statistics
Introduction to business statisticsIntroduction to business statistics
Introduction to business statistics
Aakash Kulkarni
 
Pokayokefinalppt 1334856991612-phpapp01-120419123833-phpapp01
Pokayokefinalppt 1334856991612-phpapp01-120419123833-phpapp01Pokayokefinalppt 1334856991612-phpapp01-120419123833-phpapp01
Pokayokefinalppt 1334856991612-phpapp01-120419123833-phpapp01
Aakash Kulkarni
 
Overstated role of capital
Overstated role of capitalOverstated role of capital
Overstated role of capital
Aakash Kulkarni
 

Más de Aakash Kulkarni (20)

Aakash Kulkarni
Aakash KulkarniAakash Kulkarni
Aakash Kulkarni
 
Portfolio management sessions 4&5 (1)
Portfolio management sessions 4&5 (1)Portfolio management sessions 4&5 (1)
Portfolio management sessions 4&5 (1)
 
Portfolio management sessions 1&2
Portfolio management sessions 1&2Portfolio management sessions 1&2
Portfolio management sessions 1&2
 
Merger And Acquisition - Reasons for Failure and Counter Measures
Merger And Acquisition - Reasons for Failure and Counter MeasuresMerger And Acquisition - Reasons for Failure and Counter Measures
Merger And Acquisition - Reasons for Failure and Counter Measures
 
Banking without banks group 1
Banking without banks group 1Banking without banks group 1
Banking without banks group 1
 
The global business environment presentation slides - sessions 2-8
The global business environment   presentation slides - sessions 2-8The global business environment   presentation slides - sessions 2-8
The global business environment presentation slides - sessions 2-8
 
Proctergamble 090329014100-phpapp02
Proctergamble 090329014100-phpapp02Proctergamble 090329014100-phpapp02
Proctergamble 090329014100-phpapp02
 
Poli30 session14 2008
Poli30 session14 2008Poli30 session14 2008
Poli30 session14 2008
 
Meddeb riad 29-04-08
Meddeb riad 29-04-08Meddeb riad 29-04-08
Meddeb riad 29-04-08
 
Israel 100224205701-phpapp02
Israel 100224205701-phpapp02Israel 100224205701-phpapp02
Israel 100224205701-phpapp02
 
Introduction to business statistics
Introduction to business statisticsIntroduction to business statistics
Introduction to business statistics
 
Cima certification dof
Cima certification dofCima certification dof
Cima certification dof
 
Tuapr 2011 figures_web
Tuapr 2011 figures_webTuapr 2011 figures_web
Tuapr 2011 figures_web
 
What is-six-sigma69
What is-six-sigma69What is-six-sigma69
What is-six-sigma69
 
Us shut down
Us   shut downUs   shut down
Us shut down
 
Poke yoke
Poke yokePoke yoke
Poke yoke
 
Pokayokefinalppt 1334856991612-phpapp01-120419123833-phpapp01
Pokayokefinalppt 1334856991612-phpapp01-120419123833-phpapp01Pokayokefinalppt 1334856991612-phpapp01-120419123833-phpapp01
Pokayokefinalppt 1334856991612-phpapp01-120419123833-phpapp01
 
Plant location
Plant locationPlant location
Plant location
 
Overstated role of capital
Overstated role of capitalOverstated role of capital
Overstated role of capital
 
Mproof smpl 1
Mproof smpl 1Mproof smpl 1
Mproof smpl 1
 

Último

The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptxThe basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
heathfieldcps1
 

Último (20)

Google Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptx
Google Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptxGoogle Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptx
Google Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptx
 
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
 
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptxInterdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
 
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning ExhibitSociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
 
Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...
Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...
Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...
 
Wellbeing inclusion and digital dystopias.pptx
Wellbeing inclusion and digital dystopias.pptxWellbeing inclusion and digital dystopias.pptx
Wellbeing inclusion and digital dystopias.pptx
 
NO1 Top Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
NO1 Top Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...NO1 Top Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
NO1 Top Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
 
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
 
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfMicro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
 
This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.
This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.
This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.
 
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
 
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptxCOMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
 
Fostering Friendships - Enhancing Social Bonds in the Classroom
Fostering Friendships - Enhancing Social Bonds  in the ClassroomFostering Friendships - Enhancing Social Bonds  in the Classroom
Fostering Friendships - Enhancing Social Bonds in the Classroom
 
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
 
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptxREMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
 
SOC 101 Demonstration of Learning Presentation
SOC 101 Demonstration of Learning PresentationSOC 101 Demonstration of Learning Presentation
SOC 101 Demonstration of Learning Presentation
 
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - EnglishGraduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English
 
Unit 3 Emotional Intelligence and Spiritual Intelligence.pdf
Unit 3 Emotional Intelligence and Spiritual Intelligence.pdfUnit 3 Emotional Intelligence and Spiritual Intelligence.pdf
Unit 3 Emotional Intelligence and Spiritual Intelligence.pdf
 
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptxThe basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
 
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdfUGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
 

Market efficiency and portfolio theory

  • 1. MGB Portfolio Management I MARKET EFFICIENCY
  • 2. MGB Portfolio Management I RANDOM WALK
  • 3. MGB Portfolio Management I Random Walk In 1973 when author Burton Malkiel wrote "A Random Walk Down Wall Street", which remains on the top-seller list for finance books.  Strict Definition ─ Successive stock returns are independent and identically distributed. This implies that past movement or trend of a stock price or market cannot be used to predict its future movement.  Common Definition ─ Price changes are essentially unpredictable This is the idea that stocks take a random and unpredictable path. A follower of the random walk theory believes it's impossible to outperform the market without assuming additional risk. Critics of the theory, however, contend that stocks do maintain price trends over time - in other words, that it is possible to outperform the market by carefully selecting entry and exit points for equity investments.
  • 4. MGB Portfolio Management I Random Walk Financial Economists were disturbed as this seemed to imply that stock markets were dominated by some erratic market psychology or some “animal spirit” that followed no logical rules. It soon became apparent however, that random price movements indicated a well-functioning or efficient market, not an irrational one.
  • 5. MGB Portfolio Management I Random Walk And why is that? Because any new information that could be used to predict stock performance must already reflect in the stock price. As soon as any new information is available that can impact stock prices, investors will buy/sell the security immediately to its fair level where only ordinary return can be expected (rate of return commensurate with the risk). However, if prices are bid immediately to fair levels. On getting new information, it must be that the increase/decrease is due to only that new information. But New information, by definition, must be unpredictable. If not, then the information would already be priced into the price of the security! So, stock prices should follow a random walk, that is, price changes should be random and unpredictable. Randomly evolving prices are a result of intelligent investors discovering relevant information and by their action moving the prices.
  • 6. MGB Portfolio Management I THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS
  • 7. MGB Portfolio Management I The Efficient Market Hypothesis  Expectations are very important in our financial system. ─ Expectations of returns, risk, and liquidity impact asset demand ─ Inflationary expectations impact bond prices ─ Expectations not only affect our understanding of markets, but also how financial institutions operate.  To better understand expectations, we examine the efficient markets hypothesis. ─ Framework for understanding what information is useful and what is not ─ However, we need to validate the hypothesis with real market data. The results are mixed, but generally supportive of the idea.
  • 8. MGB Portfolio Management I The Efficient Market Hypothesis  In sum, we will look at the basic reasoning behind the efficient market hypothesis. We also examine empirical evidence examining this idea: ─ The Efficient Market Hypothesis ─ Evidence on the Efficient Market Hypothesis ─ Behavioral Finance
  • 9. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Market Hypothesis • The rate of return for any position is the sum of the capital gains (Pt+1 – Pt) plus any cash payments (C): • At the start of a period, the unknown element is the future price: Pt+1. But, investors do have some expectation of that price, thus giving us an expected rate of return.
  • 10. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Market Hypothesis The Efficient Market Hypothesis views the expectations as equal to optimal forecasts using all available information. This implies: Assuming the market is in equilibrium: Re = R* [market’s equilibrium return] Put these ideas together: efficient market hypothesis Rof = R*
  • 11. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Market Hypothesis Rof = R* •This equation tells us that current prices in a financial market will be set so that the optimal forecast of a security’s return using all available information equals the security’s equilibrium return. •As a result, a security’s price fully reflects all available information in an efficient market. •Note, R* depends on risk, liquidity, other asset returns …
  • 12. MGB Portfolio Management I Rationale Behind the Hypothesis  When an unexploited profit opportunity arises on a security (so-called because, on average, people would be earning more than they should, given the characteristics of that security), investors will rush to buy until the price rises to the point that the returns are normal again.  Investors do not leave $ bills lying on the sidewalk.
  • 13. MGB Portfolio Management I Rationale Behind the Hypothesis • Why efficient market hypothesis makes sense If Rof > R* → Pt ↑ → Rof ↓ If Rof < R* → Pt ↓ → Rof ↑ Until Rof = R* • All unexploited profit opportunities eliminated • Efficient market condition holds even if there are uninformed, irrational participants in market
  • 14. MGB Portfolio Management I Rationale Behind the Hypothesis  In an efficient market, all unexploited profit opportunities will be eliminated.  Not every investor need be aware of every security and situation.  Only a few investors (even 1 big one) are needed to eliminate unexploited profit opportunities and push the market price to its equilibrium level.
  • 15. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Capital Markets • In an efficient capital market, security prices adjust rapidly to the arrival of new information, therefore the current prices of securities reflect all information about the security • Whether markets are efficient has been extensively researched and remains controversial
  • 16. MGB Portfolio Management I Why Should Capital Markets Be Efficient? The premises of an efficient market – A large number of competing profit-maximizing participants analyze and value securities, each independently of the others – New information regarding securities comes to the market in a random fashion – Profit-maximizing investors adjust security prices rapidly to reflect the effect of new information Conclusion: the expected returns implicit in the current price of a security should reflect its risk
  • 17. MGB Portfolio Management I Alternative Efficient Market Hypotheses (EMH) • Random Walk Hypothesis – changes in security prices occur randomly • Fair Game Model – current market price reflect all available information about a security and the expected return based upon this price is consistent with its risk • Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) - divided into three sub-hypotheses depending on the information set involved
  • 18. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Market Hypotheses (EMH) • Weak-Form EMH - prices reflect all security-market information • Semistrong-form EMH - prices reflect all public information • Strong-form EMH - prices reflect all public and private information
  • 19. MGB Portfolio Management I Weak-Form EMH • Current prices reflect all security-market information, including the historical sequence of prices, rates of return, trading volume data, and other market-generated information • This implies that past rates of return and other market data should have no relationship with future rates of return
  • 20. MGB Portfolio Management I Semistrong-Form EMH • Current security prices reflect all public information, including market and non-market information • This implies that decisions made on new information after it is public should not lead to above-average risk-adjusted profits from those transactions
  • 21. MGB Portfolio Management I Strong-Form EMH • Stock prices fully reflect all information from public and private sources • This implies that no group of investors should be able to consistently derive above-average risk-adjusted rates of return • This assumes perfect markets in which all information is cost-free and available to everyone at the same time
  • 22. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Weak-Form EMH • Statistical tests of independence between rates of return – Autocorrelation tests have mixed results – Runs tests indicate randomness in prices
  • 23. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Weak-Form EMH • Comparison of trading rules to a buy-and-hold policy is difficult because trading rules can be complex and there are too many to test them all – Filter rules yield above-average profits with small filters, but only before taking into account transactions costs – Trading rule results have been mixed, and most have not been able to beat a buy-and-hold policy
  • 24. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Weak-Form EMH • Testing constraints – Use only publicly available data – Include all transactions costs – Adjust the results for risk
  • 25. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Weak-Form EMH • Results generally support the weak-form EMH, but results are not unanimous
  • 26. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests of the Semistrong Form of Market Efficiency Two sets of studies • Time series analysis of returns or the cross section distribution of returns for individual stocks • Event studies that examine how fast stock prices adjust to specific significant economic events
  • 27. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Test results should adjusted a security’s rate of return for the rates of return of the overall market during the period considered Arit = Rit - Rmt where: Arit = abnormal rate of return on security i during period t Rit = rate of return on security i during period t Rmt =rate of return on a market index during period t
  • 28. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Time series tests for abnormal rates of return – short-horizon returns have limited results – long-horizon returns analysis has been quite successful based on • dividend yield (D/P) • default spread • term structure spread – Quarterly earnings reports may yield abnormal returns due to • unanticipated earnings change
  • 29. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Quarterly Earnings Reports – Large Standardized Unexpected Earnings (SUEs) result in abnormal stock price changes, with over 50% of the change happening after the announcement – Unexpected earnings can explain up to 80% of stock drift over a time period • These results suggest that the earnings surprise is not instantaneously reflected in security prices
  • 30. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • The January Anomaly – Stocks with negative returns during the prior year had higher returns right after the first of the year – Tax selling toward the end of the year has been mentioned as the reason for this phenomenon – Such a seasonal pattern is inconsistent with the EMH
  • 31. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Other calendar effects – All the market’s cumulative advance occurs during the first half of trading months – Monday/weekend returns were significantly negative – For large firms, the negative Monday effect occurred before the market opened (it was a weekend effect), whereas for smaller firms, most of the negative Monday effect occurred during the day on Monday (it was a Monday trading effect)
  • 32. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Predicting cross-sectional returns – All securities should have equal risk-adjusted returns • Studies examine alternative measures of size or quality as a tool to rank stocks in terms of risk-adjusted returns – These tests involve a joint hypothesis and are dependent both on market efficiency and the asset pricing model used
  • 33. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Price-earnings ratios and returns – Low P/E stocks experienced superior risk-adjusted results relative to the market, whereas high P/E stocks had significantly inferior risk-adjusted results – Publicly available P/E ratios possess valuable information regarding future returns – This is inconsistent with semistrong efficiency
  • 34. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Price-Earnings/Growth Rate (PEG) ratios – Studies have hypothesized an inverse relationship between the PEG ratio and subsequent rates of return. This is inconsistent with the EMH – However, the results related to using the PEG ratio to select stocks are mixed
  • 35. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • The size effect (total market value) – Several studies have examined the impact of size on the risk-adjusted rates of return – The studies indicate that risk-adjusted returns for extended periods indicate that the small firms consistently experienced significantly larger risk-adjusted returns than large firms – Firm size is a major efficient market anomaly – Could this have caused the P/E results previously studied?
  • 36. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • The P/E studies and size studies are dual tests of the EMH and the CAPM • Abnormal returns could occur because either – markets are inefficient or – market model is not properly specified and provides incorrect estimates of risk and expected returns
  • 37. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Adjustments for riskiness of small firms did not explain the large differences in rate of return • The impact of transactions costs of investing in small firms depends on frequency of trading – Daily trading reverses small firm gains • The small-firm effect is not stable from year to year
  • 38. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Neglected Firms – Firms divided by number of analysts following a stock – Small-firm effect was confirmed – Neglected firm effect caused by lack of information and limited institutional interest – Neglected firm concept applied across size classes – Another study contradicted the above results
  • 39. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-form EMH • Trading volume – Studied relationship between returns, market value, and trading activity. – Size effect was confirmed. But no significant difference was found between the mean returns of the highest and lowest trading activity portfolios
  • 40. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Ratio of Book Value of a firm’s Equity to Market Value of its equity – Significant positive relationship found between current values for this ratio and future stock returns – Results inconsistent with the EMH • Size and BV/MV dominate other ratios such as E/P ratio or leverage • This combination only works during expansive monetary policy
  • 41. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Firm size has emerged as a major predictor of future returns • This is an anomaly in the efficient markets literature • Attempts to explain the size anomaly in terms of superior risk measurements, transactions costs, analysts attention, trading activity, and differential information have not succeeded
  • 42. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Event studies – Stock split studies show that splits do not result in abnormal gains after the split announcement, but before – Initial public offerings seems to be underpriced by almost 18%, but that varies over time, and the price is adjusted within one day after the offering – Listing of a stock on an national exchange such as the NYSE may offer some short term profit opportunities for investors
  • 43. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Semistrong-Form EMH • Event studies (continued) – Stock prices quickly adjust to unexpected world events and economic news and hence do not provide opportunities for abnormal profits – Announcements of accounting changes are quickly adjusted for and do not seem to provide opportunities – Stock prices rapidly adjust to corporate events such as mergers and offerings – The above studies provide support for the semistrong-form EMH
  • 44. MGB Portfolio Management I Summary on the Semistrong-Form EMH • Evidence is mixed • Strong support from numerous event studies with the exception of exchange listing studies
  • 45. MGB Portfolio Management I Summary on the Semistrong-Form EMH • Studies on predicting rates of return for a cross-section of stocks indicates markets are not semistrong efficient
  • 46. MGB Portfolio Management I Summary on the Semistrong-Form EMH • Studies on predicting rates of return for a cross-section of stocks indicates markets are not semistrong efficient – Dividend yields, risk premiums, calendar patterns, and earnings surprises • This also included cross-sectional predictors such as size, the BV/MV ratio (when there is expansive monetary policy), E/P ratios, and neglected firms.
  • 47. MGB Portfolio Management I Tests and Results of Strong-Form EMH • Strong-form EMH contends that stock prices fully reflect all information, both public and private • This implies that no group of investors has access to private information that will allow them to consistently earn above-average profits
  • 48. MGB Portfolio Management I Testing Groups of Investors • Corporate insiders • Stock exchange specialists • Security analysts • Professional money managers
  • 49. MGB Portfolio Management I Corporate Insider Trading • Corporate insiders include major corporate officers, directors, and owners of 10% or more of any equity class of securities • Insiders must report to the SEC each month on their transactions in the stock of the firm for which they are insiders • These insider trades are made public about six weeks later and allowed to be studied
  • 50. MGB Portfolio Management I Corporate Insider Trading • Corporate insiders generally experience above-average profits especially on purchase transaction • This implies that many insiders had private information from which they derived above-average returns on their company stock
  • 51. MGB Portfolio Management I Corporate Insider Trading • Studies showed that public investors who traded with the insiders based on announced transactions would have enjoyed excess risk-adjusted returns (after commissions), but the markets now seem to have eliminated this inefficiency (soon after it was discovered)
  • 52. MGB Portfolio Management I Corporate Insider Trading • Other studies indicate that you can increase returns from using insider trading information by combining it with key financial ratios and considering what group of insiders is doing the buying and selling
  • 53. MGB Portfolio Management I Stock Exchange Specialists • Specialists have monopolistic access to information about unfilled limit orders • You would expect specialists to derive above-average returns from this information • The data generally supports this expectation
  • 54. MGB Portfolio Management I Security Analysts • Tests have considered whether it is possible to identify a set of analysts who have the ability to select undervalued stocks • This looks at whether, after a stock selection by an analyst is made known, a significant abnormal return is available to those who follow their recommendations
  • 55. MGB Portfolio Management I The Value Line Enigma • Value Line (VL) publishes financial information on about 1,700 stocks • The report includes a timing rank from 1 down to 5 • Firms ranked 1 substantially outperform the market • Firms ranked 5 substantially underperform the market
  • 56. MGB Portfolio Management I The Value Line Enigma • Changes in rankings result in a fast price adjustment • Some contend that the Value Line effect is merely the unexpected earnings anomaly due to changes in rankings from unexpected earnings
  • 57. MGB Portfolio Management I Security Analysts • There is evidence in favor of existence of superior analysts who apparently possess private information
  • 58. MGB Portfolio Management I Professional Money Managers • Trained professionals, working full time at investment management • If any investor can achieve above-average returns, it should be this group • If any non-insider can obtain inside information, it would be this group due to the extensive management interviews that they conduct
  • 59. MGB Portfolio Management I Performance of Professional Money Managers • Most tests examine mutual funds • New tests also examine trust departments, insurance companies, and investment advisors • Risk-adjusted, after expenses, returns of mutual funds generally show that most funds did not match aggregate market performance
  • 60. MGB Portfolio Management I Conclusions Regarding the Strong-Form EMH • Mixed results, but much support • Tests for corporate insiders and stock exchange specialists do not support the hypothesis (Both groups seem to have monopolistic access to important information and use it to derive above-average returns)
  • 61. MGB Portfolio Management I Conclusions Regarding the Strong-Form EMH • Tests results for analysts are concentrated on Value Line rankings – Results have changed over time – Currently tend to support EMH • Individual analyst recommendations seem to contain significant information • Performance of professional money managers seem to provide support for strong-form EMH
  • 62. MGB Portfolio Management I Behavioral Finance It is concerned with the analysis of various psychological traits of individuals and how these traits affect the manner in which they act as investors, analysts, and portfolio managers
  • 63. MGB Portfolio Management I Implications of Efficient Capital Markets • Overall results indicate the capital markets are efficient as related to numerous sets of information • There are substantial instances where the market fails to rapidly adjust to public information
  • 64. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Markets and Technical Analysis • Assumptions of technical analysis directly oppose the notion of efficient markets • Technicians believe that new information is not immediately available to everyone, but disseminated from the informed professional first to the aggressive investing public and then to the masses
  • 65. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Markets and Technical Analysis • Technicians also believe that investors do not analyze information and act immediately - it takes time • Therefore, stock prices move to a new equilibrium after the release of new information in a gradual manner, causing trends in stock price movements that persist for periods
  • 66. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Markets and Technical Analysis • Technical analysts develop systems to detect movement to a new equilibrium (breakout) and trade based on that • Contradicts rapid price adjustments indicated by the EMH • If the capital market is weak-form efficient, a trading system that depends on past trading data can have no value
  • 67. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Markets and Fundamental Analysis • Fundamental analysts believe that there is a basic intrinsic value for the aggregate stock market, various industries, or individual securities and these values depend on underlying economic factors • Investors should determine the intrinsic value of an investment at a point in time and compare it to the market price
  • 68. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Markets and Fundamental Analysis • If you can do a superior job of estimating intrinsic value you can make superior market timing decisions and generate above-average returns • This involves aggregate market analysis, industry analysis, company analysis, and portfolio management • Intrinsic value analysis should start with aggregate market analysis
  • 69. MGB Portfolio Management I Aggregate Market Analysis with Efficient Capital Markets • EMH implies that examining only past economic events is not likely to lead to outperforming a buy-and-hold policy because the market adjusts rapidly to known economic events • Merely using historical data to estimate future values is not sufficient • You must estimate the relevant variables that cause long-run movements
  • 70. MGB Portfolio Management I Industry and Company Analysis with Efficient Capital Markets • Wide distribution of returns from different industries and companies justifies industry and company analysis • Must understand the variables that effect rates of return and • Do a superior job of estimating future values of these relevant valuation variables, not just look at past data
  • 71. MGB Portfolio Management I Industry and Company Analysis with Efficient Capital Markets • Important relationship between expected earnings and actual earnings • Accurately predicting earnings surprises • Strong-form EMH indicates likely existence of superior analysts • Studies indicate that fundamental analysis based on E/P ratios, size, and the BV/MV ratios can lead to differentiating future return patterns
  • 72. MGB Portfolio Management I How to Evaluate Analysts or Investors • Examine the performance of numerous securities that this analyst recommends over time in relation to a set of randomly selected stocks in the same risk class • Selected stocks should consistently outperform the randomly selected stocks
  • 73. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Markets and Portfolio Management • Portfolio Managers with Superior Analysts – concentrate efforts in mid-cap stocks that do not receive the attention given by institutional portfolio managers to the top-tier stocks – the market for these neglected stocks may be less efficient than the market for large well-known stocks
  • 74. MGB Portfolio Management I Efficient Markets and Portfolio Management • Portfolio Managers without Superior Analysts – Determine and quantify your client's risk preferences – Construct the appropriate portfolio – Diversify completely on a global basis to eliminate all unsystematic risk – Maintain the desired risk level by rebalancing the portfolio whenever necessary – Minimize total transaction costs
  • 75. MGB Portfolio Management I The Rationale and Use of Index Funds • Efficient capital markets and a lack of superior analysts imply that many portfolios should be managed passively (so their performance matches the aggregate market, minimizes the costs of research and trading) • Institutions created market (index) funds which duplicate the composition and performance of a selected index series
  • 76. MGB Portfolio Management I Insights from Behavioral Finance • Growth companies will usually not be growth stocks due to the overconfidence of analysts regarding future growth rates and valuations • Notion of “herd mentality” of analysts in stock recommendations or quarterly earnings estimates is confirmed
  • 77. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence on Efficient Market Hypothesis  Favorable Evidence 1. Investment analysts and mutual funds don't beat the market 2. Stock prices reflect publicly available info: anticipated announcements don't affect stock price 3. Stock prices and exchange rates close to random walk; if predictions of DP big, Rof > R*  predictions of DP small 4. Technical analysis does not outperform market
  • 78. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency • Performance of Investment Analysts and Mutual Funds should not be able to consistently beat the market – The “Investment Dartboard” often beats investment managers. – Mutual funds not only do not outperform the market on average, but when they are separated into groups according to whether they had the highest or lowest profits in a chosen period, the mutual funds that did well in the first period do not beat the market in the second period. – Investment strategies using inside information is the only “proven method” to beat the market. In the U.S., it is illegal to trade on such information, but that is not true in all countries.
  • 79. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency  Do Stock Prices Reflect Publicly Available Information as the EMH predicts they will? ─ Thus if information is already publicly available, a positive announcement about a company will not, on average, raise the price of its stock because this information is already reflected in the stock price. ─ Early empirical evidence confirms: favorable earnings announcements or announcements of stock splits (a division of a share of stock into multiple shares, which is usually followed by higher earnings) do not, on average, cause stock prices to rise.
  • 80. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency  Random-Walk Behavior of Stock Prices that is, future changes in stock prices should, for all practical purposes, be unpredictable ─ If stock is predicted to rise, people will buy to equilibrium level; if stock is predicted to fall, people will sell to equilibrium level (both in concert with EMH) ─ Thus, if stock prices were predictable, thereby causing the above behavior, price changes would be near zero, which has not been the case historically
  • 81. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency  Technical Analysis means to study past stock price data and search for patterns such as trends and regular cycles, suggesting rules for when to buy and sell stocks ─ The EMH suggests that technical analysis is a waste of time ─ The simplest way to understand why is to use the random-walk result that holds that past stock price data cannot help predict changes ─ Therefore, technical analysis, which relies on such data to produce its forecasts, cannot successfully predict changes in stock prices
  • 82. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency • 2: Empirical Evidence for TA is Negligible • Much of the faith in TA hinges on anecdotal experience, not any kind of long-term statistical evidence, unlike value investing or other quantitative/fundamental methodologies we discuss on this site. Most of the statistical work done by academics to determine whether the chart patterns are actually predictive has been inconclusive at best. Indeed, a recent study by finance professors at Massey University in New Zealand examined 49 developed and emerging markets to see if TA added value. They looked at more than 5,000 technical trading rules across four rule families : • Filter Rules - These rules involve opening long (short) positions after price increases (decreases) by x% and closing these positions when price decreases (increases) by x% from a subsequent high (low). • Moving Average Rules - These rules generate buy (sell) signals when the price or a short moving average moves above (below) a long moving average. • Channel Break-outs - These rules involve opening long (short) positions when the closing price moves above (below) a channel. A channel (sometimes referred to as a trading range) can be said to occur when the high over the previous n days is within x percent of the low over the previous n days, not including the current price. • Support and Resistance Rules - These “Trading Range Break” rules involve opening a long (short) position when the closing price breaches the maximum (minimum) price over the previous n periods. • The result? Using statistical methods to adjust for data snooping bias, the authors concluded that there wasno evidence that the profits [attributed] to the technical trading rules considered were greater than those that might be expected due to random data variation.
  • 83. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence in Favor of Market Efficiency But wait – it’s not all bad…. • As you can tell, trading purely on the basis of TA is a mug’s game. However, despite inconsistencies in predictive value, • 1. TA may be a useful tool as part of a broader strategy for managing holdings (e.g. to help you time any investments that are decided on other, hopefully fundamentally-focused, criteria).The fact is that many (misguided) market participants use TA to drive their investment decisions. These collective actions result in tangible changes in asset values, so they need to be understood even by less mis-guided investors. A fundamental investor need not agree that a stock should be moving but it’s worth understand why a stock is nevertheless moving. As Birinyi, a research and money-management firm, noted in a research note: • 2. “technical approaches can and should be a useful adjunct to every investor’s — amateur and professional — arsenal, if and only if used properly and with understanding… Technicals detail and hopefully illuminate, but do not predict.” • 3. TA may be particularly useful on the sell-side where it is deemed (according to William O’Neill) prudent to sell based on “unusual market action such as price and volume movement”… • 4. Good investing is about managing your losses too, and here TA can be a useful tool to determine where best to place a stop-loss (given the number of TA practitioners out there that are likely to be anchoring around certain price points).
  • 84. MGB Portfolio Management I Case: Foreign Exchange Rates • Could you make a bundle if you could predict FX rates? Of course. • EMH predicts, then, that FX rates should be unpredictable. • That is exactly what empirical tests show—FX rates are not very predictable.
  • 85. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence on Efficient Market Hypothesis  Unfavorable Evidence 1. Small-firm effect: small firms have abnormally high returns 2. January effect: high returns in January 3. Market overreaction 4. Excessive volatility 5. Mean reversion 6. New information is not always immediately incorporated into stock prices  Overview ─ Reasonable starting point but not whole story
  • 86. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence Against Market Efficiency • The Small-Firm Effect is an anomaly. Many empirical studies have shown that small firms have earned abnormally high returns over long periods of time, even when the greater risk for these firms has been considered. – The small-firm effect seems to have diminished in recent years but is still a challenge to the theory of efficient markets – Various theories have been developed to explain the small-firm effect, suggesting that it may be due to rebalancing of portfolios by institutional investors, tax issues, low liquidity of small-firm stocks, large information costs in evaluating small firms, or an inappropriate measurement of risk for small-firm stocks
  • 87. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence Against Market Efficiency  The January Effect is the tendency of stock prices to experience an abnormal positive return in the month of January that is predictable and, hence, inconsistent with random-walk behavior – Investors have an incentive to sell stocks before the end of the year in December because they can then take capital losses on their tax return and reduce their tax liability. Then when the new year starts in January, they can repurchase the stocks, driving up their prices and producing abnormally high returns. – Although this explanation seems sensible, it does not explain why institutional investors such as private pension funds, which are not subject to income taxes, do not take advantage of the abnormal returns in January and buy stocks in December, thus bidding up their price and eliminating the abnormal returns.
  • 88. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence Against Market Efficiency  Market Overreaction: recent research suggests that stock prices may overreact to news announcements and that the pricing errors are corrected only slowly ─ When corporations announce a major change in earnings, say, a large decline, the stock price may overshoot, and after an initial large decline, it may rise back to more normal levels over a period of several weeks. ─ This violates the EMH because an investor could earn abnormally high returns, on average, by buying a stock immediately after a poor earnings announcement and then selling it after a couple of weeks when it has risen back to normal levels.
  • 89. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence Against Market Efficiency  Excessive Volatility: the stock market appears to display excessive volatility; that is, fluctuations in stock prices may be much greater than is warranted by fluctuations in their fundamental value. ─ Researchers have found that fluctuations in the S&P 500 stock index could not be justified by the subsequent fluctuations in the dividends of the stocks making up this index. ─ Other research finds that there are smaller fluctuations in stock prices when stock markets are closed, which has produced a consensus that stock market prices appear to be driven by factors other than fundamentals.
  • 90. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence Against Market Efficiency  Mean Reversion: Some researchers have found that stocks with low returns today tend to have high returns in the future, and vice versa. ─ Hence stocks that have done poorly in the past are more likely to do well in the future because mean reversion indicates that there will be a predictable positive change in the future price, suggesting that stock prices are not a random walk. ─ Newer data is less conclusive; nevertheless, mean reversion remains controversial.
  • 91. MGB Portfolio Management I Evidence Against Market Efficiency  New Information Is Not Always Immediately Incorporated into Stock Prices ─ Although generally true, recent evidence suggests that, inconsistent with the efficient market hypothesis, stock prices do not instantaneously adjust to profit announcements. ─ Instead, on average stock prices continue to rise for some time after the announcement of unexpectedly high profits, and they continue to fall after surprisingly low profit announcements.
  • 92. MGB Portfolio Management I Implications for Investing 1. How valuable are published reports by investment advisors? 2. Should you be skeptical of hot tips? 3. Do stock prices always rise when there is good news? 4. Efficient Markets prescription for investor
  • 93. MGB Portfolio Management I Implications for Investing  How valuable are published reports by investment advisors?
  • 94. MGB Portfolio Management I Implications for Investing 1. Should you be skeptical of hot tips? ─ YES. The EMH indicates that you should be skeptical of hot tips since, if the stock market is efficient, it has already priced the hot tip stock so that its expected return will equal the equilibrium return. ─ Thus, the hot tip is not particularly valuable and will not enable you to earn an abnormally high return. – As soon as the information hits the street, the unexploited profit opportunity it creates will be quickly eliminated. – The stock’s price will already reflect the information, and you should expect to realize only the equilibrium return.
  • 95. MGB Portfolio Management I Implications for Investing 3. Do stock prices always rise when there is good news? – NO. In an efficient market, stock prices will respond to announcements only when the information being announced is new and unexpected. – So, if good news was expected (or as good as expected), there will be no stock price response. – And, if good news was unexpected (or not as good as expected), there will be a stock price response.
  • 96. MGB Portfolio Management I Implications for Investing  Efficient Markets prescription for investor ─ Investors should not try to outguess the market by constantly buying and selling securities. This process does nothing but incur commissions costs on each trade. ─ Instead, the investor should pursue a “buy and hold” strategy— purchase stocks and hold them for long periods of time. This will lead to the same returns, on average, but the investor’s net profits will be higher because fewer brokerage commissions will have to be paid. ─ It is frequently a sensible strategy for a small investor, whose costs of managing a portfolio may be high relative to its size, to buy into a mutual fund rather than individual stocks. Because the EMH indicates that no mutual fund can consistently outperform the market, an investor should not buy into one that has high management fees or that pays sales commissions to brokers but rather should purchase a no-load (commission-free) mutual fund that has low management fees.
  • 97. MGB Portfolio Management I All mutual funds sold to the public – performance of all general equity mutual funds compared to the Wilshire 5000 Index. In most years more than ½ of the funds were outperformed by the index. Over the 26.5 year period about 2/3 of the funds proved inferior to the market as a whole. Same result holds for professional pension managers. Implications for Investing Cost Compare Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 6-97
  • 98. MGB Portfolio Management I Case: Any Efficient Markets Lessons from Black Monday of 1987 and the Tech Crash of 2000?  Does any version of Efficient Markets Hypothesis (EMH) hold in light of sudden or dramatic market declines?  Strong version EMH?  Weaker version EMH?  A bubble is a situation in which the price of an asset differs from its fundamental market value?  Can bubbles be rational?  Role of behavioral finance
  • 99. MGB Portfolio Management I Behavioral Finance BF argues that a few psychological phenomena pervade financial markets: 1. Practitioners rely on rules of thumb called heuristics to process information. – Heuristic—a process by which people find things out for themselves, usually by trial and error. Leads to the development of rules of thumb which are imperfect and result in errors which lead to heuristic-driven bias. 2. In addition to objective considerations, practitioners perception of risk & return are highly influenced by how decision problems are framed  frame dependence. 3. Heuristic-driven bias and framing effects cause market prices to deviate from fundamental values, i.e. markets are inefficient.
  • 100. MGB Portfolio Management I Heuristic Driven Bias • Representativeness—reliance on stereotypes – Example of High School GPA as predictor of College GPA and reversion to the mean. • Overconfidence – People set overly narrow confidence bands, high guess is too low and low guess is too high. – Results in being surprised too often. • Anchoring to old information – Security analysts do not revise their earnings estimates enough to reflect new info.
  • 101. MGB Portfolio Management I Frame Dependence • EMH assumes framing is transparent—If you move a $ from your right pocket to your left pocket, you are no wealthier! (Merton Miller) … In other words, practitioners can see through all the different ways that cash flow might be described. • But if frame is opaque, a difference in form (which pocket) is also a difference in substance and affects behavior. • Loss Aversion – Choose between • Sure loss of $7,500 or • 75% chance of loosing $10K or 25% chance of loosing $0. • Hedonic editing – Organizing Gains and Losses in separate mental accounts. • One loss and one gain are netted against each other. • Two gains are savored separately • But multiple losses are difficult to net out against moderate gains.
  • 102. MGB Portfolio Management I Frame Dependence • Hedonic editing 1. Imagine that you face the following choice. You can accept a guaranteed $1500 or play a lottery. The outcome of the lottery is determined by the toss of a fair coin. Heads—> you win $1950 Tails—> you win $1050 Which would you chose? Are you risk averse?
  • 103. MGB Portfolio Management I Frame Dependence • Hedonic editing 2. Imagine that you face the following choice. You can accept a guaranteed loss of $750 or play a lottery. The outcome of the lottery is determined by the toss of a fair coin. Heads—> you lose $750 Tails—> you lose $525 Which would you chose?
  • 104. MGB Portfolio Management I Frame Dependence • Hedonic editing 3. Now imagine that you have just won $1500 in one lottery, and you can choose to participate in another. The outcome of this second lottery is determined by the toss of a fair coin. Heads—> you win $450 Tails—> you win $450 Would you choose to participate in the second lottery?
  • 105. MGB Portfolio Management I Frame Dependence • Hedonic editing has both cognitive and emotional causes – Main cognitive issue in choice 3 above—Do you ignore the preliminary $1500 winnings or not? – Those that begin by seeing themselves $1500 ahead then experience the emotion of loosing $450 as the equivalent of winning $1050 (i.e. a smaller gain, not a loss). – Those that ignore the $1500 are less prone to accept the gamble because they will feel a $450 loss as a loss.
  • 106. MGB Portfolio Management I Assignment Q1: If the weak form of the efficient market is valid must the strong form also hold? Conversely, does strong-form efficiency imply weak-form efficiency? Q2: What would happen to market efficiency if every investor followed a passive strategy? Q3. A portfolio manager outperforms the market in 11 of 14 years. Does this violate the concept of market efficiency? Q4. A segment of the market believes that continued economic worries brought about the stock market crash of 1987. Is this explanation for the crash consistent with the Efficient Market Hypothesis?
  • 107. MGB Portfolio Management I PORTFOLIO THEORY
  • 109. MGB Portfolio Management I cov(X,Y)=E(XY)−E(X)E(Y). Proof: Let μ=E(X) and ν=E(Y). Then cov(X,Y)=E[(X−μ)(Y−ν)]=E(XY−μY−νX+μν)=E(XY)−μE(Y)−νE(X)+μν=E(XY)−μν
  • 110. MGB Portfolio Management I The "Population Standard Deviation": The "Sample Standard Deviation":
  • 111. MGB Portfolio Management I In probability theory and statistics, the mathematical concepts of covariance and correlation are very similar. Both describe the degree to which two random variables or sets of random variables tend to deviate from their expected values in similar ways. correlation covariance where E is the expected value operator and σx and σy are the standard deviations of X and Y, respectively. Notably, correlation is dimensionless while covariance is in units obtained by multiplying the units of the two variables. The covariance of a variable with itself (i.e. σxx ) is called the variance and is more commonly denoted as σ2 x the square of the standard deviation. The correlation of a variable with itself is always 1
  • 112. MGB Portfolio Management I Last year, five randomly selected students took a math aptitude test before they began their statistics course. The Statistics Department has three questions. What linear regression equation best predicts statistics performance, based on math aptitude scores? If a student made an 80 on the aptitude test, what grade would we expect her to make in statistics? How well does the regression equation fit the data? How to Find the Regression Equation In the table below, the xi column shows scores on the aptitude test. Similarly, the yi column shows statistics grades. The last two rows show sums and mean scores that we will use to conduct the regression analysis. Student xi yi (xi - x) (yi - y) (xi - x)2 (yi - y)2 (xi - x)(yi - y) 1 95 85 17 8 289 64 136 2 85 95 7 18 49 324 126 3 80 70 2 -7 4 49 -14 4 70 65 -8 -12 64 144 96 5 60 70 -18 -7 324 49 126 Sum 390 385 730 630 470 Mean 78 77 The regression equation is a linear equation of the form: ŷ = b0 + b1x . To conduct a regression analysis, we need to solve for b0 and b1. Computations are shown below. b1 = Σ [ (xi - x)(yi - y) ] / Σ [ (xi - x)2] b1 = 470/730 = 0.644 Therefore, the regression equation is: ŷ = 26.768 + 0.644x . b0 = y - b1 * x b0 = 77 - (0.644)(78) = 26.768
  • 113. MGB Portfolio Management I The Coefficient of Determination Whenever you use a regression equation, you should ask how well the equation fits the data. One way to assess fit is to check the coefficient of determination, which can be computed from the following formula. R2 = { ( 1 / N ) * Σ [ (xi - x) * (yi - y) ] / (σx * σy ) }2 where N is the number of observations used to fit the model, Σ is the summation symbol, xi is the x value for observation i, x is the mean x value, yi is the y value for observation i, y is the mean y value, σx is the standard deviation of x, and σy is the standard deviation of y. Computations for the sample problem of this lesson are shown below. σx = sqrt [ Σ ( xi - x )2 / N ] σx = sqrt( 730/5 ) = sqrt(146) = 12.083 σy = sqrt [ Σ ( yi - y )2 / N ] σy = sqrt( 630/5 ) = sqrt(126) = 11.225 R2 = { ( 1 / N ) * Σ [ (xi - x) * (yi - y) ] / (σx * σy ) }2 R2 = [ ( 1/5 ) * 470 / ( 12.083 * 11.225 ) ]2 = ( 94 / 135.632 )2 = ( 0.693 )2 = 0.48 A coefficient of determination equal to 0.48 indicates that about 48% of the variation in statistics grades (the dependent variable) can be explained by the relationship to math aptitude scores (the independent variable). This would be considered a good fit to the data, in the sense that it would substantially improve an educator's ability to predict student performance in statistics class.
  • 114. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Mathematics 114 • Of course, in practice, assets are not correlated in this simplistic way. Let us look at how portfolio risk is affected when we put two arbitrarily correlated assets in a portfolio. Let us call the two assets, a bond, D, and a stock (equity), E. • Then, we can write out the following relationship: r r w r w r p D D E E Portfolio Return Bond Weight Bond Return Equity Weight Equity Return P D D E E  w r w r      ( ) ( ) ( ) p D D E E E r  w E r  w E r
  • 115. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Mathematics 115 The expected return on a portfolio consisting of several assets is simply a weighted average of the expected returns on the assets comprising the portfolio.
  • 116. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Mathematics 116 • If we denote variance by s2, then we have the relationship: D D E E D E  D E  w w 2w w Cov r ,r 2 2 2 2 2 p s  s  s   where Cov(rD, rE) represents the covariance between the returns on assets D and E.  If we use DE to represent the correlation coefficient between the returns on the two assets, then  Cov(rD,rE) = DEsDsE  The formula for portfolio variance can be written either with covariance or with correlation.
  • 117. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Mathematics • The correlation coefficient can take values between +1 and -1. • If DE = +1, there is no diversification and the portfolio standard deviation equals wDsD + wEsE, i.e. a linear combination of the standard deviations of the two assets. • If DE= -1, the portfolio variance equals (wDsD – wEsE)2. In this case, we can construct a risk-free combination of D and E. • Setting this equal to zero and solving for wD and wE, we find 117 s E w   w D D  1 s  s D E
  • 118. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Mathematics 118 For intermediate values of r, the portfolio standard deviations fall in the middle, as shown on the graph to the right. In this example, the stock asset has a standard deviation of returns of 20% and the bond asset, of 12%.
  • 119. MGB Portfolio Management I Problem Seventy-five percent of a portfolio is invested in Honeybell stock and the remaining 25% is invested in MBIB stock. Honeybell stock has an expected return of 6% and an expected standard deviation of returns of 9%. MBIB stock has an expected return of 20% and an expected standard deviation of 30%. The coefficient of correlation between returns of the two securities is expected to be 0.4. Determine the following: (a) the expected return of the portfolio; (b) the expected variance of the portfolio; (c) the expected standard deviation for the portfolio.
  • 120. MGB Portfolio Management I Measuring Mean: Scenario or Subjective Returns Subjective returns s   E(r)  p  r i i i 1 ‘s’ = number of scenarios considered pi = probability that scenario ‘i’ will occur ri = return if scenario ‘i’ occurs
  • 121. MGB Portfolio Management I Numerical example: Scenario Distributions Scenario Probability Return 1 0.1 -5% 2 0.2 5% 3 0.4 15% 4 0.2 25% 5 0.1 35% E(r) = (.1)(-.05)+(.2)(.05)...+(.1)(.35) E(r) = .15 = 15%
  • 122. MGB Portfolio Management I Measuring Variance or Dispersion of Returns Subjective or Scenario Distributions s 2 Variance  s 2  p(i)  [r(i)  E(r)] i 1  Standard deviation = [variance]1/2 = s Using Our Example: s 2=[(.1)(-.05-.15)2+(.2)(.05- .15)2+…] =.01199 s = [ .01199]1/2 = .1095 = 10.95%
  • 123. MGB Portfolio Management I W = 100 W1 = 150; Profit = 50 W2 1-p = .4 = 80; Profit = -20 E(W) = pW1 + (1-p)W2 = 122 2 = p[W1 - E(W)]2 + (1-p) [W2 - E(W)]2 s 2 = 1,176 and s = 34.29% s Risk - Uncertain Outcomes
  • 124. MGB Portfolio Management I Risky Investments with Risk-Free Investment W1 = 150 Profit = 50 1-p = .4 W2 = 80 Profit = -20 100 Risky Investment Risk Free T-bills Profit = 5 Risk Premium = 22-5 = 17
  • 125. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk Aversion & Utility • Investor’s view of risk – Risk Averse – Risk Neutral – Risk Seeking • Utility • Utility Function U = E ( r ) – .005 A s 2 • A measures the degree of risk aversion
  • 126. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk Aversion and Value: The Sample Investment U = E ( r ) - .005 A s 2 = 22% - .005 A (34%) 2 Risk Aversion A Utility High 5 -6.90 3 4.66 Low 1 16.22 T-bill = 5%
  • 127. MGB Portfolio Management I Dominance Principle 2 3 1 4 Expected Return Variance or Standard Deviation • 2 dominates 1; has a higher return • 2 dominates 3; has a lower risk • 4 dominates 3; has a higher
  • 128. MGB Portfolio Management I Utility and Indifference Curves • Represent an investor’s willingness to trade-off return and risk Example (for an investor with A=4): Exp Return (%) St Deviation (%) 10 20.0 15 25.5 20 30.0 25 33.9 U=E(r)-.005As2 2 2 2 2
  • 129. MGB Portfolio Management I Indifference Curves Expected Return Increasing Utility Standard Deviation
  • 130. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Mathematics: Assets’ Expected Return Rule 1 : The return for an asset is the probability weighted average return in all scenarios. s   E(r)  p  r i i i 1
  • 131. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Mathematics: Assets’ Variance of Return Rule 2: The variance of an asset’s return is the expected value of the squared deviations from the expected return. s 2 2 p [r E(r)] s    i 1 i i 
  • 132. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Mathematics: Return on a Portfolio Rule 3: The rate of return on a portfolio is a weighted average of the rates of return of each asset comprising the portfolio, with the portfolio proportions as weights. rp = w1r1 + w2r2
  • 133. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Mathematics: Risk with Risk-Free Asset Rule 4: When a risky asset is combined with a risk-free asset, the portfolio standard deviation equals the risky asset’s standard deviation multiplied by the portfolio proportion invested in the risky asset. s  s p risky asset riskyasset w
  • 134. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Mathematics: Risk with two Risky Assets Rule 5: When two risky assets with variances 2 and s2 s1 2 respectively, are combined into a portfolio with portfolio weights w1 and w2, respectively, the portfolio variance is given by: sp 2  2 s 2  2 s 2 1 1 2 2  w w 2w1w2Cov(r1,r2)
  • 135. MGB Portfolio Management I Asset Mix Decision Asset mix decisions consider both investment opportunities and investor preferences. These are best described within a risk-reward framework. Investment Opportunities The goal of assessing investment opportunities can be expressed in terms of: • Expected investment returns and • Potential deviations from these expectations Asset returns are typically viewed in a probabilistic sense as: 푛 E(R) = 푖=0 푃푖*ri n= number of possible outcomes Pi is the probability that outcome I will occur ri= Realized returns if outcome I occurs
  • 136. MGB Portfolio Management I Asset Mix Decision The expected return on portfolio is written as E(Rm) = 푘 푖=0 푥푖*E(Ri) k= number of assets in the portfolio xi is the proportion of the portfolio invested in asset i E(Ri)= Realized returns if outcome i occurs The variability of the returns about the expectations is measured by the standard deviation of the returns: The right hand side of the equation is collectively known as the capital market conditions. The resulting risk return characteristics of each mix can be plotted on a return-standard deviation graph to get a chart of all the portfolios that are constructed.
  • 137. MGB Portfolio Management I Asset Mix Decision The Efficient Frontier It's clear that for any given value of standard deviation, you would like to choose a portfolio that gives you the greatest possible rate of return; so you always want a portfolio that lies up along the efficient frontier, rather than lower down, in the interior of the region. This is the first important property of the efficient frontier: it's where the best portfolios are. The second important property of the efficient frontier is that it's curved, not straight. This is actually significant -- in fact, it's the key to how diversification lets you improve your reward-to-risk ratio. To see why, imagine a 50/50 allocation between just two securities. Assuming that the year-to-year performance of these two securities is not perfectly in sync -- that is, assuming that the great years and the lousy years for Security 1 don't correspond perfectly to the great years and lousy years for Security 2, but that their cycles are at least a little off -- then the standard deviation of the 50/50 allocation will be less than the average of the standard deviations of the two securities separately. Graphically, this stretches the possible allocations to the left of the straight line joining the two securities. In statistical terms, this effect is due to lack of covariance. The smaller the covariance between the two securities -- the more out of sync they are -- the smaller the standard deviation of a portfolio that combines them. The ultimate would be to find two securities with negative covariance.
  • 138. MGB Portfolio Management I Asset Mix Decision Investor Preferences Investor preference is quantified in terms of utility derived from owning a security. They • Like Return • Dislike Risk 2 = Return – “Risk Penalty” tk • Umk = E(Rm) – σm Umk = Expected utility of asset mix m derived by investor k tk = Investor k’s risk tolerance
  • 139. MGB Portfolio Management I Asset Mix Decision Utility Curves • An investor is indifferent between any two portfolios that lie on the same indifference curve. • Investors want to be on the highest indifference curve that is available given current capital market conditions. • Indifference curves do not intersect. • Flatter indifference curves indicate that the investor has higher tolerance for risk • Certainty equivalent rate of return is given by the y intercept and is greater than the risk free rate of return.
  • 140. MGB Portfolio Management I Utility Functions • Utility is a measure of well-being. • A utility function shows the relationship between utility and return (or wealth) when the returns are risk-free. • Risk-Neutral Utility Functions: Investors are indifferent to risk. They only analyze return when making investment decisions. • Risk-Loving Utility Functions: For any given rate of return, investors prefer more risk. • Risk-Averse Utility Functions: For any given rate of return, investors prefer less risk.
  • 141. MGB Portfolio Management I Utility Functions (Continued) • To illustrate the different types of utility functions, we will analyze the following risky investment for three different investors: Possible Return (%) (ri) _________ 10% 50% Probability (pi) _________ .5 .5    E(r ) .5(10%) .5(50%) 30% 2 2 i σ(r ) .5(10% 30%) .5(50% 30%) 20% i     
  • 142. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk-Neutral Investor • Assume the following linear utility function: ui = 10ri Return (%) (ri) __________ 0 10 20 30 40 50 Total Utility (ui) __________ 0 100 200 300 400 500 Constant Marginal Utility __________ 100 100 100 100 100
  • 143. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk-Neutral Investor (Continued) • Expected Utility of the Risky Investment:   E(u) .5*u(10%) .5*u(50%)    E(u) .5(100) .5(500) 300 • Note: The expected utility of the risky investment with an expected return of 30% (300) is equal to the utility associated with receiving 30% risk-free (300).
  • 144. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk-Neutral Utility Function ui = 10ri Total Utility 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Percent Return
  • 145. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk-Loving Investor • Assume the following quadratic utility function: ui = 0 + 5ri + .1ri 2 Return (%) (ri) __________ 0 10 20 30 40 50 Total Utility (ui) __________ 0 60 140 240 360 500 Increasing Marginal Utility __________ 60 80 100 120 140
  • 146. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk-Loving Investor (Continued) • Expected Utility of the Risky Investment:   E(u) .5*u(10%) .5*u(50%)    E(u) .5(60) .5(500) 280 • Note: The expected utility of the risky investment with an expected return of 30% (280) is greater than the utility associated with receiving 30% risk-free (240). 33.5% - 5 + 25- 4(.1)(-280) Certainty Equivalent :  2(.1) • That is, the investor would be indifferent between receiving 33.5% risk-free and investing in a risky asset that has E(r) = 30% and s(r) = 20%
  • 147. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk-Loving Utility Function 2 ui = 0 + 5ri + .1ri Total Utility 600 0 0 60 Percent Return 500 280 240 60 10 30 33.5 50
  • 148. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk-Averse Investor • Assume the following quadratic utility function: ui = 0 + 20ri - .2ri 2 Return (%) (ri) __________ 0 10 20 30 40 50 Total Utility (ui) __________ 0 180 320 420 480 500 Diminishing Marginal Utility __________ 180 140 100 60 20
  • 149. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk-Averse Investor (Continued) • Expected Utility of the Risky Investment:   E(u) .5*u(10%) .5*u(50%)    E(u) .5(180) .5(500) 340 • Note: The expected utility of the risky investment with an expected return of 30% (340) is less than the utility associated with receiving 30% risk-free (420). - 20+ 400- 4(-.2)(-340) Certainty Equivalent :   2( .2) • That is, the investor would be indifferent between 21.7% receiving 21.7% risk-free and investing in a risky asset that has E(r) = 30% and s(r) = 20%.
  • 150. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk-Averse Utility Function 2 ui = 0 + 20ri - .2ri Total Utility 600 0 0 60 Percent Return 500 420 340 180 10 21.7 30 50
  • 151. MGB Portfolio Management I Indifference Curve • Given the total utility function, an indifference curve can be generated for any given level of utility. First, for quadratic utility functions, the following equation for expected utility is derived in the text:     E(u) a a E(r) a E(r) a σ (r) 2 a E(r) 2 1 0 2 Solving for σ(r) : E(u) 2 2 2 2 0 1 2 E(r) a a a a σ(r) =   
  • 152. MGB Portfolio Management I Indifference Curve (Continued) • Using the previous utility function for the risk-averse investor, (ui = 0 + 20ri - .2ri 2), and a given level of utility of 180: 2 E(r) 20E(r) σ(r)  .2 180 .2     • Therefore, the indifference curve would be: E(r) 10 20 30 40 50 s(r) 0 26.5 34.6 38.7 40.0
  • 153. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk-Averse Indifference Curve 2 When E(u) = 180, and ui = 0 + 20ri - .2ri Expected Return 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 Standard Deviation of Returns
  • 154. MGB Portfolio Management I Maximizing Utility • Given the efficient set of investment possibilities and a “mass” of indifference curves, an investor would maximize his/her utility by finding the point of tangency between an indifference curve and the efficient set. Expected Return 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 E(u) = 380 E(u) = 280 Portfolio That Maximizes Utility E(u) = 180 0 10 20 30 40 50 Standard Deviation of Returns
  • 155. MGB Portfolio Management I Problems With Quadratic Utility Functions Quadratic utility functions turn down after they reach a certain level of return (or wealth). This aspect is obviously unrealistic: Total Utility 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 Unrealistic 0 20 40 60 80 Percent Return
  • 156. MGB Portfolio Management I Problems With Quadratic Utility Functions (Continued) • With a quadratic utility function, as your wealth level increases, your willingness to take on risk decreases (i.e., both absolute risk aversion [dollars you are willing to commit to risky investments] and relative risk aversion [% of wealth you are willing to commit to risky investments] increase with wealth levels). In general, however, rich people are more willing to take on risk than poor people. Therefore, other mathematical functions (e.g., logarithmic) may be more appropriate.
  • 157. MGB Portfolio Management I What do you think about the move to a more active stock-picking strategy? stock standard deviation return Index fund 4.61% 1.10% California R.E.I.T. 9.23% -2.27% Brown Group 8.17% -0.67% Portfolio of 99% index 4.57% 1.07% fund and 1 % California R.E.I.T. Portfolio of 99% index fund and 1 % Brown Group 4.61% 1.08% Thus we see that the index fund has the highest return of 1.10% with the standard deviation of 4.61% By including California REIT the standard deviation (risk) is reduced to 4.57% but the return also reduces to 1.07% Thus there can be a tradeoff between these two strategies However including Brown Group is not a good idea as return drops but the risk (standard deviation remains the same)
  • 158. MGB Portfolio Management I Asset Mix Decision Optimal Portfolio - Where the Efficient frontier and Utility curve meet
  • 159. MGB Portfolio Management I Estimating Risk Aversion • Use questionnaires • Observe individuals’ decisions when confronted with risk • Observe how much people are willing to pay to avoid risk
  • 160. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk Aversion and Capital Allocation to Risky Assets
  • 161. MGB Portfolio Management I The Investment Decision • Top-down process with 3 steps: 1. Capital allocation between the risky portfolio and risk-free asset 2. Asset allocation across broad asset classes 3. Security selection of individual assets within each asset class
  • 162. MGB Portfolio Management I Allocation to Risky Assets • Investors will avoid risk unless there is a reward. – i.e. Risk Premium should be positive • Agents preference (taste) gives the optimal allocation between a risky portfolio and a risk-free asset.
  • 163. MGB Portfolio Management I Speculation vs. Gamble • Speculation – Taking considerable risk for a commensurate gain – Parties have heterogeneous expectations • Gamble – Bet or wager on an uncertain outcome for enjoyment – Parties assign the same probabilities to the possible outcomes
  • 164. MGB Portfolio Management I Available Risky Portfolios (Risk-free Rate = 5%) Each portfolio receives a utility score to assess the investor’s risk/return trade off
  • 165. MGB Portfolio Management I Utility Function U = utility of portfolio with return r E ( r ) = expected return portfolio A = coefficient of risk aversion s2 = variance of returns of portfolio ½ = a scaling factor 2 1 U  E ( r )  As 2
  • 166. MGB Portfolio Management I Utility Scores of Alternative Portfolios for Investors with Varying Degree of Risk Aversion IN CLASS EXERCISE. Answer: How high does the risk aversion coefficient (A) has to be so that L is preferred over M and H?
  • 167. MGB Portfolio Management I Mean-Variance (M-V) Criterion • Portfolio A dominates portfolio B if: • And  A   B  E r  E r A B s s • As noted before: this does not determine the choice of one portfolio, but a whole set of efficient portfolios.
  • 168. MGB Portfolio Management I Capital Allocation Across Risky and Risk-Free Portfolios Asset Allocation: • Is a very important part of portfolio construction. • Refers to the choice among broad asset classes. – % of total Investment in risky vs. risk-free assets Controlling Risk: • Simplest way: Manipulate the fraction of the portfolio invested in risk-free assets versus the portion invested in the risky assets
  • 169. MGB Portfolio Management I Basic Asset Allocation Example Total Amount Invested $300,000 Risk-free money market $90,000 fund Total risk assets $210,000 Equities $113,400 Bonds (long-term) $96,600 $113,400 W   0.54 0.46 E $210,000 $96,600   B W $210,00 Proportion of Risk assets on Equities Proportion of Risk assets on Bonds
  • 170. MGB Portfolio Management I Basic Asset Allocation • P is the complete portfolio where we have y as the weight on the risky portfolio and (1-y) = weight of risk-free assets: $90,000 1 y   y   0.7 0.3 $210,000 $300,000 $113,400 $96,600 B :  E :  .322 • Complete Portfolio is: (0.3, 0.378, 0.322) $300,000 .378 $300,000 $300,000
  • 171. MGB Portfolio Management I The Risk-Free Asset • Only the government can issue default-free bonds. – Risk-free in real terms only if price indexed and maturity equal to investor’s holding period. • T-bills viewed as “the” risk-free asset • Money market funds also considered risk-free in practice
  • 172. MGB Portfolio Management I Figure 6.3 Spread Between 3-Month CD and T-bill Rates
  • 173. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolios of One Risky Asset and a Risk-Free Asset • It’s possible to create a complete portfolio by splitting investment funds between safe and risky assets. – Let y=portion allocated to the risky portfolio, P – (1-y)=portion to be invested in risk-free asset, F.
  • 174. MGB Portfolio Management I Example rf = 7% srf = 0% E(rp) = 15% sp = 22% y = % in p (1-y) = % in rf
  • 175. MGB Portfolio Management I Example (Ctd.) The expected return on the complete portfolio is the risk-free rate plus the weight of P times the risk premium of P E(rc )  rf  y E(rP )  rf  Er   7  y15  7 c
  • 176. MGB Portfolio Management I Example (Ctd.) • The risk of the complete portfolio is the weight of P times the risk of P: y y C P s  s  22 – This follows straight from the formulas we saw before and the fact that any constant random variable has zero variance.
  • 177. MGB Portfolio Management I Feasible (var, mean) • Taken together this determines the set of feasible (mean,variance) portfolio return: Er   7  y15  7 c y y C P s  s  22 – This determines a straight line, which we call Capital Allocation Line. Next we derive it’s equation completely
  • 178. MGB Portfolio Management I Example (Ctd.) • Rearrange and substitute y=sC/sP: s 8   C     P f C E r  r  E r  r  7  s C f s P 22 – The sub-index C is to stand for complete portfolio   8 22  E r  r P f  s P Slope – The slope has a special name: Sharpe ratio.
  • 179. MGB Portfolio Management I The Investment Opportunity Set
  • 180. MGB Portfolio Management I Capital Allocation Line - Changing Allocation Increasing he fraction of the overall portfolio invested in the risky asset increases the expected return by the risk premium of the equation (which is 8%) but also increases portfolio standard deviation at the rate of 22%. The extra return per extra risk is 8/22 = 0.36
  • 181. MGB Portfolio Management I Capital Allocation Line Changing Allocation I have invested 300,000 risky assets and if I borrow 120,000 and invest it into the risky asset as well y = 420,000/300,000 = 1.4 1-y = 1-1.4 = -0.4 E(rc) = 7% + (1.4 x 8%) = 18.2% σc = 1.4 X 22% = 30.8% S= E(rc) – rf = 18.2 – 7 = 0.36 σc 30.8
  • 182. MGB Portfolio Management I Capital Allocation Line with Leverage • Lend at rf=7% and borrow at rf=9% – Lending range slope = 8/22 = 0.36 – Borrowing range slope = 6/22 = 0.27 • CAL kinks at P
  • 183. MGB Portfolio Management I The Opportunity Set with Differential Borrowing and Lending Rates
  • 184. MGB Portfolio Management I Utility Levels for Various Positions in Risky Assets (y) for an Investor with Risk Aversion A = 4
  • 185. MGB Portfolio Management I Utility as a Function of Allocation to the Risky Asset, y
  • 186. MGB Portfolio Management I Table 6.5 Spreadsheet Calculations of Indifference Curves
  • 187. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio problem • Agent’s problem with one risky and one risk-free asset is thus: • Pick portfolio (y, 1-y) to maximize utility U – U(y,1-y) = E(rC) -0.005*A*Var(rC) • Where rC is the complete portfolio – This is the same as – rf + y[E(r) – rf] -0.5*A*y2*Var(r) – Solution: y* = E(r) – rf )/0.01A*Var(rC)
  • 188. MGB Portfolio Management I Indifference Curves for U = .05 and U = .09 with A = 2 and A = 4
  • 189. MGB Portfolio Management I Finding the Optimal Complete Portfolio Using Indifference Curves
  • 190. MGB Portfolio Management I Expected Returns on Four Indifference Curves and the CAL
  • 191. MGB Portfolio Management I Risk Tolerance and Asset Allocation • The investor must choose one optimal portfolio, C, from the set of feasible choices – Expected return of the complete portfolio: E(rc )  rf  y E(rP )  rf  – Variance: 2 2 2 C P s  y s
  • 192. MGB Portfolio Management I Summary The Asset Allocation process has 2 steps: 1. Determine the CAL 2. Find the point of highest utility along that line
  • 193. MGB Portfolio Management I One word on Indifference Curves • If you see the IC curves over (mean,st. dev) you will note that these are all nice smooth concave curves. – This is an assumption. – Note that investors have preference over random variables (representing payoff/return). A random variable, in general, is not completely described by (mean, variance). • That is, in general, we can have X and Y with mean(X) < mean (Y) and var(X)=var(Y) BUT X is ranked better than Y nonetheless.
  • 194. MGB Portfolio Management I Passive Strategies: The Capital Market Line • A natural candidate for a passively held risky asset would be a well-diversified portfolio of common stocks such as the S&P 500. • The capital market line (CML) is the capital allocation line formed from 1-month T-bills and a broad index of common stocks (e.g. the S&P 500).
  • 195. MGB Portfolio Management I Passive Strategies: The Capital Market Line • The CML is given by a strategy that involves investment in two passive portfolios: 1. virtually risk-free short-term T-bills (or a money market fund) 2. a fund of common stocks that mimics a broad market index.
  • 196. MGB Portfolio Management I Passive Strategies: The Capital Market Line • From 1926 to 2009, the passive risky portfolio offered an average risk premium of 7.9% with a standard deviation of 20.8%, resulting in a reward-to-volatility ratio of .38.
  • 197. MGB Portfolio Management I Diversification and Portfolio Risk • Suppose there is a single common source of risk in the economy. • All assets are exposed both to this single common source of risk and a separate 197 idiosyncratic source of risk that is uncorrelated across assets. • Then the insurance principle says that if we construct a portfolio of a very large number of these assets, the combined portfolio will only reflect the common risk. The idiosyncratic risk will average out and tend to zero as the number of securities grows very large. • Thus, if there are many home fire insurance policyholders and the risk of fire is uncorrelated across similarly sized homes, then if the number of policy holders is very large, the actual losses in the portfolio tends to the expected loss per home times the number of homes. • This means that homeowners, by pooling their risk, can remove their exposure to risk completely. • In practice, the risks are not completed uncorrelated across homes but a fair amount of risk reduction is possible. • The next slide shows graphically how portfolio risk would be affected in these conditions.
  • 198. MGB Portfolio Management I Diversification and Portfolio Risk 198
  • 199. MGB Portfolio Management I Diversification and Portfolio Risk 199
  • 200. MGB Portfolio Management I Investment Opportunity Sets: Risky Assets This graph shows the portfolio opportunity set for different values of . That is, the combination of portfolio E(r) and s than can be obtained by combining the two asset. In our example, the equity asset has an expected return of 13%, while the bond asset has an expected return of 8%. The curved line joining the two assets D and E is, in effect, part of the opportunity set of (E(R), s) combinations available to the investor. To get the entire opportunity set, we simply extend this curve both beyond E and beyond D.
  • 201. MGB Portfolio Management I Optimal Portfolio: Two Risky Assets
  • 202. MGB Portfolio Management I 7-202 Covariance and Correlation • Portfolio risk depends on the correlation between the returns of the assets in the portfolio • Covariance and the correlation coefficient provide a measure of the way returns of two assets vary
  • 203. MGB Portfolio Management I 7-203 Two-Security Portfolio: Return r  p w r w r D D E E r  Portfolio Return P w  Bond Weight D r  Bond Return D w  Equity Weight E r  Equity Return E E ( r )  w E ( r )  w E ( r ) p D D E E
  • 204. MGB Portfolio Management I 7-204 Two-Security Portfolio: Risk D D E E D E  D E  w w 2w w Cov r ,r 2 2 2 2 2 p s  s  s  = Variance of Security D = Variance of Security E = Covariance of returns for Security D and Security E 2 D s 2 E s   D E Cov r , r
  • 205. MGB Portfolio Management I Two-Security Portfolio: Risk • Another way to express variance of the portfolio: 2 ( , ) ( , ) 2 ( , ) P D D D D E E E E D E D E w s  w Cov r r  w w Cov r r  w w Cov r r
  • 206. MGB Portfolio Management I Covariance Cov(rD,rE) = DEsDsE D,E = Correlation coefficient of returns sD = Standard deviation of returns for Security D sE = Standard deviation of returns for Security E
  • 207. MGB Portfolio Management I Correlation Coefficients: Possible Values Range of values for 1,2 + 1.0 >  > -1.0 If  = 1.0, the securities are perfectly positively correlated If  = - 1.0, the securities are perfectly negatively correlated
  • 208. MGB Portfolio Management I Correlation Coefficients • When ρDE = 1, there is no diversification P E E D D s  w s  w s • When ρDE = -1, a perfect hedge is possible s E w   w D D  1 s  s D E
  • 209. MGB Portfolio Management I Computation of Portfolio Variance From the Covariance Matrix
  • 210. MGB Portfolio Management I Three-Asset Portfolio 1 1 2 2 3 3 E(rp )  w E(r )  w E(r )  w E(r ) 2 s ws ws ws p    2 3 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 1,2 1 3 1,3 2 3 2,3  2w ws  2w ws  2w ws
  • 211. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Expected Return as a Function of Investment Proportions
  • 212. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Standard Deviation as a Function of Investment Proportions
  • 213. MGB Portfolio Management I 7-213 The Minimum Variance Portfolio • The minimum variance portfolio is the portfolio composed of the risky assets that has the smallest standard deviation, the portfolio with least risk. • When correlation is less than +1, the portfolio standard deviation may be smaller than that of either of the individual component assets. • When correlation is -1, the standard deviation of the minimum variance portfolio is zero.
  • 214. MGB Portfolio Management I Portfolio Expected Return as a Function of Standard Deviation
  • 215. MGB Portfolio Management I Correlation Effects • The amount of possible risk reduction through diversification depends on the correlation. • The risk reduction potential increases as the correlation approaches -1. – If  = +1.0, no risk reduction is possible. – If  = 0, σP may be less than the standard deviation of either component asset. – If  = -1.0, a riskless hedge is possible.
  • 216. MGB Portfolio Management I Optimal Portfolio Selection • We can solve the optimization problem to compute the following useful formulas: • The minimum variance portfolio of risky assets D, E is given by the following formula: • The optimal portfolio for an investor with a risk aversion parameter, A, is given by this formula: 푤퐷 = 퐸 푟퐷 − 퐸 푟퐸 + 0.01퐴[휎2 퐸 − 퐶표푣 푟퐷, 푟퐸 ] 0.01퐴[휎2 퐸 + 휎2 퐷 − 퐶표푣 푟퐷, 푟퐸 ]
  • 217. MGB Portfolio Management I Numerical Example Debt Equity 2 mutual funds Expected Return, E(r) 8% 13% Standard deviation, σ 12% 20% Covariance, Cov (rD, rE) 72 Correlation Coefficient, ρDE 0.30 Wmin(D) = σ2 E – Cov (rD,rE) = 202 -72 = 0.82 σ2 D + σ2 E – 2Cov (rD,rE) 122 + 202 – 2x72 Wmin(E) = 1-0.82 = 0.18 The minimum variance portfolio σ = [0.822 x 122 + 0.182 x 202 + 2x0.82x0.18x72]1/2 = 11.45% Sharpe Ratio SA= E(rA) – rf = 8.9 – 5 = 0.34 σA 11.45
  • 218. MGB Portfolio Management I Optimal Portfolio Selection We now introduce a risk free asset. The expected return on a portfolio consisting of a risk free asset and a risky portfolio is, of course, a weighted average of the expected returns on the component assets. But the standard deviation of the portfolio is also linear in the standard deviation of the risky asset. Hence the CAL if there is one risk free asset and a risky portfolio is simply a straight line passing through the two assets, as shown in the figure on the right.
  • 219. MGB Portfolio Management I Numerical Example Debt Equity 2 mutual funds Expected Return, E(r) 8% 13% Standard deviation, σ 12% 20% Covariance, Cov (rD, rE) 72 Correlation Coefficient, ρDE 0.30 B has an E(r) = 9.5% and a σ of 11.7% giving it a risk premium of 4.5% Its Sharpe Ratio is SB = 9.5 – 5.0 = 0.38 11.7 SB – SA = .38 - .34 = 0.04. We get 4 basis points per percentage point increase in risk.
  • 220. MGB Portfolio Management I Optimal Portfolio Selection The slope of each of the CALs drawn in the previous figure is a reward-to-volatility (Sharpe) ratio. Since we want this ratio to be maximized, the single CAL for the set of risky and risk free assets is the CAL with the steepest slope, i.e. the highest Sharpe ratio.
  • 221. MGB Portfolio Management I Optimal Portfolio Selection If we now superimpose the indifference curve map on the CAL, we can compute the complete optimal portfolio.
  • 222. MGB Portfolio Management I Optimal Portfolio Selection • The formula for the tangency portfolio (shown as portfolio C on the picture in the previous slide) is: Max Sp = 퐸 푟푃 −푟푓 휎푃 • Note that the investor risk aversion coefficient does not show up in this formula. • Once the tangency portfolio is available, all investors choose a combination of this portfolio (denoted p in the formula below) and the risk-free asset. The formula for this, which we know already, is: 푦 ∗ = 퐸 푟푃 − 푟푓 0.01퐴휎2 푃
  • 223. MGB Portfolio Management I Optimal Portfolio Selection • WD = (8-5)400 – (13-5)72__________ = 0.40 (8-5)400 + (13-5)144 – (8-5+13-5)72 • WE = 1-0.4 = 0.60 • σp = (0.42 x 144 + 0.62x400 + 2 x 0.4 x 0.6 x 72)1/2 = 14.2 • Sp = 11-5/14.2 = 0.42 • Note that the investor risk aversion coefficient does not show up in this formula. • Once the tangency portfolio is available, all investors choose a combination of this portfolio (denoted p in the formula below) and the risk-free asset. The formula for this, which we know already, is: 푦 ∗ = 퐸 푟푃 −푟푓 0.01퐴휎푃 2 = 11 – 5 /(0.01 x 4 x 14.22) = -.7439
  • 224. MGB Portfolio Management I Optimal Portfolio Selection 224 The investor will invest 74.39% of the wealth in Portfolio P and 25.62 in T-bills. Portfolio P consists of 40% bonds and 60% stocks so 0.4x74.39 = 29.76% of the wealth will be in bonds and 0.6 x 74.39 = 44.63% of the wealth will be in stocks.
  • 226. MGB Portfolio Management I Numerical Example You have available to you, two mutual funds, whose returns have a correlation of 0.23. Both funds belong to the fund category “Balanced – Domestic.” Here is some information on the fund returns for the last six years (obtained from http://www.financialweb.com/funds/): In addition, you can also invest in a risk free 1-year T-bill yielding 6.286%. The expected return on the market portfolio is 20%. a.If you have a risk aversion coefficient of 4, and you have a total of $20,000 to invest, how much should you invest in each of the three investment vehicles? b.What is the standard deviation of your optimal portfolio? 226 Year Capital Value Fund Green Century Balanced Year Capital Value Fund Green Century Balanced 1999 21.32% -10.12% 1996 21.48% 18.26% 1998 21.44% 18.91% 1995 0.91% -4.28% 1997 9.86% 24.91% 1994 10.79% -0.47% average 14.30% 7.87% stdev 8.52% 14.57%
  • 227. MGB Portfolio Management I Solution • a. Using the formula, we can find the portfolio weights for the tangent portfolio of risky assets as follows: which works out to 1641.13/1529.31 = 1.073. Hence wGCB = 1-(1.073) = - 0.073. In order to find the optimal combination of the tangent portfolio and the risk free asset for our investor, we need to compute the expected return on the tangent portfolio and the variance of portfolio returns. E(Rtgtport) = 1.073(14.3) + (-0.073)(7.87) = 14.77% Var(Rtgtport) = (1.073)2(8.52)2 + (-0.073)2(14.57)2 + 2(-0.073)(1.073)(8.52)(14.57)(0.23) = 82.47. Hence, stgtport = 9.08%
  • 228. MGB Portfolio Management I Solution (Contd.) Using the formula y* = [E(Rport) – Rf]/0.01AVar(Rtgtport), we get y* = = 2.57; hence the proportion in the riskfree asset is -1.57. In other words, the investor borrows to invest in the tangent portfolio. If the investor’s total outlay is $20,000, the amount borrowed equals (20000)(1.57) = $31,400. This provides a total of $51,400 for investment in the tangent portfolio. However, the tangent portfolio itself consists of shortselling Green Century Balanced to the extent of (0.073)(51,400) = 3752.20, providing a total of 51,400 + 3752.2 = $55,152.20 for investment in Capital Value Fund. b. The standard deviation of the optimal portfolio is 2.57(9.08) = 23.34%. The expected return on the optimal portfolio is 2.57(14.77) + (- 1.57)(6.286) = 28.09%
  • 229. MGB Portfolio Management I Optimal Portfolio Selection • Until now, we have dealt with the case of two risky assets. We now increase the number of risky assets to more than two. • In this case, graphically, the situation remains the same, as we will see, except that the opportunity set instead of being a simple parabolic curve becomes an area, bounded by a parabolic curve. • However, since all investors are interested in higher expected return and lower variance of returns, only the northwestern frontier of this set is relevant, and so the graphic illustration remains comparable. • Mathematically, the computation of the tangency portfolio is a bit more complicated, and will require the solution of a system of n equations. We will not go further into it, here. • We now look at the graphical illustration of the problem
  • 230. MGB Portfolio Management I Markowitz Portfolio Selection • The first step is to determine the risk-return opportunities available. • All portfolios that lie on the minimum-variance frontier from the global minimum-variance portfolio and upward provide the best risk-return combinations
  • 231. MGB Portfolio Management I Markowitz Portfolio Selection • We now search for the CAL with the highest reward-to-variability ratio
  • 232. MGB Portfolio Management I Markowitz Portfolio Selection • The separation property tells us that the portfolio choice problem may be separated into two independent tasks – Determination of the optimal risky portfolio is purely technical. – Allocation of the complete portfolio to T-bills versus the risky portfolio depends on personal preference. • Thus, everyone invests in P, regardless of their degree of risk aversion. – More risk averse investors put more in the risk-free asset. – Less risk averse investors put more in P.
  • 233. MGB Portfolio Management I More on Diversification • We have seen that D D E E D E  D E  w w 2w w Cov r ,r 2 2 2 2 2 p s  s  s  • If we have three assets, portfolio variance is given by: 2 s ws ws ws p    2 3 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 1,2 1 3 1,3 2 3 2,3  2w ws  2w ws  2w ws • If we generalize it to n assets, we can write the formula as: • Defining the average variance and the average covariance, we then get • That is, the portfolio variance is a weighted average of the average variance and the average covariance. • However, as the number of assets increases, the relative weight on the variance goes to zero, while that on the covariance goes to 1. • Hence we see that it is the covariance between the returns on the component assets that is important for the determination of the portfolio variance.

Notas del editor

  1. All mutual funds sold to the public – performance of all general equity mutual funds compared to the Wilshire 5000 Index. In most years more than ½ of the funds were outperformed by the index. Over the 26.5 year period about 2/3 of the funds proved inferior to the market as a whole. Same result holds for professional pension managers.
  2. People develop general principles as they find things out for themsevles They rely on rules of thumb to draw inferences from info at their disposal They are susceptible to errors because the heuristics are imperfect They commit errors for this reason.
  3. Overconfidence again Driving ability? Investors are about as overconfident of their trading ability as they are of their driving ability. Investors take bad bets because they fail to realize they are at an informational disadvantage. Investors trade to frequently. Other behavior analysis points to investor overconfidence as perpetuating stock price bubbles Representativeness– Stocks that have been extreme past losers in the preceding 3 years do much better than extreme past winners over the subsequent three years. Long term earning forecasts made by analysts tend to be biased in the direction of recent success. Analysts over-react being much more optimistic about recent winners and pessimistic about recent losers.
  4. Generally the majority choose the guaranteed win——this is the risk averse answer because the expected payoff is $1,500 exactly the same as the guaranteed payoff, but expected utility is higher for the certain outcome under risk aversion.
  5. Usually people now choose the risky (i.e. uncertain outcome). People are not uniform in their tolerance for risk. It depends on the frame. Usually people tolerate more risk when they face the prospect of a loss—i.e. they will take on more risk if there is a chance they can minimize a loss.
  6. From a dollar perspective, 1 and 3 are identical. You should respond the same to both. Yet usually people switch their choices. 25% often take the gamble in 2. Why? Hedonic editing. If you loose 450, you combine it with your earlier gain to end up with $1050. But if you win, you savor your two gains separately. The added attraction of experiencing gains separately inclines people to be more willing to take the gamble.
  7. From a dollar perspective, 1 and 3 are identical. You should respond the same to both. Yet usually people switch their choices. 25% often take the gamble in 2. Why? Hedonic editing. If you loose 450, you combine it with your earlier gain to end up with $1050. But if you win, you savor your two gains separately. The added attraction of experiencing gains separately inclines people to be more willing to take the gamble.
  8. From a dollar perspective, 1 and 3 are identical. You should respond the same to both. Yet usually people switch their choices. 25% often take the gamble in 2. Why? Hedonic editing. If you loose 450, you combine it with your earlier gain to end up with $1050. But if you win, you savor your two gains separately. The added attraction of experiencing gains separately inclines people to be more willing to take the gamble.