SlideShare una empresa de Scribd logo
1 de 161
Descargar para leer sin conexión
Redistributive Allocation Mechanisms
(with an application to the potential European energy crisis)
Mohammad Akbarpour r
O Piotr Dworczak r
O Scott Duke Kominers*
(Stanford) (GRAPE & Northwestern) (Harvard)
22 November, 2022
European Central Bank, invited speaker seminar
Research sponsored by ERC grant IMD-101040122.
*Authors’ names are in certified random order.
Motivation
Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms,
even though monetary transfers are feasible:
Housing
Motivation
Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms,
even though monetary transfers are feasible:
Housing
Health care
Motivation
Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms,
even though monetary transfers are feasible:
Housing
Health care
Food
Motivation
Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms,
even though monetary transfers are feasible:
Housing
Health care
Food
Road access
Motivation
Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms,
even though monetary transfers are feasible:
Housing
Health care
Food
Road access
...
Motivation
Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms,
even though monetary transfers are feasible:
Housing
Health care
Food
Road access
...
Follow-up paper: Covid-19 vaccines
Motivation
Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms,
even though monetary transfers are feasible:
Housing
Health care
Food
Road access
...
Follow-up paper: Covid-19 vaccines
Focus today: Energy this winter in Europe
Motivation—European energy crisis
Source: Sgaravatti, G., S. Tagliapietra, G. Zachmann (2021) ‘National policies to shield consumers from rising energy prices’
Motivation—European energy crisis
Source: Sgaravatti, G., S. Tagliapietra, G. Zachmann (2021) ‘National policies to shield consumers from rising energy prices’
Motivation—European energy crisis
Source: Sgaravatti, G., S. Tagliapietra, G. Zachmann (2021) ‘National policies to shield consumers from rising energy prices’
Motivation
Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to
inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum
payments (II WT)
Motivation
Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to
inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum
payments (II WT)
▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152
Motivation
Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to
inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum
payments (II WT)
▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152
But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information!
Motivation
Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to
inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum
payments (II WT)
▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152
But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information!
Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in
practice:
Motivation
Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to
inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum
payments (II WT)
▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152
But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information!
Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in
practice:
▶ Detailed financial situation?
Motivation
Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to
inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum
payments (II WT)
▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152
But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information!
Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in
practice:
▶ Detailed financial situation?
▶ Job market opportunities?
Motivation
Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to
inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum
payments (II WT)
▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152
But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information!
Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in
practice:
▶ Detailed financial situation?
▶ Job market opportunities?
▶ Exposure to interest rate hikes?
Motivation
Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to
inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum
payments (II WT)
▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152
But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information!
Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in
practice:
▶ Detailed financial situation?
▶ Job market opportunities?
▶ Exposure to interest rate hikes?
▶ Energy efficiency of housing?
Motivation
Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to
inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum
payments (II WT)
▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152
But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information!
Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in
practice:
▶ Detailed financial situation?
▶ Job market opportunities?
▶ Exposure to interest rate hikes?
▶ Energy efficiency of housing?
▶ Heating method?
Motivation
Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to
inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum
payments (II WT)
▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152
But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information!
Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in
practice:
▶ Detailed financial situation?
▶ Job market opportunities?
▶ Exposure to interest rate hikes?
▶ Energy efficiency of housing?
▶ Heating method?
▶ Family size?
Inequality-aware Market Design
Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal
allocation under redistributive concerns
(Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market)
Inequality-aware Market Design
Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal
allocation under redistributive concerns
(Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market)
Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed
and unobserved characteristics.
Inequality-aware Market Design
Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal
allocation under redistributive concerns
(Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market)
Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed
and unobserved characteristics.
We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and
an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights.
Inequality-aware Market Design
Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal
allocation under redistributive concerns
(Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market)
Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed
and unobserved characteristics.
We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and
an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights.
Some key take-aways:
Inequality-aware Market Design
Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal
allocation under redistributive concerns
(Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market)
Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed
and unobserved characteristics.
We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and
an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights.
Some key take-aways:
▶ Non-market mechanisms can be optimal!
Inequality-aware Market Design
Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal
allocation under redistributive concerns
(Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market)
Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed
and unobserved characteristics.
We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and
an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights.
Some key take-aways:
▶ Non-market mechanisms can be optimal!
▶ If lump-sum payments are available, uniform price caps are never
optimal;
Inequality-aware Market Design
Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal
allocation under redistributive concerns
(Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market)
Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed
and unobserved characteristics.
We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and
an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights.
Some key take-aways:
▶ Non-market mechanisms can be optimal!
▶ If lump-sum payments are available, uniform price caps are never
optimal;
▶ Instead, price caps should only be applied up to some threshold
consumption level;
Inequality-aware Market Design
Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal
allocation under redistributive concerns
(Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market)
Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed
and unobserved characteristics.
We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and
an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights.
Some key take-aways:
▶ Non-market mechanisms can be optimal!
▶ If lump-sum payments are available, uniform price caps are never
optimal;
▶ Instead, price caps should only be applied up to some threshold
consumption level;
▶ Uniform price caps can be optimal when lump-sum payments are
costly;
Literature
Weitzman (1977): First paper to point out that random allocation
might be preferred to market pricing when agents’ “needs” are not
well expressed by willingness to pay.
Condorelli (2013): A full mechanism-design approach to Weitzman’s
problem
▶ On a technical level: We add heterogeneous quality of objects,
continuum of goods and agents, groups of agents with the same
observable characteristics, and designer’s preferences over revenue.
▶ On a conceptual level: We focus on a particular objective function
(weighted sum of utilities and revenue) and connect market
circumstances with practical conclusions about the optimal design.
Dworczak r
O Kominers r
O Akbarpour (2021): two-sided market
but “maximally simplified” (no heterogeneous quality, no observable
information, no restrictions on lump-sum transfers)
Literature
Price control, public provision of goods: Nichols and Zeckhauser (1982), Besley
and Coate (1991), Blackorby and Donaldson (1988), Viscusi, Harrington, and
Vernon (2005), Gahvari and Mattos (2007), Currie and Gahvari (2008)
Optimal taxation: Diamond and Mirrlees (1971), Atkinson and Stiglitz (1976),
Akerlof (1978), Saez and Stantcheva (2016)
Auctions with budget-constrained bidders: Che and Gale (1998), Fernandez and
Gali (1999); Che, Gale, and Kim (2012); Pai and Vohra (2014); Kotowski (2017)
Costly-screening/ money-burning literature: McAfee and McMillan (1992),
Damiano and Li (2007), Hartline and Roughgarden (2008), Hoppe, Moldovanu,
and Sela (2009), Condorelli (2012), Chakravarty and Kaplan (2013)
Methods (generalized ironing): Muir and Loertscher (2021), Ashlagi, Monachou,
and Nikzad (2021), Kleiner, Moldovanu, and Strack (2021), Z. Kang (2020a).
New threads in mechanism design with redistribution motives: Z. Kang
(2020b), M. Kang and Zheng (2020, 2021), Reuter and Groh (2021)
Model
Model
Model
A designer chooses a mechanism to allocate a unit mass of objects to
a unit mass of agents.
Each object has quality q ∈ [0, 1], q is distributed acc. to cdf F.
Each agent is characterized by a type (i, r, λ), where:
i is an observable label, i ∈ I (finite);
r is an unobserved willingness to pay (for quality), r ∈ R+;
λ is an unobserved social welfare weight, λ ∈ R+;
The type distribution is known to the designer.
If (i, r, λ) gets a good with quality q and pays t, her utility is qr − t,
while her contribution to social welfare is λ(qr − t)
Model
Comments for the energy context:
Quality normalized to 0 or 1, interpreted as quantity.
Then, q = 1 can be interpreted as the “normal consumption level.”
Instead of distribution of quality F, we just have total quantity S
available: F(q) = 1{q≥S}.
Throughout, assume that S < 1.
To the extent that some households have a higher “normal
consumption level,” we can (intuitively) fold it into the WTP r
r · qnormal = rqnormal
| {z }
r̃
· 1
Model
The designer has access to arbitrary (direct) allocation mechanisms
(Γ, T) where Γ(q|i, r, λ) is the probability that (i, r, λ) gets a good with
quality q or less, and T(i, r, λ) is the associated payment, subject to:
Feasibility: E(i,r,λ) [Γ(q|i, r, λ)] ≥ F(q), ∀q ∈ [0, 1];
IC constraint: Each agent (i, r, λ) reports (r, λ) truthfully;
IR constraint: U(i, r, λ) ≡ r
R
qdΓ(q|i, r, λ) − T(i, r, λ) ≥ 0;
Non-negative transfers: T(i, r, λ) ≥ 0, ∀(i, r, λ).
The designer maximizes, for some constant α ≥ 0, a weighted sum of
revenue and agents’ utilities:
E(i,r,λ) [αT(i, r, λ) + λU(i, r, λ)] .
Comments about the model
Lemma: It is without loss of optimality for the mechanism designer to
only elicit information about r through the mechanism—allocation and
transfers depend on (i, r) but not on λ directly.
Comments about the model
Lemma: It is without loss of optimality for the mechanism designer to
only elicit information about r through the mechanism—allocation and
transfers depend on (i, r) but not on λ directly.
This implies that the designer forms expectations over the unobserved
social welfare weights:
λi(r) ≡ E(i,r,λ) [λ| i, r] ;
we call these functions Pareto weights, and assume they are continuous.
Comments about the model
Lemma: It is without loss of optimality for the mechanism designer to
only elicit information about r through the mechanism—allocation and
transfers depend on (i, r) but not on λ directly.
This implies that the designer forms expectations over the unobserved
social welfare weights:
λi(r) ≡ E(i,r,λ) [λ| i, r] ;
we call these functions Pareto weights, and assume they are continuous.
Designer’s objective becomes:
E(i,r) [αTi(r) + λi(r)Ui(r)] .
Comments about the model
λi(r) ≡ E(i,r,λ) [λ| i, r]
Economic idea:
The designer assesses the “need” of agents by estimating the unobserved
welfare weights based on the observable (label i) and elicitable (wtp r)
information.
Comments about the model
λi(r) ≡ E(i,r,λ) [λ| i, r]
Economic idea:
The designer assesses the “need” of agents by estimating the unobserved
welfare weights based on the observable (label i) and elicitable (wtp r)
information.
Consequence:
The optimal allocation depends on the statistical correlation of labels
and willingness to pay with the unobserved social welfare weights.
Comments about the model
Correlation of labels with welfare weights:
If label i captures income brackets, then we may naturally think that
E[λ| i] ≡ λ̄i ≥ λ̄j ≡ E[λ| j]
if i corresponds to a lower income bracket than j;
Comments about the model
Correlation of labels with welfare weights:
If label i captures income brackets, then we may naturally think that
E[λ| i] ≡ λ̄i ≥ λ̄j ≡ E[λ| j]
if i corresponds to a lower income bracket than j;
Other possibilities (varies by country): Labels could capture family
size, energy efficiency of housing, heating method, exposure to
interest rate hikes.
Comments about the model
Correlation of WTP with welfare weights:
Suppose there is just one label I = {i}, but we elicit information
about willingness to pay of two patients for a treatment:
Agent A: e50,000
Agent B: e1,000
Naturally, we may presume that λi(r) is decreasing in r.
Comments about the model
Correlation of WTP with welfare weights:
Many labels, i captures low income, and we elicit information
about willingness to pay of two patients for a treatment:
Agent A: e 50,000
Agent B: e1,000
Naturally, we may presume that λi(r) is (“less”) decreasing in r.
Comments about the model
Correlation of WTP with welfare weights:
Suppose there is just one label I = {i}, but we elicit information
about WTP of two consumers for maintaining “normal” energy
consumption:
Agent A: $10,000
Agent B: $5,000
Naturally, we may presume that λi(r) is decreasing in r.
Comments about the model
Correlation of WTP with welfare weights:
Many labels, i captures family size and energy efficiency, but we
elicit information about WTP of two consumers for maintaining
“normal” energy consumption:
Agent A: $10,000
Agent B: $5,000
Naturally, we may presume that λi(r) is (“more”) decreasing in r.
Comments about the model
The role of revenue:
The weight α on revenue captures the value of a dollar in the
designer’s budget, spent on the most valuable “cause.”
Comments about the model
The role of revenue:
The weight α on revenue captures the value of a dollar in the
designer’s budget, spent on the most valuable “cause.”
When α = maxi λ̄i, then it is as if a lump-sum transfer to group i
were allowed; when α = averagei λ̄i, then it is as if lump-sum
transfers to all agents were allowed.
Comments about the model
The role of revenue:
The weight α on revenue captures the value of a dollar in the
designer’s budget, spent on the most valuable “cause.”
When α = maxi λ̄i, then it is as if a lump-sum transfer to group i
were allowed; when α = averagei λ̄i, then it is as if lump-sum
transfers to all agents were allowed.
When α > λ̄i for all i, there is an “outside cause”.
Comments about the model
The role of revenue:
The weight α on revenue captures the value of a dollar in the
designer’s budget, spent on the most valuable “cause.”
When α = maxi λ̄i, then it is as if a lump-sum transfer to group i
were allowed; when α = averagei λ̄i, then it is as if lump-sum
transfers to all agents were allowed.
When α > λ̄i for all i, there is an “outside cause”.
When α < λ̄i for some i, lump-sum payments to agents in group
i are prohibited or costly (insurance motive as in Gadenne et al.,
2022).
Comments about the model
The role of revenue:
The weight α on revenue captures the value of a dollar in the
designer’s budget, spent on the most valuable “cause.”
When α = maxi λ̄i, then it is as if a lump-sum transfer to group i
were allowed; when α = averagei λ̄i, then it is as if lump-sum
transfers to all agents were allowed.
When α > λ̄i for all i, there is an “outside cause”.
When α < λ̄i for some i, lump-sum payments to agents in group
i are prohibited or costly (insurance motive as in Gadenne et al.,
2022).
When α = 0, we are in the money-burning/costly-screening case.
Comments about the model
Universally desired goods
Comments about the model
Universally desired goods
Let Gi(r) be the cdf of willingness to pay conditional on label i, and let
gi(r) be its continuous positive density on [ri, r̄i].
Comments about the model
Universally desired goods
Let Gi(r) be the cdf of willingness to pay conditional on label i, and let
gi(r) be its continuous positive density on [ri, r̄i].
We call the good universally desired (for group i) if ri > 0.
Comments about the model
Universally desired goods
Let Gi(r) be the cdf of willingness to pay conditional on label i, and let
gi(r) be its continuous positive density on [ri, r̄i].
We call the good universally desired (for group i) if ri > 0.
Interpretation: A vast majority of agents have a willingness to pay that is
bounded away from zero.
Comments about the model
Universally desired goods
Let Gi(r) be the cdf of willingness to pay conditional on label i, and let
gi(r) be its continuous positive density on [ri, r̄i].
We call the good universally desired (for group i) if ri > 0.
Interpretation: A vast majority of agents have a willingness to pay that is
bounded away from zero.
Examples:
“Essential” goods: housing, energy, food, basic health care;
Comments about the model
Universally desired goods
Let Gi(r) be the cdf of willingness to pay conditional on label i, and let
gi(r) be its continuous positive density on [ri, r̄i].
We call the good universally desired (for group i) if ri > 0.
Interpretation: A vast majority of agents have a willingness to pay that is
bounded away from zero.
Examples:
“Essential” goods: housing, energy, food, basic health care;
“Stores of value”: shares, currencies, commodities
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism
1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆
i ;
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism
1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆
i ;
2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects
F⋆
i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism
1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆
i ;
2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects
F⋆
i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism
1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆
i ;
2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects
F⋆
i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details
Observation: Only expected quality, Qi(r), matters for payoffs.
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism
1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆
i ;
2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects
F⋆
i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details
Observation: Only expected quality, Qi(r), matters for payoffs.
Result: Within a group, agents are partitioned into intervals according to
WTP, with either the “market” or “non-market” allocation in each interval
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism
1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆
i ;
2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects
F⋆
i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details
Observation: Only expected quality, Qi(r), matters for payoffs.
Result: Within a group, agents are partitioned into intervals according to
WTP, with either the “market” or “non-market” allocation in each interval
Market allocation: assortative matching between WTP and quality
Qi(r) = (F⋆
i )−1
(Gi(r)), ∀r ∈ [a, b];
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism
1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆
i ;
2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects
F⋆
i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details
Observation: Only expected quality, Qi(r), matters for payoffs.
Result: Within a group, agents are partitioned into intervals according to
WTP, with either the “market” or “non-market” allocation in each interval
Market allocation: assortative matching between WTP and quality
Qi(r) = (F⋆
i )−1
(Gi(r)), ∀r ∈ [a, b];
Non-market allocation: random matching (rationing!) between
WTP and quality
Qi(r) = q̄, ∀r ∈ [a, b].
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
Economic Implications
Economic Implications
Economic Implications
Proposition 1 (WTP-revealed inequality )
Suppose that α ≥ λ̄i (lump-sum payments are available).
Economic Implications
Proposition 1 (WTP-revealed inequality )
Suppose that α ≥ λ̄i (lump-sum payments are available).
Then, it is optimal to ration agents with willingness to pay in some
(non-degenerate) interval if and only if the function αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is
not non-decreasing, where
hi(r) =
1 − Gi(r)
gi(r)
, Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei
[λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r].
Economic Implications
Proposition 1 (WTP-revealed inequality )
Suppose that α ≥ λ̄i (lump-sum payments are available).
Then, it is optimal to ration agents with willingness to pay in some
(non-degenerate) interval if and only if the function αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is
not non-decreasing, where
hi(r) =
1 − Gi(r)
gi(r)
, Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei
[λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r].
Assuming differentiability, the condition becomes
Λ′
i(r)hi(r) + α + (Λi(r) − α)h′
i(r) < 0.
Economic Implications
Proposition 1 (WTP-revealed inequality )
Suppose that α ≥ λ̄i (lump-sum payments are available).
Then, it is optimal to ration agents with willingness to pay in some
(non-degenerate) interval if and only if the function αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is
not non-decreasing, where
hi(r) =
1 − Gi(r)
gi(r)
, Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei
[λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r].
Assuming differentiability, the condition becomes
Λ′
i(r)hi(r) + α + (Λi(r) − α)h′
i(r) < 0.
Some non-market allocation is optimal if willingness to pay is strongly
(negatively) correlated with the unobserved social welfare weights.
Economic Implications
Proposition 2 (Optimality of uniform rationing)
A necessary condition for uniform rationing (at a fixed low price) to be
optimal within group i is that
αr̄i ≤
Z r̄i
ri
rλi(r)dGi(r).
This condition becomes sufficient if αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is quasi-convex.
Economic Implications
Proposition 2 (Optimality of uniform rationing)
A necessary condition for uniform rationing (at a fixed low price) to be
optimal within group i is that
αr̄i ≤
Z r̄i
ri
rλi(r)dGi(r).
This condition becomes sufficient if αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is quasi-convex.
Key take-away: It is never optimal to use uniform rationing if a
lump-sum payment to group i is feasible.
Economic Implications
Proposition 2 (Optimality of uniform rationing)
A necessary condition for uniform rationing (at a fixed low price) to be
optimal within group i is that
αr̄i ≤
Z r̄i
ri
rλi(r)dGi(r).
This condition becomes sufficient if αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is quasi-convex.
Key take-away: It is never optimal to use uniform rationing if a
lump-sum payment to group i is feasible.
By an extension of the same argument: It is never optimal to have a
uniform price cap.
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for
vulnerable households.
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for
vulnerable households.
Each household chooses between a high per-unit price with no limit
on consumption or a lower per-unit price but up to a consumption
threshold q̄ < 1.
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for
vulnerable households.
Each household chooses between a high per-unit price with no limit
on consumption or a lower per-unit price but up to a consumption
threshold q̄ < 1.
Selection will be based on WTP.
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for
vulnerable households.
Each household chooses between a high per-unit price with no limit
on consumption or a lower per-unit price but up to a consumption
threshold q̄ < 1.
Selection will be based on WTP.
Key question: Do we get the “right” selection?
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for
vulnerable households.
Each household chooses between a high per-unit price with no limit
on consumption or a lower per-unit price but up to a consumption
threshold q̄ < 1.
Selection will be based on WTP.
Key question: Do we get the “right” selection?
If yes, subsidize (by reducing the per-unit price) the group that
self-identified as being in need.
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for
vulnerable households.
Each household chooses between a high per-unit price with no limit
on consumption or a lower per-unit price but up to a consumption
threshold q̄ < 1.
Selection will be based on WTP.
Key question: Do we get the “right” selection?
If yes, subsidize (by reducing the per-unit price) the group that
self-identified as being in need.
If no, then the rationing policy is pure allocative inefficiency.
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
The answer to the question largely depends on available labels!
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
The answer to the question largely depends on available labels!
Mathematically, we need strong negative correlation between WTP
and welfare weights (Λ′
i(r) < 0)
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
The answer to the question largely depends on available labels!
Mathematically, we need strong negative correlation between WTP
and welfare weights (Λ′
i(r) < 0)
This might hold when we control for confounding factors that wold
raise the WTP of poor households:
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
The answer to the question largely depends on available labels!
Mathematically, we need strong negative correlation between WTP
and welfare weights (Λ′
i(r) < 0)
This might hold when we control for confounding factors that wold
raise the WTP of poor households:
▶ Large family size;
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
The answer to the question largely depends on available labels!
Mathematically, we need strong negative correlation between WTP
and welfare weights (Λ′
i(r) < 0)
This might hold when we control for confounding factors that wold
raise the WTP of poor households:
▶ Large family size;
▶ Energy inefficiency of housing;
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
The answer to the question largely depends on available labels!
Mathematically, we need strong negative correlation between WTP
and welfare weights (Λ′
i(r) < 0)
This might hold when we control for confounding factors that wold
raise the WTP of poor households:
▶ Large family size;
▶ Energy inefficiency of housing;
▶ Electricity-based heating.
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum
payments: Additional screening!
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum
payments: Additional screening!
Market choices may reveal which households are really in need.
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum
payments: Additional screening!
Market choices may reveal which households are really in need.
Then, clear why uniform price and quantity caps can’t work!
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum
payments: Additional screening!
Market choices may reveal which households are really in need.
Then, clear why uniform price and quantity caps can’t work!
They distort economic efficiency without offering the screening
benefit.
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum
payments: Additional screening!
Market choices may reveal which households are really in need.
Then, clear why uniform price and quantity caps can’t work!
They distort economic efficiency without offering the screening
benefit.
Thus, they are dominated by lump-sum payments (here, we agree
with the Economist and the IMF paper)
Economic Implications
Key idea behind optimality of rationing:
Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum
payments: Additional screening!
Market choices may reveal which households are really in need.
Then, clear why uniform price and quantity caps can’t work!
They distort economic efficiency without offering the screening
benefit.
Thus, they are dominated by lump-sum payments (here, we agree
with the Economist and the IMF paper)
What if lump-sum payments are costly? (administration costs,
insurance motive, behavioral aspects, etc.)
Economic Implications
Proposition 3 (Label-revealed inequality )
Suppose that
the average Pareto weight λ̄i for group i is strictly larger than the
weight on revenue α;
the good is universally desired (ri > 0).
Then, there exists r⋆
i > ri such that the optimal allocation is to ration (at
a price of 0) all types r ≤ r⋆
i .
Economic Implications
Proposition 3 (Label-revealed inequality )
Suppose that
the average Pareto weight λ̄i for group i is strictly larger than the
weight on revenue α;
the good is universally desired (ri > 0).
Then, there exists r⋆
i > ri such that the optimal allocation is to ration (at
a price of 0) all types r ≤ r⋆
i .
Interpretation: If the designer would like to redistribute to group i but
cannot give agents in that group a direct cash transfer, then it is optimal
to provide small quantities of universally desired goods for free.
Economic Implications
Proposition 3 (Label-revealed inequality )
Suppose that
the average Pareto weight λ̄i for group i is strictly larger than the
weight on revenue α;
the good is universally desired (ri > 0).
Then, there exists r⋆
i > ri such that the optimal allocation is to ration (at
a price of 0) all types r ≤ r⋆
i .
Interpretation: If the designer would like to redistribute to group i but
cannot give agents in that group a direct cash transfer, then it is optimal
to provide small quantities of universally desired goods for free.
Note: There might still be a price gradient for higher quantities (the exact
condition is the one we have seen before)
Economic Implications
Proposition 1 (Label-revealed inequality )
Suppose that
the average Pareto weight λ̄i for group i is strictly larger than the
weight on revenue α;
the good is universally desired (ri > 0).
Then, there exists r⋆
i > ri such that the optimal allocation is to ration (at
a price of 0) all types r ≤ r⋆
i .
“Wrong” intuition: A random allocation for free increases the welfare of
agents with lowest willingness to pay
Economic Implications
Proposition 1 (Label-revealed inequality )
Suppose that
the average Pareto weight λ̄i for group i is strictly larger than the
weight on revenue α;
the good is universally desired (ri > 0).
Then, there exists r⋆
i > ri such that the optimal allocation is to ration (at
a price of 0) all types r ≤ r⋆
i .
“Wrong” intuition: A random allocation for free increases the welfare of
agents with lowest willingness to pay
Correct Intuition: A random allocation for free enables the designer to
lower prices for all agents Picture
Conclusions
Conclusions
Conclusions
When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a
below-market-clearing prices)
Conclusions
When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a
below-market-clearing prices)
Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved
welfare weights.
Conclusions
When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a
below-market-clearing prices)
Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved
welfare weights.
1 Label-revealed inequality:
Conclusions
When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a
below-market-clearing prices)
Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved
welfare weights.
1 Label-revealed inequality: When lump-sum payments are costly and
some groups can be identified as vulnerable, it is optimal to use some
in-kind redistribution for universally desired goods.
Conclusions
When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a
below-market-clearing prices)
Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved
welfare weights.
1 Label-revealed inequality: When lump-sum payments are costly and
some groups can be identified as vulnerable, it is optimal to use some
in-kind redistribution for universally desired goods.
▶ Energy context: Controlling electricity bills for poorest households may
be easier/ cheaper than direct cash transfers.
Conclusions
When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a
below-market-clearing prices)
Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved
welfare weights.
1 Label-revealed inequality: When lump-sum payments are costly and
some groups can be identified as vulnerable, it is optimal to use some
in-kind redistribution for universally desired goods.
▶ Energy context: Controlling electricity bills for poorest households may
be easier/ cheaper than direct cash transfers.
2 WTP-revealed inequality: When welfare weights are strongly and
negatively correlated with willingness to pay conditional on labels.
Conclusions
When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a
below-market-clearing prices)
Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved
welfare weights.
1 Label-revealed inequality: When lump-sum payments are costly and
some groups can be identified as vulnerable, it is optimal to use some
in-kind redistribution for universally desired goods.
▶ Energy context: Controlling electricity bills for poorest households may
be easier/ cheaper than direct cash transfers.
2 WTP-revealed inequality: When welfare weights are strongly and
negatively correlated with willingness to pay conditional on labels.
▶ Energy context: A well-designed subsidy system can screen for most
vulnerable households, better than a cash transfer scheme could.
Conclusions
We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design.
Conclusions
We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design.
Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors:
Conclusions
We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design.
Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors:
1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the
information that the designer can elicit or observe directly;
Conclusions
We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design.
Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors:
1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the
information that the designer can elicit or observe directly;
2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers;
Conclusions
We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design.
Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors:
1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the
information that the designer can elicit or observe directly;
2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers;
3 Whether the good is universally desired or not.
Conclusions
We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design.
Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors:
1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the
information that the designer can elicit or observe directly;
2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers;
3 Whether the good is universally desired or not.
More work is needed on market design with redistributive
concerns:
Conclusions
We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design.
Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors:
1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the
information that the designer can elicit or observe directly;
2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers;
3 Whether the good is universally desired or not.
More work is needed on market design with redistributive
concerns:
1 There are hundreds (thousands?) of theory papers focusing on how to
maximize revenue or efficiency when allocating resources...
Conclusions
We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design.
Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors:
1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the
information that the designer can elicit or observe directly;
2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers;
3 Whether the good is universally desired or not.
More work is needed on market design with redistributive
concerns:
1 There are hundreds (thousands?) of theory papers focusing on how to
maximize revenue or efficiency when allocating resources...
2 ... but only a handful on how to achieve optimal redistribution.
Conclusions
We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design.
Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors:
1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the
information that the designer can elicit or observe directly;
2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers;
3 Whether the good is universally desired or not.
More work is needed on market design with redistributive
concerns:
1 There are hundreds (thousands?) of theory papers focusing on how to
maximize revenue or efficiency when allocating resources...
2 ... but only a handful on how to achieve optimal redistribution.
3 Much more work remains to be done... (many stylized assumptions in
our model!)
Thank you
Thank you
Appendix
Appendix
Back to slides
Back to slides
Back to slides
Back to slides
Back to slides
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The “within-group” problem:
Fixing a group of agents i, and a distribution of quality Fi available for
group i, what is the optimal way to allocate quality subject to IC and IR
constraints?
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality)
max
Qi(r), Ui(ri)
Z r̄i
ri
Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + (λ̄i − α)Ui(ri)
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality)
max
Qi(r)
Z r̄i
ri
Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri).
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality)
max
Qi(r)
Z r̄i
ri
Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri).
In the above, Vi(r) = αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r), where
hi(r) =
1 − Gi(r)
gi(r)
, Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei
[λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r].
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality)
max
Qi(r)
Z r̄i
ri
Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri).
In the above, Vi(r) = αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r), where
hi(r) =
1 − Gi(r)
gi(r)
, Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei
[λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r].
Feasible distribution of expected quality: CDF Φi such that
Fi ≻MPS Φi.
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality)
max
Qi(r)
Z r̄i
ri
Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri).
In the above, Vi(r) = αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r), where
hi(r) =
1 − Gi(r)
gi(r)
, Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei
[λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r].
Feasible distribution of expected quality: CDF Φi such that
Fi ≻MPS Φi.
Incentive-compatibility =⇒ Gi(r) = Φi(q)
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality)
max
Qi(r)
Z r̄i
ri
Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri).
In the above, Vi(r) = αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r), where
hi(r) =
1 − Gi(r)
gi(r)
, Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei
[λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r].
Feasible distribution of expected quality: CDF Φi such that
Fi ≻MPS Φi.
Incentive-compatibility =⇒ Qi(r) = Φ−1
i (Gi(r))
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality)
max
Qi(r)
Z r̄i
ri
Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri).
In the above, Vi(r) = αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r), where
hi(r) =
1 − Gi(r)
gi(r)
, Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei
[λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r].
Feasible distribution of expected quality: CDF Φi such that
Φ−1
i ≻MPS F−1
i .
Incentive-compatibility =⇒ Qi(r) = Φ−1
i (Gi(r))
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem is
max
Ψi
Z r̄i
ri
Vi(r)Ψi(Gi(r))dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riΨi(0)
s.t. Ψi ≻MPS
F−1
i
Back
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem is
max
Ψi
Z 1
0
Vi(t)
z }| {
Z 1
t
Vi(G−1
i (x))dx + max{0, λ̄i − α}ri1{t=0}

dΨi(t)
s.t. Ψi ≻MPS
F−1
i
Back
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem is
max
Ψi
Z 1
0
Vi(t)
z }| {
Z 1
t
Vi(G−1
i (x))dx + max{0, λ̄i − α}ri1{t=0}

dΨi(t)
s.t. Ψi ≻MPS
F−1
i
Agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP:
Back
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem is
max
Ψi
Z 1
0
Vi(t)
z }| {
Z 1
t
Vi(G−1
i (x))dx + max{0, λ̄i − α}ri1{t=0}

dΨi(t)
s.t. Ψi ≻MPS
F−1
i
Agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP:
▶ Market allocation: assortative matching between WTP and quality
Qi(r) = F−1
i (Gi(r)), ∀r ∈ [a, b];
Back
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem is
max
Ψi
Z 1
0
Vi(t)
z }| {
Z 1
t
Vi(G−1
i (x))dx + max{0, λ̄i − α}ri1{t=0}

dΨi(t)
s.t. Ψi ≻MPS
F−1
i
Agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP:
▶ Market allocation: assortative matching between WTP and quality
Qi(r) = F−1
i (Gi(r)), ∀r ∈ [a, b];
▶ Non-market allocation: random matching between WTP and quality
Qi(r) = q̄, ∀r ∈ [a, b].
Back
Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism
The designer’s problem is
max
Ψi, F̃i
Z 1
0
Vi(t)
z }| {
Z 1
t
Vi(G−1
i (x))dx + max{0, λ̄i − α}ri1{t=0}

dΨi(t)
s.t. Ψi ≻MPS
F̃−1
i ≻FOSD
F−1
i
Agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP:
▶ Market allocation: assortative matching between WTP and quality
Qi(r) = F−1
i (Gi(r)), ∀r ∈ [a, b];
▶ Non-market allocation: random matching between WTP and quality
Qi(r) = q̄, ∀r ∈ [a, b].
Back

Más contenido relacionado

La actualidad más candente

BUWAN NG PAGBASA NARRATIVE REPORT.docx
BUWAN NG PAGBASA NARRATIVE REPORT.docxBUWAN NG PAGBASA NARRATIVE REPORT.docx
BUWAN NG PAGBASA NARRATIVE REPORT.docx
honeybee47
 
1 give justification to a possible ending to a
1 give justification to a possible ending to a1 give justification to a possible ending to a
1 give justification to a possible ending to a
Jennifer Maderazo
 
Filipino 3 Learner's Manual 2nd Quarter
Filipino 3 Learner's Manual 2nd  QuarterFilipino 3 Learner's Manual 2nd  Quarter
Filipino 3 Learner's Manual 2nd Quarter
EDITHA HONRADEZ
 
Aralin 2 pagiging matiyaga uugaliin ko!
Aralin 2 pagiging matiyaga uugaliin ko!Aralin 2 pagiging matiyaga uugaliin ko!
Aralin 2 pagiging matiyaga uugaliin ko!
EDITHA HONRADEZ
 

La actualidad más candente (20)

BUWAN NG PAGBASA NARRATIVE REPORT.docx
BUWAN NG PAGBASA NARRATIVE REPORT.docxBUWAN NG PAGBASA NARRATIVE REPORT.docx
BUWAN NG PAGBASA NARRATIVE REPORT.docx
 
1 give justification to a possible ending to a
1 give justification to a possible ending to a1 give justification to a possible ending to a
1 give justification to a possible ending to a
 
Different parts of a book
Different parts of a bookDifferent parts of a book
Different parts of a book
 
Esp q1 week 3 paggamit ng wastong impormasyon
Esp q1 week 3 paggamit ng wastong impormasyonEsp q1 week 3 paggamit ng wastong impormasyon
Esp q1 week 3 paggamit ng wastong impormasyon
 
Araling Panlipunan 3 Curriculum Guide rev.2016
Araling Panlipunan 3 Curriculum Guide rev.2016Araling Panlipunan 3 Curriculum Guide rev.2016
Araling Panlipunan 3 Curriculum Guide rev.2016
 
CLASSROOM-PROGRAM-GRADE-4_-2022-2023 (4).docx
CLASSROOM-PROGRAM-GRADE-4_-2022-2023 (4).docxCLASSROOM-PROGRAM-GRADE-4_-2022-2023 (4).docx
CLASSROOM-PROGRAM-GRADE-4_-2022-2023 (4).docx
 
DLL-ENGLISH-Q4-WEEK 3.pdf
DLL-ENGLISH-Q4-WEEK 3.pdfDLL-ENGLISH-Q4-WEEK 3.pdf
DLL-ENGLISH-Q4-WEEK 3.pdf
 
ESP 5 COT 2022.pptx
ESP 5 COT 2022.pptxESP 5 COT 2022.pptx
ESP 5 COT 2022.pptx
 
Pagpapalano ng masustansyang Pagkain
Pagpapalano ng masustansyang PagkainPagpapalano ng masustansyang Pagkain
Pagpapalano ng masustansyang Pagkain
 
MVTS Brigada Opening Program 2016
MVTS Brigada Opening Program 2016MVTS Brigada Opening Program 2016
MVTS Brigada Opening Program 2016
 
Araling Panlipunan 6 - MELC Updated
Araling Panlipunan 6 - MELC UpdatedAraling Panlipunan 6 - MELC Updated
Araling Panlipunan 6 - MELC Updated
 
Mga Kagawaran ng Sangay Tagapagpaganap
Mga Kagawaran ng Sangay TagapagpaganapMga Kagawaran ng Sangay Tagapagpaganap
Mga Kagawaran ng Sangay Tagapagpaganap
 
Mga pagdiriwang sa aking komunidad
Mga pagdiriwang sa aking komunidadMga pagdiriwang sa aking komunidad
Mga pagdiriwang sa aking komunidad
 
Filipino 3 Learner's Manual 2nd Quarter
Filipino 3 Learner's Manual 2nd  QuarterFilipino 3 Learner's Manual 2nd  Quarter
Filipino 3 Learner's Manual 2nd Quarter
 
Aralin 2 pagiging matiyaga uugaliin ko!
Aralin 2 pagiging matiyaga uugaliin ko!Aralin 2 pagiging matiyaga uugaliin ko!
Aralin 2 pagiging matiyaga uugaliin ko!
 
Jose ang batang magalang
Jose ang batang magalangJose ang batang magalang
Jose ang batang magalang
 
English 3 lm quarter 3
English 3 lm quarter 3English 3 lm quarter 3
English 3 lm quarter 3
 
Goalball
GoalballGoalball
Goalball
 
Pamilyar at Di-Pamilyar na Salita
Pamilyar at Di-Pamilyar na SalitaPamilyar at Di-Pamilyar na Salita
Pamilyar at Di-Pamilyar na Salita
 
The effect of mathematics anxiety on the achievement of middle school student...
The effect of mathematics anxiety on the achievement of middle school student...The effect of mathematics anxiety on the achievement of middle school student...
The effect of mathematics anxiety on the achievement of middle school student...
 

Similar a Redistributive Allocation Mechanisms

Social cost benefit analysis
Social cost benefit analysisSocial cost benefit analysis
Social cost benefit analysis
Bikramjit Singh
 
Social cost benefit analysis
Social cost benefit analysisSocial cost benefit analysis
Social cost benefit analysis
Neeti Gupta
 
1_Public_Finanace_Lectures_Part_1_ppt.ppt
1_Public_Finanace_Lectures_Part_1_ppt.ppt1_Public_Finanace_Lectures_Part_1_ppt.ppt
1_Public_Finanace_Lectures_Part_1_ppt.ppt
HenokFikadu4
 

Similar a Redistributive Allocation Mechanisms (20)

Slides.pdf
Slides.pdfSlides.pdf
Slides.pdf
 
Slides.pdf
Slides.pdfSlides.pdf
Slides.pdf
 
Social Cost Benefit Analysis
Social Cost Benefit AnalysisSocial Cost Benefit Analysis
Social Cost Benefit Analysis
 
I like scenarios
I like scenariosI like scenarios
I like scenarios
 
Social Cost Benefit Analysis - SCBA - Seminar by Mohan Kumar G
Social Cost Benefit Analysis - SCBA - Seminar by Mohan Kumar GSocial Cost Benefit Analysis - SCBA - Seminar by Mohan Kumar G
Social Cost Benefit Analysis - SCBA - Seminar by Mohan Kumar G
 
Social cost benefit analysis
Social cost benefit analysisSocial cost benefit analysis
Social cost benefit analysis
 
Social cost benefit analysis
Social cost benefit analysisSocial cost benefit analysis
Social cost benefit analysis
 
publicgoods.ppt
publicgoods.pptpublicgoods.ppt
publicgoods.ppt
 
Presentation on Microeconomics
Presentation on MicroeconomicsPresentation on Microeconomics
Presentation on Microeconomics
 
Social cost benefit analysis (scba)
Social cost benefit analysis (scba)Social cost benefit analysis (scba)
Social cost benefit analysis (scba)
 
Presentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfPresentation.pdf
Presentation.pdf
 
1_Public_Finanace_Lectures_Part_1_ppt.ppt
1_Public_Finanace_Lectures_Part_1_ppt.ppt1_Public_Finanace_Lectures_Part_1_ppt.ppt
1_Public_Finanace_Lectures_Part_1_ppt.ppt
 
Business Env. Lec4-1.pptx
Business Env. Lec4-1.pptxBusiness Env. Lec4-1.pptx
Business Env. Lec4-1.pptx
 
Project Management- Unit V
Project Management- Unit VProject Management- Unit V
Project Management- Unit V
 
Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments
Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environmentsEquity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments
Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments
 
Raj PPt
Raj PPtRaj PPt
Raj PPt
 
DPB 10013 MICROECONOMICS (INTRODUCTION)
DPB 10013 MICROECONOMICS (INTRODUCTION)DPB 10013 MICROECONOMICS (INTRODUCTION)
DPB 10013 MICROECONOMICS (INTRODUCTION)
 
Chapter 6
Chapter 6Chapter 6
Chapter 6
 
MBA Urban Farming Sample Business Plan
MBA Urban Farming Sample Business PlanMBA Urban Farming Sample Business Plan
MBA Urban Farming Sample Business Plan
 
Dr Darin Gunesekera at NASA -SU "Internet of Social Action" (ISA)
Dr Darin Gunesekera at NASA -SU "Internet of Social Action" (ISA)Dr Darin Gunesekera at NASA -SU "Internet of Social Action" (ISA)
Dr Darin Gunesekera at NASA -SU "Internet of Social Action" (ISA)
 

Más de GRAPE

Presentation_Yale.pdf
Presentation_Yale.pdfPresentation_Yale.pdf
Presentation_Yale.pdf
GRAPE
 
Presentation_Columbia.pdf
Presentation_Columbia.pdfPresentation_Columbia.pdf
Presentation_Columbia.pdf
GRAPE
 

Más de GRAPE (20)

Gender board diversity and firm performance
Gender board diversity and firm performanceGender board diversity and firm performance
Gender board diversity and firm performance
 
Gender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European data
Gender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European dataGender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European data
Gender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European data
 
Demographic transition and the rise of wealth inequality
Demographic transition and the rise of wealth inequalityDemographic transition and the rise of wealth inequality
Demographic transition and the rise of wealth inequality
 
(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality
(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality
(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality
 
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eyeGender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
 
Wage Inequality and women's self-employment
Wage Inequality and women's self-employmentWage Inequality and women's self-employment
Wage Inequality and women's self-employment
 
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)
 
Empathy in risky choices on behalf of others
Empathy in risky choices on behalf of othersEmpathy in risky choices on behalf of others
Empathy in risky choices on behalf of others
 
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences
Contracts with Interdependent PreferencesContracts with Interdependent Preferences
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences
 
Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...
Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...
Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...
 
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eyeGender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
 
The European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population aging
The European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population agingThe European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population aging
The European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population aging
 
ENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdf
ENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdfENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdf
ENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdf
 
POSTER_EARHART.pdf
POSTER_EARHART.pdfPOSTER_EARHART.pdf
POSTER_EARHART.pdf
 
Boston_College Slides.pdf
Boston_College Slides.pdfBoston_College Slides.pdf
Boston_College Slides.pdf
 
Presentation_Yale.pdf
Presentation_Yale.pdfPresentation_Yale.pdf
Presentation_Yale.pdf
 
Presentation_Columbia.pdf
Presentation_Columbia.pdfPresentation_Columbia.pdf
Presentation_Columbia.pdf
 
Presentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfPresentation.pdf
Presentation.pdf
 
Presentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfPresentation.pdf
Presentation.pdf
 
DDKT-Munich.pdf
DDKT-Munich.pdfDDKT-Munich.pdf
DDKT-Munich.pdf
 

Último

Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
amitlee9823
 
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
priyasharma62062
 
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
call girls in Sant Nagar (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953056974 🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Sant Nagar (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953056974 🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in Sant Nagar (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953056974 🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Sant Nagar (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953056974 🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
9953056974 Low Rate Call Girls In Saket, Delhi NCR
 
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men 🔝Malda🔝 Escorts Ser...
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men  🔝Malda🔝   Escorts Ser...➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men  🔝Malda🔝   Escorts Ser...
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men 🔝Malda🔝 Escorts Ser...
amitlee9823
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai Central 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Ever...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai Central 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Ever...VIP Call Girl in Mumbai Central 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Ever...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai Central 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Ever...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 

Último (20)

Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
 
Airport Road Best Experience Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 Santacruz MOst Es...
Airport Road Best Experience Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 Santacruz MOst Es...Airport Road Best Experience Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 Santacruz MOst Es...
Airport Road Best Experience Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 Santacruz MOst Es...
 
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
 
Toronto dominion bank investor presentation.pdf
Toronto dominion bank investor presentation.pdfToronto dominion bank investor presentation.pdf
Toronto dominion bank investor presentation.pdf
 
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
 
call girls in Sant Nagar (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953056974 🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Sant Nagar (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953056974 🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in Sant Nagar (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953056974 🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Sant Nagar (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953056974 🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
 
Technology industry / Finnish economic outlook
Technology industry / Finnish economic outlookTechnology industry / Finnish economic outlook
Technology industry / Finnish economic outlook
 
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
 
Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...
Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...
Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...
 
(INDIRA) Call Girl Srinagar Call Now 8617697112 Srinagar Escorts 24x7
(INDIRA) Call Girl Srinagar Call Now 8617697112 Srinagar Escorts 24x7(INDIRA) Call Girl Srinagar Call Now 8617697112 Srinagar Escorts 24x7
(INDIRA) Call Girl Srinagar Call Now 8617697112 Srinagar Escorts 24x7
 
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men 🔝Malda🔝 Escorts Ser...
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men  🔝Malda🔝   Escorts Ser...➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men  🔝Malda🔝   Escorts Ser...
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men 🔝Malda🔝 Escorts Ser...
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
 
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
 
Webinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech Belgium
Webinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech BelgiumWebinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech Belgium
Webinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech Belgium
 
cost-volume-profit analysis.ppt(managerial accounting).pptx
cost-volume-profit analysis.ppt(managerial accounting).pptxcost-volume-profit analysis.ppt(managerial accounting).pptx
cost-volume-profit analysis.ppt(managerial accounting).pptx
 
Lion One Corporate Presentation May 2024
Lion One Corporate Presentation May 2024Lion One Corporate Presentation May 2024
Lion One Corporate Presentation May 2024
 
Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques in Participating in Various Types...
Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques  in Participating in Various Types...Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques  in Participating in Various Types...
Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques in Participating in Various Types...
 
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai Central 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Ever...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai Central 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Ever...VIP Call Girl in Mumbai Central 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Ever...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai Central 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Ever...
 
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
 
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
 

Redistributive Allocation Mechanisms

  • 1. Redistributive Allocation Mechanisms (with an application to the potential European energy crisis) Mohammad Akbarpour r O Piotr Dworczak r O Scott Duke Kominers* (Stanford) (GRAPE & Northwestern) (Harvard) 22 November, 2022 European Central Bank, invited speaker seminar Research sponsored by ERC grant IMD-101040122. *Authors’ names are in certified random order.
  • 2. Motivation Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms, even though monetary transfers are feasible: Housing
  • 3. Motivation Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms, even though monetary transfers are feasible: Housing Health care
  • 4. Motivation Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms, even though monetary transfers are feasible: Housing Health care Food
  • 5. Motivation Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms, even though monetary transfers are feasible: Housing Health care Food Road access
  • 6. Motivation Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms, even though monetary transfers are feasible: Housing Health care Food Road access ...
  • 7. Motivation Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms, even though monetary transfers are feasible: Housing Health care Food Road access ... Follow-up paper: Covid-19 vaccines
  • 8. Motivation Many goods and services are allocated using non-market mechanisms, even though monetary transfers are feasible: Housing Health care Food Road access ... Follow-up paper: Covid-19 vaccines Focus today: Energy this winter in Europe
  • 9. Motivation—European energy crisis Source: Sgaravatti, G., S. Tagliapietra, G. Zachmann (2021) ‘National policies to shield consumers from rising energy prices’
  • 10. Motivation—European energy crisis Source: Sgaravatti, G., S. Tagliapietra, G. Zachmann (2021) ‘National policies to shield consumers from rising energy prices’
  • 11. Motivation—European energy crisis Source: Sgaravatti, G., S. Tagliapietra, G. Zachmann (2021) ‘National policies to shield consumers from rising energy prices’
  • 12. Motivation Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum payments (II WT)
  • 13. Motivation Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum payments (II WT) ▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152
  • 14. Motivation Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum payments (II WT) ▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152 But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information!
  • 15. Motivation Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum payments (II WT) ▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152 But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information! Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in practice:
  • 16. Motivation Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum payments (II WT) ▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152 But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information! Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in practice: ▶ Detailed financial situation?
  • 17. Motivation Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum payments (II WT) ▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152 But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information! Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in practice: ▶ Detailed financial situation? ▶ Job market opportunities?
  • 18. Motivation Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum payments (II WT) ▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152 But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information! Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in practice: ▶ Detailed financial situation? ▶ Job market opportunities? ▶ Exposure to interest rate hikes?
  • 19. Motivation Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum payments (II WT) ▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152 But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information! Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in practice: ▶ Detailed financial situation? ▶ Job market opportunities? ▶ Exposure to interest rate hikes? ▶ Energy efficiency of housing?
  • 20. Motivation Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum payments (II WT) ▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152 But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information! Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in practice: ▶ Detailed financial situation? ▶ Job market opportunities? ▶ Exposure to interest rate hikes? ▶ Energy efficiency of housing? ▶ Heating method?
  • 21. Motivation Classical economic perspective: Distorting prices will lead to inefficiency (I WT); if you want to redistribute, do so via lump-sum payments (II WT) ▶ echoed in The Economist on 08/09/2022 and IMF WP/22/152 But: Welfare theorems ignore the issue of private information! Governments do have some information... but far from perfect in practice: ▶ Detailed financial situation? ▶ Job market opportunities? ▶ Exposure to interest rate hikes? ▶ Energy efficiency of housing? ▶ Heating method? ▶ Family size?
  • 22. Inequality-aware Market Design Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal allocation under redistributive concerns (Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market)
  • 23. Inequality-aware Market Design Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal allocation under redistributive concerns (Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market) Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed and unobserved characteristics.
  • 24. Inequality-aware Market Design Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal allocation under redistributive concerns (Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market) Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed and unobserved characteristics. We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights.
  • 25. Inequality-aware Market Design Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal allocation under redistributive concerns (Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market) Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed and unobserved characteristics. We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights. Some key take-aways:
  • 26. Inequality-aware Market Design Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal allocation under redistributive concerns (Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market) Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed and unobserved characteristics. We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights. Some key take-aways: ▶ Non-market mechanisms can be optimal!
  • 27. Inequality-aware Market Design Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal allocation under redistributive concerns (Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market) Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed and unobserved characteristics. We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights. Some key take-aways: ▶ Non-market mechanisms can be optimal! ▶ If lump-sum payments are available, uniform price caps are never optimal;
  • 28. Inequality-aware Market Design Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal allocation under redistributive concerns (Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market) Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed and unobserved characteristics. We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights. Some key take-aways: ▶ Non-market mechanisms can be optimal! ▶ If lump-sum payments are available, uniform price caps are never optimal; ▶ Instead, price caps should only be applied up to some threshold consumption level;
  • 29. Inequality-aware Market Design Our approach: A market-design framework for determining the optimal allocation under redistributive concerns (Market-design perspective: the designer only controls a single market) Designer allocates a set of goods to agents differing in their observed and unobserved characteristics. We derive the optimal mechanism under IC and IR constraints and an objective that reflects redistributive concerns via welfare weights. Some key take-aways: ▶ Non-market mechanisms can be optimal! ▶ If lump-sum payments are available, uniform price caps are never optimal; ▶ Instead, price caps should only be applied up to some threshold consumption level; ▶ Uniform price caps can be optimal when lump-sum payments are costly;
  • 30. Literature Weitzman (1977): First paper to point out that random allocation might be preferred to market pricing when agents’ “needs” are not well expressed by willingness to pay. Condorelli (2013): A full mechanism-design approach to Weitzman’s problem ▶ On a technical level: We add heterogeneous quality of objects, continuum of goods and agents, groups of agents with the same observable characteristics, and designer’s preferences over revenue. ▶ On a conceptual level: We focus on a particular objective function (weighted sum of utilities and revenue) and connect market circumstances with practical conclusions about the optimal design. Dworczak r O Kominers r O Akbarpour (2021): two-sided market but “maximally simplified” (no heterogeneous quality, no observable information, no restrictions on lump-sum transfers)
  • 31. Literature Price control, public provision of goods: Nichols and Zeckhauser (1982), Besley and Coate (1991), Blackorby and Donaldson (1988), Viscusi, Harrington, and Vernon (2005), Gahvari and Mattos (2007), Currie and Gahvari (2008) Optimal taxation: Diamond and Mirrlees (1971), Atkinson and Stiglitz (1976), Akerlof (1978), Saez and Stantcheva (2016) Auctions with budget-constrained bidders: Che and Gale (1998), Fernandez and Gali (1999); Che, Gale, and Kim (2012); Pai and Vohra (2014); Kotowski (2017) Costly-screening/ money-burning literature: McAfee and McMillan (1992), Damiano and Li (2007), Hartline and Roughgarden (2008), Hoppe, Moldovanu, and Sela (2009), Condorelli (2012), Chakravarty and Kaplan (2013) Methods (generalized ironing): Muir and Loertscher (2021), Ashlagi, Monachou, and Nikzad (2021), Kleiner, Moldovanu, and Strack (2021), Z. Kang (2020a). New threads in mechanism design with redistribution motives: Z. Kang (2020b), M. Kang and Zheng (2020, 2021), Reuter and Groh (2021)
  • 33. Model A designer chooses a mechanism to allocate a unit mass of objects to a unit mass of agents. Each object has quality q ∈ [0, 1], q is distributed acc. to cdf F. Each agent is characterized by a type (i, r, λ), where: i is an observable label, i ∈ I (finite); r is an unobserved willingness to pay (for quality), r ∈ R+; λ is an unobserved social welfare weight, λ ∈ R+; The type distribution is known to the designer. If (i, r, λ) gets a good with quality q and pays t, her utility is qr − t, while her contribution to social welfare is λ(qr − t)
  • 34. Model Comments for the energy context: Quality normalized to 0 or 1, interpreted as quantity. Then, q = 1 can be interpreted as the “normal consumption level.” Instead of distribution of quality F, we just have total quantity S available: F(q) = 1{q≥S}. Throughout, assume that S < 1. To the extent that some households have a higher “normal consumption level,” we can (intuitively) fold it into the WTP r r · qnormal = rqnormal | {z } r̃ · 1
  • 35. Model The designer has access to arbitrary (direct) allocation mechanisms (Γ, T) where Γ(q|i, r, λ) is the probability that (i, r, λ) gets a good with quality q or less, and T(i, r, λ) is the associated payment, subject to: Feasibility: E(i,r,λ) [Γ(q|i, r, λ)] ≥ F(q), ∀q ∈ [0, 1]; IC constraint: Each agent (i, r, λ) reports (r, λ) truthfully; IR constraint: U(i, r, λ) ≡ r R qdΓ(q|i, r, λ) − T(i, r, λ) ≥ 0; Non-negative transfers: T(i, r, λ) ≥ 0, ∀(i, r, λ). The designer maximizes, for some constant α ≥ 0, a weighted sum of revenue and agents’ utilities: E(i,r,λ) [αT(i, r, λ) + λU(i, r, λ)] .
  • 36. Comments about the model Lemma: It is without loss of optimality for the mechanism designer to only elicit information about r through the mechanism—allocation and transfers depend on (i, r) but not on λ directly.
  • 37. Comments about the model Lemma: It is without loss of optimality for the mechanism designer to only elicit information about r through the mechanism—allocation and transfers depend on (i, r) but not on λ directly. This implies that the designer forms expectations over the unobserved social welfare weights: λi(r) ≡ E(i,r,λ) [λ| i, r] ; we call these functions Pareto weights, and assume they are continuous.
  • 38. Comments about the model Lemma: It is without loss of optimality for the mechanism designer to only elicit information about r through the mechanism—allocation and transfers depend on (i, r) but not on λ directly. This implies that the designer forms expectations over the unobserved social welfare weights: λi(r) ≡ E(i,r,λ) [λ| i, r] ; we call these functions Pareto weights, and assume they are continuous. Designer’s objective becomes: E(i,r) [αTi(r) + λi(r)Ui(r)] .
  • 39. Comments about the model λi(r) ≡ E(i,r,λ) [λ| i, r] Economic idea: The designer assesses the “need” of agents by estimating the unobserved welfare weights based on the observable (label i) and elicitable (wtp r) information.
  • 40. Comments about the model λi(r) ≡ E(i,r,λ) [λ| i, r] Economic idea: The designer assesses the “need” of agents by estimating the unobserved welfare weights based on the observable (label i) and elicitable (wtp r) information. Consequence: The optimal allocation depends on the statistical correlation of labels and willingness to pay with the unobserved social welfare weights.
  • 41. Comments about the model Correlation of labels with welfare weights: If label i captures income brackets, then we may naturally think that E[λ| i] ≡ λ̄i ≥ λ̄j ≡ E[λ| j] if i corresponds to a lower income bracket than j;
  • 42. Comments about the model Correlation of labels with welfare weights: If label i captures income brackets, then we may naturally think that E[λ| i] ≡ λ̄i ≥ λ̄j ≡ E[λ| j] if i corresponds to a lower income bracket than j; Other possibilities (varies by country): Labels could capture family size, energy efficiency of housing, heating method, exposure to interest rate hikes.
  • 43. Comments about the model Correlation of WTP with welfare weights: Suppose there is just one label I = {i}, but we elicit information about willingness to pay of two patients for a treatment: Agent A: e50,000 Agent B: e1,000 Naturally, we may presume that λi(r) is decreasing in r.
  • 44. Comments about the model Correlation of WTP with welfare weights: Many labels, i captures low income, and we elicit information about willingness to pay of two patients for a treatment: Agent A: e 50,000 Agent B: e1,000 Naturally, we may presume that λi(r) is (“less”) decreasing in r.
  • 45. Comments about the model Correlation of WTP with welfare weights: Suppose there is just one label I = {i}, but we elicit information about WTP of two consumers for maintaining “normal” energy consumption: Agent A: $10,000 Agent B: $5,000 Naturally, we may presume that λi(r) is decreasing in r.
  • 46. Comments about the model Correlation of WTP with welfare weights: Many labels, i captures family size and energy efficiency, but we elicit information about WTP of two consumers for maintaining “normal” energy consumption: Agent A: $10,000 Agent B: $5,000 Naturally, we may presume that λi(r) is (“more”) decreasing in r.
  • 47. Comments about the model The role of revenue: The weight α on revenue captures the value of a dollar in the designer’s budget, spent on the most valuable “cause.”
  • 48. Comments about the model The role of revenue: The weight α on revenue captures the value of a dollar in the designer’s budget, spent on the most valuable “cause.” When α = maxi λ̄i, then it is as if a lump-sum transfer to group i were allowed; when α = averagei λ̄i, then it is as if lump-sum transfers to all agents were allowed.
  • 49. Comments about the model The role of revenue: The weight α on revenue captures the value of a dollar in the designer’s budget, spent on the most valuable “cause.” When α = maxi λ̄i, then it is as if a lump-sum transfer to group i were allowed; when α = averagei λ̄i, then it is as if lump-sum transfers to all agents were allowed. When α > λ̄i for all i, there is an “outside cause”.
  • 50. Comments about the model The role of revenue: The weight α on revenue captures the value of a dollar in the designer’s budget, spent on the most valuable “cause.” When α = maxi λ̄i, then it is as if a lump-sum transfer to group i were allowed; when α = averagei λ̄i, then it is as if lump-sum transfers to all agents were allowed. When α > λ̄i for all i, there is an “outside cause”. When α < λ̄i for some i, lump-sum payments to agents in group i are prohibited or costly (insurance motive as in Gadenne et al., 2022).
  • 51. Comments about the model The role of revenue: The weight α on revenue captures the value of a dollar in the designer’s budget, spent on the most valuable “cause.” When α = maxi λ̄i, then it is as if a lump-sum transfer to group i were allowed; when α = averagei λ̄i, then it is as if lump-sum transfers to all agents were allowed. When α > λ̄i for all i, there is an “outside cause”. When α < λ̄i for some i, lump-sum payments to agents in group i are prohibited or costly (insurance motive as in Gadenne et al., 2022). When α = 0, we are in the money-burning/costly-screening case.
  • 52. Comments about the model Universally desired goods
  • 53. Comments about the model Universally desired goods Let Gi(r) be the cdf of willingness to pay conditional on label i, and let gi(r) be its continuous positive density on [ri, r̄i].
  • 54. Comments about the model Universally desired goods Let Gi(r) be the cdf of willingness to pay conditional on label i, and let gi(r) be its continuous positive density on [ri, r̄i]. We call the good universally desired (for group i) if ri > 0.
  • 55. Comments about the model Universally desired goods Let Gi(r) be the cdf of willingness to pay conditional on label i, and let gi(r) be its continuous positive density on [ri, r̄i]. We call the good universally desired (for group i) if ri > 0. Interpretation: A vast majority of agents have a willingness to pay that is bounded away from zero.
  • 56. Comments about the model Universally desired goods Let Gi(r) be the cdf of willingness to pay conditional on label i, and let gi(r) be its continuous positive density on [ri, r̄i]. We call the good universally desired (for group i) if ri > 0. Interpretation: A vast majority of agents have a willingness to pay that is bounded away from zero. Examples: “Essential” goods: housing, energy, food, basic health care;
  • 57. Comments about the model Universally desired goods Let Gi(r) be the cdf of willingness to pay conditional on label i, and let gi(r) be its continuous positive density on [ri, r̄i]. We call the good universally desired (for group i) if ri > 0. Interpretation: A vast majority of agents have a willingness to pay that is bounded away from zero. Examples: “Essential” goods: housing, energy, food, basic health care; “Stores of value”: shares, currencies, commodities
  • 58. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism Derivation of Optimal Mechanism
  • 59. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism 1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆ i ;
  • 60. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism 1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆ i ; 2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects F⋆ i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details
  • 61. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism 1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆ i ; 2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects F⋆ i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details
  • 62. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism 1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆ i ; 2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects F⋆ i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details Observation: Only expected quality, Qi(r), matters for payoffs.
  • 63. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism 1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆ i ; 2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects F⋆ i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details Observation: Only expected quality, Qi(r), matters for payoffs. Result: Within a group, agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP, with either the “market” or “non-market” allocation in each interval
  • 64. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism 1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆ i ; 2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects F⋆ i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details Observation: Only expected quality, Qi(r), matters for payoffs. Result: Within a group, agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP, with either the “market” or “non-market” allocation in each interval Market allocation: assortative matching between WTP and quality Qi(r) = (F⋆ i )−1 (Gi(r)), ∀r ∈ [a, b];
  • 65. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism 1 Objects are allocated “across” groups: F is split into I cdfs F⋆ i ; 2 Objects are allocated “within” groups: For each label i, the objects F⋆ i are allocated optimally to agents in group i. Details Observation: Only expected quality, Qi(r), matters for payoffs. Result: Within a group, agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP, with either the “market” or “non-market” allocation in each interval Market allocation: assortative matching between WTP and quality Qi(r) = (F⋆ i )−1 (Gi(r)), ∀r ∈ [a, b]; Non-market allocation: random matching (rationing!) between WTP and quality Qi(r) = q̄, ∀r ∈ [a, b].
  • 66. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
  • 67. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
  • 68. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
  • 69. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
  • 70. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
  • 71. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
  • 72. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: within-group allocation
  • 73. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 74. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 75. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 76. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 77. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 78. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 79. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 80. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 81. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 82. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 83. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 84. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 85. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 86. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 87. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 88. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 89. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 90. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 91. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 92. Derivation of Optimal Mechanism: across-group allocation
  • 94. Economic Implications Proposition 1 (WTP-revealed inequality ) Suppose that α ≥ λ̄i (lump-sum payments are available).
  • 95. Economic Implications Proposition 1 (WTP-revealed inequality ) Suppose that α ≥ λ̄i (lump-sum payments are available). Then, it is optimal to ration agents with willingness to pay in some (non-degenerate) interval if and only if the function αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is not non-decreasing, where hi(r) = 1 − Gi(r) gi(r) , Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei [λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r].
  • 96. Economic Implications Proposition 1 (WTP-revealed inequality ) Suppose that α ≥ λ̄i (lump-sum payments are available). Then, it is optimal to ration agents with willingness to pay in some (non-degenerate) interval if and only if the function αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is not non-decreasing, where hi(r) = 1 − Gi(r) gi(r) , Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei [λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r]. Assuming differentiability, the condition becomes Λ′ i(r)hi(r) + α + (Λi(r) − α)h′ i(r) < 0.
  • 97. Economic Implications Proposition 1 (WTP-revealed inequality ) Suppose that α ≥ λ̄i (lump-sum payments are available). Then, it is optimal to ration agents with willingness to pay in some (non-degenerate) interval if and only if the function αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is not non-decreasing, where hi(r) = 1 − Gi(r) gi(r) , Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei [λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r]. Assuming differentiability, the condition becomes Λ′ i(r)hi(r) + α + (Λi(r) − α)h′ i(r) < 0. Some non-market allocation is optimal if willingness to pay is strongly (negatively) correlated with the unobserved social welfare weights.
  • 98. Economic Implications Proposition 2 (Optimality of uniform rationing) A necessary condition for uniform rationing (at a fixed low price) to be optimal within group i is that αr̄i ≤ Z r̄i ri rλi(r)dGi(r). This condition becomes sufficient if αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is quasi-convex.
  • 99. Economic Implications Proposition 2 (Optimality of uniform rationing) A necessary condition for uniform rationing (at a fixed low price) to be optimal within group i is that αr̄i ≤ Z r̄i ri rλi(r)dGi(r). This condition becomes sufficient if αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is quasi-convex. Key take-away: It is never optimal to use uniform rationing if a lump-sum payment to group i is feasible.
  • 100. Economic Implications Proposition 2 (Optimality of uniform rationing) A necessary condition for uniform rationing (at a fixed low price) to be optimal within group i is that αr̄i ≤ Z r̄i ri rλi(r)dGi(r). This condition becomes sufficient if αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r) is quasi-convex. Key take-away: It is never optimal to use uniform rationing if a lump-sum payment to group i is feasible. By an extension of the same argument: It is never optimal to have a uniform price cap.
  • 101. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for vulnerable households.
  • 102. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for vulnerable households. Each household chooses between a high per-unit price with no limit on consumption or a lower per-unit price but up to a consumption threshold q̄ < 1.
  • 103. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for vulnerable households. Each household chooses between a high per-unit price with no limit on consumption or a lower per-unit price but up to a consumption threshold q̄ < 1. Selection will be based on WTP.
  • 104. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for vulnerable households. Each household chooses between a high per-unit price with no limit on consumption or a lower per-unit price but up to a consumption threshold q̄ < 1. Selection will be based on WTP. Key question: Do we get the “right” selection?
  • 105. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for vulnerable households. Each household chooses between a high per-unit price with no limit on consumption or a lower per-unit price but up to a consumption threshold q̄ < 1. Selection will be based on WTP. Key question: Do we get the “right” selection? If yes, subsidize (by reducing the per-unit price) the group that self-identified as being in need.
  • 106. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Offering a reduced-price option with rationing allows to screen for vulnerable households. Each household chooses between a high per-unit price with no limit on consumption or a lower per-unit price but up to a consumption threshold q̄ < 1. Selection will be based on WTP. Key question: Do we get the “right” selection? If yes, subsidize (by reducing the per-unit price) the group that self-identified as being in need. If no, then the rationing policy is pure allocative inefficiency.
  • 107. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: The answer to the question largely depends on available labels!
  • 108. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: The answer to the question largely depends on available labels! Mathematically, we need strong negative correlation between WTP and welfare weights (Λ′ i(r) < 0)
  • 109. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: The answer to the question largely depends on available labels! Mathematically, we need strong negative correlation between WTP and welfare weights (Λ′ i(r) < 0) This might hold when we control for confounding factors that wold raise the WTP of poor households:
  • 110. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: The answer to the question largely depends on available labels! Mathematically, we need strong negative correlation between WTP and welfare weights (Λ′ i(r) < 0) This might hold when we control for confounding factors that wold raise the WTP of poor households: ▶ Large family size;
  • 111. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: The answer to the question largely depends on available labels! Mathematically, we need strong negative correlation between WTP and welfare weights (Λ′ i(r) < 0) This might hold when we control for confounding factors that wold raise the WTP of poor households: ▶ Large family size; ▶ Energy inefficiency of housing;
  • 112. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: The answer to the question largely depends on available labels! Mathematically, we need strong negative correlation between WTP and welfare weights (Λ′ i(r) < 0) This might hold when we control for confounding factors that wold raise the WTP of poor households: ▶ Large family size; ▶ Energy inefficiency of housing; ▶ Electricity-based heating.
  • 113. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum payments: Additional screening!
  • 114. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum payments: Additional screening! Market choices may reveal which households are really in need.
  • 115. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum payments: Additional screening! Market choices may reveal which households are really in need. Then, clear why uniform price and quantity caps can’t work!
  • 116. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum payments: Additional screening! Market choices may reveal which households are really in need. Then, clear why uniform price and quantity caps can’t work! They distort economic efficiency without offering the screening benefit.
  • 117. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum payments: Additional screening! Market choices may reveal which households are really in need. Then, clear why uniform price and quantity caps can’t work! They distort economic efficiency without offering the screening benefit. Thus, they are dominated by lump-sum payments (here, we agree with the Economist and the IMF paper)
  • 118. Economic Implications Key idea behind optimality of rationing: Advantage of consumption-capped price subsidy over lump-sum payments: Additional screening! Market choices may reveal which households are really in need. Then, clear why uniform price and quantity caps can’t work! They distort economic efficiency without offering the screening benefit. Thus, they are dominated by lump-sum payments (here, we agree with the Economist and the IMF paper) What if lump-sum payments are costly? (administration costs, insurance motive, behavioral aspects, etc.)
  • 119. Economic Implications Proposition 3 (Label-revealed inequality ) Suppose that the average Pareto weight λ̄i for group i is strictly larger than the weight on revenue α; the good is universally desired (ri > 0). Then, there exists r⋆ i > ri such that the optimal allocation is to ration (at a price of 0) all types r ≤ r⋆ i .
  • 120. Economic Implications Proposition 3 (Label-revealed inequality ) Suppose that the average Pareto weight λ̄i for group i is strictly larger than the weight on revenue α; the good is universally desired (ri > 0). Then, there exists r⋆ i > ri such that the optimal allocation is to ration (at a price of 0) all types r ≤ r⋆ i . Interpretation: If the designer would like to redistribute to group i but cannot give agents in that group a direct cash transfer, then it is optimal to provide small quantities of universally desired goods for free.
  • 121. Economic Implications Proposition 3 (Label-revealed inequality ) Suppose that the average Pareto weight λ̄i for group i is strictly larger than the weight on revenue α; the good is universally desired (ri > 0). Then, there exists r⋆ i > ri such that the optimal allocation is to ration (at a price of 0) all types r ≤ r⋆ i . Interpretation: If the designer would like to redistribute to group i but cannot give agents in that group a direct cash transfer, then it is optimal to provide small quantities of universally desired goods for free. Note: There might still be a price gradient for higher quantities (the exact condition is the one we have seen before)
  • 122. Economic Implications Proposition 1 (Label-revealed inequality ) Suppose that the average Pareto weight λ̄i for group i is strictly larger than the weight on revenue α; the good is universally desired (ri > 0). Then, there exists r⋆ i > ri such that the optimal allocation is to ration (at a price of 0) all types r ≤ r⋆ i . “Wrong” intuition: A random allocation for free increases the welfare of agents with lowest willingness to pay
  • 123. Economic Implications Proposition 1 (Label-revealed inequality ) Suppose that the average Pareto weight λ̄i for group i is strictly larger than the weight on revenue α; the good is universally desired (ri > 0). Then, there exists r⋆ i > ri such that the optimal allocation is to ration (at a price of 0) all types r ≤ r⋆ i . “Wrong” intuition: A random allocation for free increases the welfare of agents with lowest willingness to pay Correct Intuition: A random allocation for free enables the designer to lower prices for all agents Picture
  • 125. Conclusions When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a below-market-clearing prices)
  • 126. Conclusions When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a below-market-clearing prices) Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved welfare weights.
  • 127. Conclusions When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a below-market-clearing prices) Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved welfare weights. 1 Label-revealed inequality:
  • 128. Conclusions When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a below-market-clearing prices) Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved welfare weights. 1 Label-revealed inequality: When lump-sum payments are costly and some groups can be identified as vulnerable, it is optimal to use some in-kind redistribution for universally desired goods.
  • 129. Conclusions When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a below-market-clearing prices) Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved welfare weights. 1 Label-revealed inequality: When lump-sum payments are costly and some groups can be identified as vulnerable, it is optimal to use some in-kind redistribution for universally desired goods. ▶ Energy context: Controlling electricity bills for poorest households may be easier/ cheaper than direct cash transfers.
  • 130. Conclusions When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a below-market-clearing prices) Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved welfare weights. 1 Label-revealed inequality: When lump-sum payments are costly and some groups can be identified as vulnerable, it is optimal to use some in-kind redistribution for universally desired goods. ▶ Energy context: Controlling electricity bills for poorest households may be easier/ cheaper than direct cash transfers. 2 WTP-revealed inequality: When welfare weights are strongly and negatively correlated with willingness to pay conditional on labels.
  • 131. Conclusions When to use in-kind redistribution? (provision of goods at a below-market-clearing prices) Roughly: When observable variables uncover inequality in the unobserved welfare weights. 1 Label-revealed inequality: When lump-sum payments are costly and some groups can be identified as vulnerable, it is optimal to use some in-kind redistribution for universally desired goods. ▶ Energy context: Controlling electricity bills for poorest households may be easier/ cheaper than direct cash transfers. 2 WTP-revealed inequality: When welfare weights are strongly and negatively correlated with willingness to pay conditional on labels. ▶ Energy context: A well-designed subsidy system can screen for most vulnerable households, better than a cash transfer scheme could.
  • 132. Conclusions We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design.
  • 133. Conclusions We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design. Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors:
  • 134. Conclusions We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design. Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors: 1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the information that the designer can elicit or observe directly;
  • 135. Conclusions We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design. Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors: 1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the information that the designer can elicit or observe directly; 2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers;
  • 136. Conclusions We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design. Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors: 1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the information that the designer can elicit or observe directly; 2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers; 3 Whether the good is universally desired or not.
  • 137. Conclusions We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design. Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors: 1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the information that the designer can elicit or observe directly; 2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers; 3 Whether the good is universally desired or not. More work is needed on market design with redistributive concerns:
  • 138. Conclusions We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design. Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors: 1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the information that the designer can elicit or observe directly; 2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers; 3 Whether the good is universally desired or not. More work is needed on market design with redistributive concerns: 1 There are hundreds (thousands?) of theory papers focusing on how to maximize revenue or efficiency when allocating resources...
  • 139. Conclusions We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design. Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors: 1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the information that the designer can elicit or observe directly; 2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers; 3 Whether the good is universally desired or not. More work is needed on market design with redistributive concerns: 1 There are hundreds (thousands?) of theory papers focusing on how to maximize revenue or efficiency when allocating resources... 2 ... but only a handful on how to achieve optimal redistribution.
  • 140. Conclusions We proposed a model of Inequality-aware Market Design. Our analysis uncovers the importance of three factors: 1 Correlation between the unobserved welfare weights and the information that the designer can elicit or observe directly; 2 Importance of availability of lump-sum transfers; 3 Whether the good is universally desired or not. More work is needed on market design with redistributive concerns: 1 There are hundreds (thousands?) of theory papers focusing on how to maximize revenue or efficiency when allocating resources... 2 ... but only a handful on how to achieve optimal redistribution. 3 Much more work remains to be done... (many stylized assumptions in our model!)
  • 148. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The “within-group” problem: Fixing a group of agents i, and a distribution of quality Fi available for group i, what is the optimal way to allocate quality subject to IC and IR constraints?
  • 149. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality) max Qi(r), Ui(ri) Z r̄i ri Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + (λ̄i − α)Ui(ri)
  • 150. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality) max Qi(r) Z r̄i ri Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri).
  • 151. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality) max Qi(r) Z r̄i ri Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri). In the above, Vi(r) = αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r), where hi(r) = 1 − Gi(r) gi(r) , Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei [λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r].
  • 152. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality) max Qi(r) Z r̄i ri Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri). In the above, Vi(r) = αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r), where hi(r) = 1 − Gi(r) gi(r) , Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei [λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r]. Feasible distribution of expected quality: CDF Φi such that Fi ≻MPS Φi.
  • 153. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality) max Qi(r) Z r̄i ri Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri). In the above, Vi(r) = αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r), where hi(r) = 1 − Gi(r) gi(r) , Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei [λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r]. Feasible distribution of expected quality: CDF Φi such that Fi ≻MPS Φi. Incentive-compatibility =⇒ Gi(r) = Φi(q)
  • 154. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality) max Qi(r) Z r̄i ri Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri). In the above, Vi(r) = αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r), where hi(r) = 1 − Gi(r) gi(r) , Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei [λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r]. Feasible distribution of expected quality: CDF Φi such that Fi ≻MPS Φi. Incentive-compatibility =⇒ Qi(r) = Φ−1 i (Gi(r))
  • 155. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem: (Qi(r) denotes expected quality) max Qi(r) Z r̄i ri Vi(r)Qi(r)dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riQi(ri). In the above, Vi(r) = αJi(r) + Λi(r)hi(r), where hi(r) = 1 − Gi(r) gi(r) , Ji(r) = r − hi(r), Λi(r) = Ei [λi(r̃) | r̃ ≥ r]. Feasible distribution of expected quality: CDF Φi such that Φ−1 i ≻MPS F−1 i . Incentive-compatibility =⇒ Qi(r) = Φ−1 i (Gi(r))
  • 156. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem is max Ψi Z r̄i ri Vi(r)Ψi(Gi(r))dGi(r) + max{0, λ̄i − α}riΨi(0) s.t. Ψi ≻MPS F−1 i Back
  • 157. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem is max Ψi Z 1 0 Vi(t) z }| { Z 1 t Vi(G−1 i (x))dx + max{0, λ̄i − α}ri1{t=0} dΨi(t) s.t. Ψi ≻MPS F−1 i Back
  • 158. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem is max Ψi Z 1 0 Vi(t) z }| { Z 1 t Vi(G−1 i (x))dx + max{0, λ̄i − α}ri1{t=0} dΨi(t) s.t. Ψi ≻MPS F−1 i Agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP: Back
  • 159. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem is max Ψi Z 1 0 Vi(t) z }| { Z 1 t Vi(G−1 i (x))dx + max{0, λ̄i − α}ri1{t=0} dΨi(t) s.t. Ψi ≻MPS F−1 i Agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP: ▶ Market allocation: assortative matching between WTP and quality Qi(r) = F−1 i (Gi(r)), ∀r ∈ [a, b]; Back
  • 160. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem is max Ψi Z 1 0 Vi(t) z }| { Z 1 t Vi(G−1 i (x))dx + max{0, λ̄i − α}ri1{t=0} dΨi(t) s.t. Ψi ≻MPS F−1 i Agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP: ▶ Market allocation: assortative matching between WTP and quality Qi(r) = F−1 i (Gi(r)), ∀r ∈ [a, b]; ▶ Non-market allocation: random matching between WTP and quality Qi(r) = q̄, ∀r ∈ [a, b]. Back
  • 161. Derivation of the optimal “within-group” mechanism The designer’s problem is max Ψi, F̃i Z 1 0 Vi(t) z }| { Z 1 t Vi(G−1 i (x))dx + max{0, λ̄i − α}ri1{t=0} dΨi(t) s.t. Ψi ≻MPS F̃−1 i ≻FOSD F−1 i Agents are partitioned into intervals according to WTP: ▶ Market allocation: assortative matching between WTP and quality Qi(r) = F−1 i (Gi(r)), ∀r ∈ [a, b]; ▶ Non-market allocation: random matching between WTP and quality Qi(r) = q̄, ∀r ∈ [a, b]. Back