SlideShare una empresa de Scribd logo
1 de 9
Descargar para leer sin conexión
Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1–9
                                                                                            www.elsevier.com / locate / econbase



   The ‘New Keynesian’ Phillips curve: closed economy versus
                       open economy
                                         Assaf Razin a , Chi-Wa Yuen b , *
                    a
                     Tel Aviv University, Cornell University, NBER, CEPR, and CES-Ifo, Tel Aviv, Israel
           b
               School of Economics and Finance, University of Hong Kong, Pokfulam Road, Hong Kong, China

                                        Received 27 May 2001; accepted 6 June 2001




Abstract

   The paper extends Woodford’s [Optimizing models with nominal rigidities, Chapter 3 of Interest and prices:
foundations of a theory of monetary policy, Princeton University, 2000; unpublished manuscript] analysis of the
closed economy Phillips curve to an open economy with both commodity trade and capital mobility. We show
that consumption smoothing, which comes with the opening of the capital market, raises the degree of strategic
complementarity among monopolistically competitive suppliers, thus rendering prices more sticky and
magnifying output responses to nominal GDP shocks. © 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Phillips curve; New Keynesian; Trade; Capital mobility

JEL classification: E12; F41




1. Introduction

   In this paper, we examine how open market policies would interact with the degree of price rigidity
in the domestic economy to affect the output-inflation tradeoffs as well as the volatilities of output and
inflation in response to nominal shocks. The analysis will be conducted in an optimization-based
‘New Keynesian’ framework a la Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987). In the discussion, we extend to an
open-trade-account and open-capital-account economy the succinct exposition of Woodford (2000)
conducted in the context of a closed economy. [For a useful survey of the new open economy
macroeconomic approach we adopt for our analysis in this paper, see Lane (2001).]
   Why is such extension potentially useful? Empirically, Loungani et al. (2001) have found that
countries with greater restrictions on capital mobility tend to have steeper Phillips curves. Evidently,

  * Corresponding author. Tel.: 1852-2859-1051; fax: 1852-2548-1152.
  E-mail address: cwyuen@econ.khu.hk (C.-W. Yuen).

0165-1765 / 02 / $ – see front matter   © 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
PII: S0165-1765( 01 )00588-2
2                                                 A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9

the degree of price stickiness is related to the organization of markets — for instance, whether the
labor market is common or segmented. Similarly, the degree of price stickiness can be affected by the
openness of the economy in both commodity trade and capital flows.


2. The analytical framework

   Consider a small open economy with a representative household that is endowed with a continuum
of goods-specific skills — uniformly distributed on the unit interval [0, n] — to be supplied to a
differentiated product industry. As a consumer, the representative household has access to consump-
tion of both domestic goods (distributed on [0, n]) and foreign goods (distributed on (n, 1]). The
household seeks to maximize a discounted sum of expected utilities:
                                                               n

           O b [u(C , M /P ; j ) 2E v(h ( j); j ) dj]
            `
                      t
      E0                    t         t       t        t               t          t
           t 50
                                                               0

where b is the subjective discount factor, C is the Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) index of household
consumption, P the Dixit–Stiglitz price index, M /P the demand for real balances, j a preference
shock, and h( j) the supply of type-j labor to the production of good of variety j. Like Obstfeld and
Rogoff (1996), we define the consumption index and its corresponding price index, respectively, as
                  n                                        1                                  u / (u 21 )

      Ct 5
                3E0
                            (
                                                 t         E
                      c t ( j) u 21 ) / u dj 1 c * ( j)(u 21 ) / u dj
                                                           n
                                                                                          4
and
                  n                                1                                      1 / (12u )

      Pt 5
                5E0
                      pt ( j)
                                12u
                                                 tE
                                      dj 1 [´t p * ( j)]
                                                   n
                                                                           12u
                                                                                 dj
                                                                                      6                                             (1)


where c( j) represents domestic consumption of the jth domestically produced good, c*( j) domestic
consumption of the jth foreign-produced good, p( j) the domestic-currency price of c( j), p*( j) the
foreign-currency price of c*( j), ´ the nominal exchange rate (domestic-currency price of foreign
currency), u . 1 the elasticity of substitution among the different goods, and n the fraction of goods
that are produced domestically.
   In nominal terms, the budget constraint facing the household is given by:
      n                                       1

      E p ( j)c ( j) dj 1 ´ E p*( j)c*( j) dj 1S]]DM 1 B 1 ´ B *
            t         t                   t
                                              n
                                                 i
                                                11i    t           t
                                                                                              t

                                                                                                  t
                                                                                                            t       t   t   t
      0
                                                                                                                n               n

                                                       *      *
           5 Mt21 1 (1 1 i t 21 )Bt 21 1 ft21,t (1 1 i t21 )B t21 1 w t ( j)h t ( j) dj 1 Pt ( j) dj            E               E
                                                                                                                0               0

where B is the domestic-currency value of domestic borrowing, B* the foreign-currency value of
A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9                        3

foreign borrowing, ft21,t the forward exchange rate for foreign currencies purchased / sold at time t 2 1
for delivery at time t, i and i* the domestic and foreign interest rates, w( j) the wage rate per unit labor
of type j, and P ( j) profit income from firms of type j. With perfect capital mobility, covered interest
parity prevails:

     1 1 i t 5 (1 1 i t* ) ]] S D
                           ft,t11
                              ´t
[cf. first-order conditions of the household with respect to B and B*.]
   From this point on, we shall focus on the relation between aggregate supply of goods and
consumption smoothing made possible by international capital mobility. For this purpose, we would
not be concerned about the details of aggregate demand (including the demand for money),
international commodity trade, and the determination of the exchange rate. For simplicity, consumer
utility is assumed to be separable between consumption and real money balances.
   For our purpose, the relevant utility-maximizing conditions include an intratemporal condition for
the choice of labor supply of type j:
     vh (h t ( j); j t ) w t ( j)
     ]]]] 5 ]]                                                                                                     (2)
      u c (Ct ; j t )      Pt

and an intertemporal condition for the consumption-saving choice:
         u c (Ct ; j t )
     ]]]]] 5 b (1 1 r*)                                                                                            (3)
     u c (Ct11 ; j t11 )
where r* is the world real rate of interest, assumed for simplicity to be time-invariant. This latter
equality is a consequence of the covered interest parity and the Fisher equation. As in the Dixit and
Stiglitz (1977) model, demand for good j satisfies

                   S D
                   pt ( j)
     c t ( j) 5 Ct ]]
                     Pt
                                  2u
                                                                                                                   (4)

  The production function assumes the form
     y t ( j) 5 A t f(h t ( j))
                                                                                                  21
where A is a random productivity shock. The variable cost of supplying y t ( j) is w t ( j)f           ( y t ( j) /A t ),
which implies a (real) marginal cost of
                             w t ( j)
     s t ( j) 5 ]]]]]]]
                Pt A t f 9( f 21 ( y t ( j) /A t ))

Using Eq. (2), we can replace the real wage above by the marginal rate of substitution. Imposing
symmetry across firms (so that we can drop the index j), the above equation can be rewritten as

                            vh ( f 21 ( y /A); j )
     s( y, C; j , A) 5 ]]]]]]]                                                                                     (5)
                       u c (C; j )Af 9( f 21 ( y /A))
4                                     A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9

    Trade-wise, price-making firms face world demand for their products so that Eq. (4) implies

                    S D
                     pt ( j)
      y t ( j) 5 Y W ]]
                   t   Pt
                                 2u
                                                                                                        (49)

where y t ( j) is the quantity of good j supplied by the firm to meet the world demand and
  W     H      F                                                                   H    n
Y t 5 Y t 1 Y t the index for all goods produced around the world, with Y t 5 e0 (( pt ( j)y t ( j)) /Pt ) dj
      F      n
and Y t 5 e0 ((´t p * ( j)y t ( j)) /Pt ) dj as corresponding production indices for home goods and foreign
                    t
goods.
   The goods markets are monopolistically competitive. A fraction g of the firms sets their prices
flexibly at p1t , supplying y 1t ; whereas the remaining 1 2 g of firms sets their prices one period in
advance (in period t 2 1) at p2t , supplying y 2t . In the former case, the price is marked up above the
marginal cost by a factor of m ( 5 u /(u 2 1) . 1) so that
      p1t
      ] 2 m s( y 1t , Ct ; j t , A t ) 5 0                                                              (6a)
      Pt

In the latter case, p2t will be chosen to maximize expected discounted profit

      Et21FS]]]D( p y 2 w h )G
              1
            11i          t 21
                                 2t    2t       t t


         5 E HS]]]DfY P p 2 w f                                                            J
                  1                             u   12u
                                                                     (Y tW P tu p 2u /A t )g
                                            W                   21
                11i
              t21
                                t21
                                            t   t   2t      t                     2t


where we have used the inverse demand function from Eq. (4) for y 2t and the inverse production
function for h t . One can show that p2t satisfies

      Et21   HS]]]DY
                 1
               11i       t 21
                                W
                                t      t    F
                                            p2t
                                     P u 21 ] 2 m s( y 2t , Ct ; j t , A t )
                                            Pt                                  GJ 5 0                  (6b)

Given p1t and p2t , the aggregate price index (1) can be rewritten as:

      Pt 5hn[g p 1t u 1 (1 2 g )p 2t u ] 1 (1 2 n)(´t p t* )12uj 1 / (12u )
                    12            12
                                                                                                        (19)

   In the extreme case where all prices are fully flexible (i.e. g 5 1), output will attain its natural
level, Y n , implicitly defined by
         t

                   pt
      ]]]]]]]]]] 5 m s(Y n , C n ; j t , A t )
      fnp t 1 (1 2 n)´t p t*12ug 1 / (12u )
          12u                               t t


                                 n                                                                        n
Among other things, Y t depends on the level of home consumption under flexible prices (C t ),
domestic and foreign prices ( pt and p t* ), as well as the exchange rate (´t ). For later purpose, we can
denote s(Y n , C n ; j t , A t ) as s n .
           t     t                    t
  In the absence of capital flows, C n 5 Y n so that the natural output level is defined by
                                          t   t

                   pt
      ]]]]]]]]]] 5 m s(Y n , Y n ; j t , A t )
      fnp t 1 (1 2 n)´t p t*12ug 1 / (12u )
          12u                               t t
A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9         5

When the economy is completely closed in terms of both commodity trade and capital flows (n 5 1
and C n 5 Y n ), the equation above further simplifies to
      t     t


      1 5 m s(Y tn , Y tn ; j t , A t )
In this last case, equilibrium output is completely independent of monetary policy.


3. The Phillips curve

   This section derives the expectations-augmented Phillips curve of the kind hypothesized by
Friedman (1968) and Phelps (1970) for both closed and economies [cf. Ball et al. (1988) and Roberts
(1995)].
   In order to obtain a tractable solution, we log-linearize the equilibrium conditions around the steady
state. We assume that b (1 1 r*) 5 1, which is necessary for the existence of a steady state. In
                                                                              ]
particular, we consider a deterministic steady state where j t 5 0 and A t 5A with ´t 5], p t* 5p*, and
                                                                                          ´      ]
     ]                       ] . (x 2x) /x as the proportional deviation of any variable x from its
                                        ] ]
                 ˆ
Ct 5C. Define x t 5 log(x t /x)      t                                                          t
deterministic steady state value ] We can then log-linearize Eq. (5) around the deterministic steady
                                   x.
state equilibrium to get
      ˆ ˆn                ˆn       21 ˆ   ˆn
      s t 2 s t 5 v (yt 2 Y t ) 1 s (Ct 2 C t )
                     ˆ                                                                               (59)
where
      v 5 vw 1 vp
                ] ]
           vhh (y /A)
      vw 5 ]]]
             vh f 9
                            ] ]
             f 0( f 21 (.))(y /A)
      vp 5 2 ]]]]]
              f 9( f 21 (.))f 9(.)
and
                ]
            u ccc
      s 5 2 ]]
             uc
Log-linearizing the two price-setting Eqs. (6a) and (6b) using Eq. (59), we obtain
                                                n
                                       ˆ
      log( p1t ) 5 log(Pt ) 1 v (y1t 2 Y t ) 1 s
                                 ˆ                      21    ˆ    ˆn
                                                             (Ct 2 C t )                           (6a9)
and
                                             ˆn       21 ˆ   ˆn
      log( p2t ) 5 Et 21flog(Pt ) 1 v (y2t 2 Y t ) 1 s (Ct 2 C t )g
                                       ˆ                                                           (6b9)

  From the definition of the aggregate price index (19), we can derive the following approximation
      log(Pt ) 5 n[g log( p1t ) 1 (1 2 g ) log( p2t )] 1 (1 2 n) log(´t p * )
                                                                          t                          (10)
6                            A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9

  Define the inflation rate pt 5 ln(Pt /Pt21 ) so that pt 2 Et 21 (pt ) 5 log(Pt ) 2 Et 21 log(Pt ), and the real
exchange rate as e t ; ´t P t* /Pt . We show in Appendix A how these price relations can be combined to
obtain the open-economy Phillips curve as follows:

                         g         nv
                      S
     pt 2 Et 21 (pt ) 5 ]]
                        12g DHS]]]D(Yˆ 2 Yˆ )
                                 1 1 uv
                                                   H
                                                   t
                                                                   n
                                                                   t



                       1F]]]G(Y 2 Y ) 1S]]]D(C 2 C )J
                                                                       21
                         (1 2 n)v ˆ       F s      n                                             n
                                        ˆ         ˆ    ˆ
                          1 1 uv          t1 1 uv  t                                  t          t


                       1S]]DHS]]D log(e ) 2 E [log(e )]J
                         12n         1
                                                                                                           (7)
                           n       12g                     t           t21                t




3.1. Perfect capital mobility

  When capital is perfectly mobile, consumption smoothing can be achieved and, given the
                                                                                          ˆ        ˆn
assumption that b (1 1 r*) 5 1, consumption will be trendless (see Eq. (3)). As a result, Ct 5 0 5 C t .
The Phillips curve therefore simplifies to

                         g         nv
                      S
     pt 2 Et 21 (pt ) 5 ]]
                        12g DHS]]]D(Yˆ 2 Yˆ )
                                 1 1 uv
                                                   H
                                                   t
                                                                   n
                                                                   t



                       1F]]]G(Y 2 Y )J
                         (1 2 n)v ˆ       F        n
                                        ˆ
                          1 1 uv          t        t


                       1S]]DHS]]D log (e ) 2 E                                                J
                         12n         1
                                                                                  [log (e t )]            (79)
                           n       12g                         t           t 21




3.2. Closing the capital account

  In the absence of capital flows, consumption smoothing can no longer be achieved and consumption
                                         ˆ    ˆH      ˆn ˆn
will fluctuate with domestic output (i.e. Ct 5 Y t and C t 5 Y t ). As a result, the Phillips curve assumes
the form


                      S DHS]]]D(Yˆ 2 Yˆ )
                                              21
                         g      nv 1 s                     H           n
     pt 2 Et 21 (pt ) 5 ]]
                        12g      1 1 uv                    t           t



                      1F]]]]G(Y 2 Y )J
                                     21
                        (1 2 n)s              F        n
                                      ˆ ˆ
                          1 1 uv              t        t


                      1S]]DHS]]D log(e ) 2 E [log(e )]J
                        12n         1
                                                                                                          (70)
                          n       12g                      t           t21                t




3.3. Closed economy

  If we further close the trade account, the economy will be self-sufficient and n 5 1. In this case, the
Phillips curve will take an even simpler form
A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9                                   7



                         S DS]]]D(Yˆ
                                               21
                          g  v 1s                      H
                                                            ˆ n
      pt 2 Et 21 (pt ) 5 ]]                                2Yt )                                                       (7-)
                         12g  1 1 uv                   t


which is exactly identical to Eq. (1.23) in Woodford (2000).

3.4. A comparison

   The difference in the output-inflation tradeoff coefficients between (79) and (70) lies in gs 21 /(1 2
g )(1 1 uv ), which captures the sensitivity of inflation to consumption spending. This term will
disappear in the presence of consumption smoothing, as will be achieved under perfect capital
mobility. The difference in the same coefficients between (70) and (7-) is g (n 2 1)v /(1 2 g )(1 1 uv ),
where n represents the fraction of world consumption that is produced domestically in the case of
trade openness whereas 1 stands for the same fraction (i.e. 100%) in the case of a closed economy.
Therefore, successive opening of the economy will flatten the Phillips curve.1


4. Short-run aggregate supply

   As a corollary to our analysis of the output-inflation tradeoff, we can also examine how exogenous
shocks to nominal GDP, defined as n[g p1 t y 1t 1 (1 2 g )p2t y 2t ] 5 P tH Y tH ; Q t , would affect the relative
responses of domestic output and producer prices. From the Phillips curve Eq. (7), we can show that
the sensitivity of log(Y H ) 2 log(Y n ) with respect to innovations in the exogenous process, viz.,
                             t          t
log(Q t ) 2 Et21 [log(Q t )], in the case of perfect capital mobility is
                                        1
      output-elasticity open 5 ]]]]]]]
                                     g     v
                                      S
                               1 1 ]] ]]]
                                   1 2 g 1 1 uv DS           D
while the sensitivity of log(P H ) 2 Et21 log(P tH ) is
                               t

                                     g      v
                                  S]]DS]]]D
                                   1 2 g 1 1 uv
      price-elasticity open   5 ]]]]]]]g      v
                                1 1S]]DS]]]D
                                     1 2 g 1 1 uv
   Similarly, the sensitivity parameters in the case of a closed economy are given by
                                         1
      output-elasticity closed 5 ]]]]]]]]
                                      g
                                     12gS
                                 1 1 ]] ]]]      DS
                                           v 1 s 21
                                            1 1 uv
                                                                  D
and

  1
    Obviously, our conclusion here is valid only if the parameters involved in the various versions of the Phillips curve are
stable and invariant to changes in trade and capital mobility regimes. The same condition applies to our results in the next
section.
8                               A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9


                                   g
                                    S
                                  ]] ]]]
                                  12g     DS
                                       v 1 s 21
                                        1 1 uv
                                                          D
      price-elasticity closed 5 ]]]]]]]]
                                11
                                     g
                                        S DS
                                   ]] ]]]
                                   12g
                                         v 1 s 21
                                          1 1 uv
                                                              D
   As discussed in Woodford (2000), these sensitivity parameters are related to the degree of strategic
complementarity among price setters. In turn, the latter depends on the organization of markets. For
instance, strategic substitutability (complementarity) will prevail if all factor prices are (cannot be)
instantaneously equalized across suppliers of different goods, the case of common (segmented) factor
markets. In our case, we show another example where the organization of the world capital market
matters — in particular, the integration or not of the domestic capital market into the world market.
Consumption smoothing, which comes with the opening of the capital market, will increase the degree
of strategic complementarity, thus rendering prices more sticky and magnifying output responses.


Appendix A

    Let us start with the two price-setting equations:
                                       ˆn       21 ˆ   ˆn
      log( p1t ) 5 log(Pt ) 1 v (y1t 2 Y t ) 1 s (Ct 2 C t )
                                 ˆ                                                               (A.1a)

and
                                             ˆn       21 ˆ   ˆn
      log( p2t ) 5 Et 21flog(Pt ) 1 v (y2t 2 Y t ) 1 s (Ct 2 C t )g
                                       ˆ                                                         (A.1b)
                                                                                                  W
    Log-linearizing the demand functions facing the firm (Eq. 4) (where we can replace c t and C t by
y t and Y tW , respectively), we get

       ˆ      ˆW
       y jt 5 Y t 2 u [log( pjt ) 2 log(Pt )], j 5 1,2                                            (A.2)

Substituting (A.2) into (A.1a) and (A.1b) and rearranging terms, we have

                               Sv
                              1 1 uv
                                     ˆW ˆn  D            1
                                                      1 1 uv
                                                             ˆ  ˆnS
      log( p1t ) 5 log(Pt ) 1 ]]] (Y t 2 Y t ) 1 s 21 ]]] (Ct 2 C t )     D                     (A.1a9)

and

                        F             v
                                        S
                                    1 1 uv
                                           ˆW ˆnD              1
                                                            1 1 uv
                                                                   ˆ  S
                                                                      ˆn
      log( p2t ) 5 Et 21 log(Pt ) 1 ]]] (Y t 2 Y t ) 1 s 21 ]]] (Ct 2 C t )     D          G    (A.1b9)

Together, (A.1a9) and (A.1b9) imply that

      log( p2t ) 5 Et 21 [log( p1t )]                                                             (A.3)

    From the aggregate price index Eq. (19), we have an approximate relation of the following kind
      log(Pt ) 5 n[g log( p1t ) 1 (1 2 g ) log( p2t )] 1 (1 2 n) log(´t p * )
                                                                          t                       (A.4)
A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9                               9

From this and (A.3), the unanticipated rate of inflation is given by
      log(Pt ) 2 Et 21flog(Pt )g 5 ng [log( p1t ) 2 log( p2t )]
                                   1 (1 2 n)hlog(´t p * ) 2 Et 21flog(´t p t* )gj
                                                      t                                                         (A.49)
(A.4) also implies that

                  F    1
                               G
      log( p2t ) 5 ]]] [log(Pt ) 2 ng log( p1t ) 2 (1 2 n) log(´t p * )]
                   n(1 2 g )                                        t


Substituting this into (A.49) and defining the real exchange rate as e t ; ´t P * /Pt , we have
                                                                               t

                                   g
                                   S       D
      log(Pt ) 2 Et 21 log(Pt ) 5 ]] [log( p1t ) 2 log(Pt )]
                                  12g
                                   12n
                                 1 ]]
                                     n
                                       S      1
                                               DHS        D
                                           ]] log(e t ) 2 Et21 [log(e t )]
                                           12g                                         J
Replacing log( p1t ) in the above expression by (A.1a9) yields an open-economy Phillips curve of the
form
                                   g
                                   S
      log(Pt ) 2 Et 21 log(Pt ) 5 ]]
                                  12g    DFS D
                                         v    ˆt    ˆt        s 21
                                       ]]] (Y W 2 Y n ) 1 ]]] (Ct 2 C n )
                                       1 1 uv               1 1 uv
                                                                         ˆ S
                                                                           ˆt        D            G
                                   12n
                                 1 ]]
                                     n
                                       S DHS D
                                           1
                                         ]] log(e t ) 2 Et21 [log(e t )]
                                         12g                                          J
                                                   ˆW     ˆH           ˆF
Eq. (7) in the text can be obtained by noting that Y t 5 nY t 1 (1 2 n)Y t .


References

Ball, L., Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D., 1988. The new Keynesian economics and the output-inflation tradeoff. Brookings Papers
   on Economic Activity 19, 1–65.
Blanchard, O., Kiyotaki, N., 1987. Monopolistic competition and the effects of aggregate demand. American Economic
   Review 77, 647–666.
Dixit, A., Stiglitz, J.E., 1977. Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review 67,
   297–308.
Friedman, M., 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58, 1–17.
Lane, P.R., 2001. The new open economy macroeconomics: a survey. Journal of International Economics 54, 235–266.
Loungani, P., Razin, A., Yuen, C.-W., 2001. Capital mobility and the output-inflation tradeoff. Journal of Development
   Economics 64, 255–274.
Obstfeld, M., Rogoff, K., 1996. Foundations of International Macroeconomics. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, Chapter 10.
Phelps, E.S., 1970. Microeconomic Foundations of Employment Theory. Norton, New York.
Roberts, J.M., 1995. New Keynesian economics and the Phillips curve. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, 975–984.
Woodford, M., 2000. Optimizing models with nominal rigidities, Chapter 3 of Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory
   of Monetary Policy, unpublished manuscript, Princeton University.

Más contenido relacionado

Similar a Elett02

Advanced macroeconomics, 4th edition. Romer. Chapter12.12.1. T.docx
Advanced macroeconomics, 4th edition. Romer. Chapter12.12.1. T.docxAdvanced macroeconomics, 4th edition. Romer. Chapter12.12.1. T.docx
Advanced macroeconomics, 4th edition. Romer. Chapter12.12.1. T.docx
galerussel59292
 
Homework 51)a) the IS curve ln Yt= ln Y(t+1) – (1Ɵ)rtso th.docx
Homework 51)a) the IS curve ln Yt= ln Y(t+1) – (1Ɵ)rtso th.docxHomework 51)a) the IS curve ln Yt= ln Y(t+1) – (1Ɵ)rtso th.docx
Homework 51)a) the IS curve ln Yt= ln Y(t+1) – (1Ɵ)rtso th.docx
adampcarr67227
 
THE IMPORTANCE OF INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE IN THE PROCESS OF AGGLOMERATION...
THE IMPORTANCE OF INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE IN THE PROCESS OF AGGLOMERATION...THE IMPORTANCE OF INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE IN THE PROCESS OF AGGLOMERATION...
THE IMPORTANCE OF INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE IN THE PROCESS OF AGGLOMERATION...
Vítor João Pereira Domingues Martinho
 
Interest rate derivatives
Interest rate derivativesInterest rate derivatives
Interest rate derivatives
Springer
 

Similar a Elett02 (20)

Solow Growth Model
Solow Growth ModelSolow Growth Model
Solow Growth Model
 
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHYA NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
 
A LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY FOR
A LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY FORA LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY FOR
A LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY FOR
 
WHAT SAID THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY ABOUT
WHAT SAID THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY ABOUTWHAT SAID THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY ABOUT
WHAT SAID THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY ABOUT
 
diff equation
diff equationdiff equation
diff equation
 
13.30 o2 v bubanja
13.30 o2 v bubanja13.30 o2 v bubanja
13.30 o2 v bubanja
 
Advanced macroeconomics, 4th edition. Romer. Chapter12.12.1. T.docx
Advanced macroeconomics, 4th edition. Romer. Chapter12.12.1. T.docxAdvanced macroeconomics, 4th edition. Romer. Chapter12.12.1. T.docx
Advanced macroeconomics, 4th edition. Romer. Chapter12.12.1. T.docx
 
Homework 51)a) the IS curve ln Yt= ln Y(t+1) – (1Ɵ)rtso th.docx
Homework 51)a) the IS curve ln Yt= ln Y(t+1) – (1Ɵ)rtso th.docxHomework 51)a) the IS curve ln Yt= ln Y(t+1) – (1Ɵ)rtso th.docx
Homework 51)a) the IS curve ln Yt= ln Y(t+1) – (1Ɵ)rtso th.docx
 
WHAT SAID THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY ABOUT
WHAT SAID THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY ABOUTWHAT SAID THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY ABOUT
WHAT SAID THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY ABOUT
 
THE IMPORTANCE OF INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE IN THE PROCESS OF AGGLOMERATION...
THE IMPORTANCE OF INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE IN THE PROCESS OF AGGLOMERATION...THE IMPORTANCE OF INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE IN THE PROCESS OF AGGLOMERATION...
THE IMPORTANCE OF INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE IN THE PROCESS OF AGGLOMERATION...
 
Insiders modeling london-2006
Insiders modeling london-2006Insiders modeling london-2006
Insiders modeling london-2006
 
Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital Presentation Sample
Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital Presentation SampleMacroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital Presentation Sample
Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital Presentation Sample
 
F0543645
F0543645F0543645
F0543645
 
Non-tradable Goods, Factor Markets Frictions, and International Capital Flows
Non-tradable Goods, Factor Markets Frictions, and International Capital FlowsNon-tradable Goods, Factor Markets Frictions, and International Capital Flows
Non-tradable Goods, Factor Markets Frictions, and International Capital Flows
 
Non-tradable Goods, Factor Markets Frictions, and International Capital Flows
Non-tradable Goods, Factor Markets Frictions, and International Capital FlowsNon-tradable Goods, Factor Markets Frictions, and International Capital Flows
Non-tradable Goods, Factor Markets Frictions, and International Capital Flows
 
Interest rate derivatives
Interest rate derivativesInterest rate derivatives
Interest rate derivatives
 
Modeling
ModelingModeling
Modeling
 
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHYA NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
 
A05220108
A05220108A05220108
A05220108
 
Cash Settled Interest Rate Swap Futures
Cash Settled Interest Rate Swap FuturesCash Settled Interest Rate Swap Futures
Cash Settled Interest Rate Swap Futures
 

Último

BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
SoniaTolstoy
 
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactBeyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
PECB
 
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
fonyou31
 
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
QucHHunhnh
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
heathfieldcps1
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Krashi Coaching
 
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfActivity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
ciinovamais
 

Último (20)

BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
 
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
 
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
 
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactBeyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
 
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptxINDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
 
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SDMeasures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
 
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The BasicsIntroduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
 
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpin
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpinStudent login on Anyboli platform.helpin
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpin
 
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
 
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
 
BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...
BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...
BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
 
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfArihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
 
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdfClass 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
 
social pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajan
social pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajansocial pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajan
social pharmacy d-pharm 1st year by Pragati K. Mahajan
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
 
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfActivity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
 

Elett02

  • 1. Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1–9 www.elsevier.com / locate / econbase The ‘New Keynesian’ Phillips curve: closed economy versus open economy Assaf Razin a , Chi-Wa Yuen b , * a Tel Aviv University, Cornell University, NBER, CEPR, and CES-Ifo, Tel Aviv, Israel b School of Economics and Finance, University of Hong Kong, Pokfulam Road, Hong Kong, China Received 27 May 2001; accepted 6 June 2001 Abstract The paper extends Woodford’s [Optimizing models with nominal rigidities, Chapter 3 of Interest and prices: foundations of a theory of monetary policy, Princeton University, 2000; unpublished manuscript] analysis of the closed economy Phillips curve to an open economy with both commodity trade and capital mobility. We show that consumption smoothing, which comes with the opening of the capital market, raises the degree of strategic complementarity among monopolistically competitive suppliers, thus rendering prices more sticky and magnifying output responses to nominal GDP shocks. © 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Phillips curve; New Keynesian; Trade; Capital mobility JEL classification: E12; F41 1. Introduction In this paper, we examine how open market policies would interact with the degree of price rigidity in the domestic economy to affect the output-inflation tradeoffs as well as the volatilities of output and inflation in response to nominal shocks. The analysis will be conducted in an optimization-based ‘New Keynesian’ framework a la Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987). In the discussion, we extend to an open-trade-account and open-capital-account economy the succinct exposition of Woodford (2000) conducted in the context of a closed economy. [For a useful survey of the new open economy macroeconomic approach we adopt for our analysis in this paper, see Lane (2001).] Why is such extension potentially useful? Empirically, Loungani et al. (2001) have found that countries with greater restrictions on capital mobility tend to have steeper Phillips curves. Evidently, * Corresponding author. Tel.: 1852-2859-1051; fax: 1852-2548-1152. E-mail address: cwyuen@econ.khu.hk (C.-W. Yuen). 0165-1765 / 02 / $ – see front matter © 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S0165-1765( 01 )00588-2
  • 2. 2 A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9 the degree of price stickiness is related to the organization of markets — for instance, whether the labor market is common or segmented. Similarly, the degree of price stickiness can be affected by the openness of the economy in both commodity trade and capital flows. 2. The analytical framework Consider a small open economy with a representative household that is endowed with a continuum of goods-specific skills — uniformly distributed on the unit interval [0, n] — to be supplied to a differentiated product industry. As a consumer, the representative household has access to consump- tion of both domestic goods (distributed on [0, n]) and foreign goods (distributed on (n, 1]). The household seeks to maximize a discounted sum of expected utilities: n O b [u(C , M /P ; j ) 2E v(h ( j); j ) dj] ` t E0 t t t t t t t 50 0 where b is the subjective discount factor, C is the Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) index of household consumption, P the Dixit–Stiglitz price index, M /P the demand for real balances, j a preference shock, and h( j) the supply of type-j labor to the production of good of variety j. Like Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996), we define the consumption index and its corresponding price index, respectively, as n 1 u / (u 21 ) Ct 5 3E0 ( t E c t ( j) u 21 ) / u dj 1 c * ( j)(u 21 ) / u dj n 4 and n 1 1 / (12u ) Pt 5 5E0 pt ( j) 12u tE dj 1 [´t p * ( j)] n 12u dj 6 (1) where c( j) represents domestic consumption of the jth domestically produced good, c*( j) domestic consumption of the jth foreign-produced good, p( j) the domestic-currency price of c( j), p*( j) the foreign-currency price of c*( j), ´ the nominal exchange rate (domestic-currency price of foreign currency), u . 1 the elasticity of substitution among the different goods, and n the fraction of goods that are produced domestically. In nominal terms, the budget constraint facing the household is given by: n 1 E p ( j)c ( j) dj 1 ´ E p*( j)c*( j) dj 1S]]DM 1 B 1 ´ B * t t t n i 11i t t t t t t t t 0 n n * * 5 Mt21 1 (1 1 i t 21 )Bt 21 1 ft21,t (1 1 i t21 )B t21 1 w t ( j)h t ( j) dj 1 Pt ( j) dj E E 0 0 where B is the domestic-currency value of domestic borrowing, B* the foreign-currency value of
  • 3. A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9 3 foreign borrowing, ft21,t the forward exchange rate for foreign currencies purchased / sold at time t 2 1 for delivery at time t, i and i* the domestic and foreign interest rates, w( j) the wage rate per unit labor of type j, and P ( j) profit income from firms of type j. With perfect capital mobility, covered interest parity prevails: 1 1 i t 5 (1 1 i t* ) ]] S D ft,t11 ´t [cf. first-order conditions of the household with respect to B and B*.] From this point on, we shall focus on the relation between aggregate supply of goods and consumption smoothing made possible by international capital mobility. For this purpose, we would not be concerned about the details of aggregate demand (including the demand for money), international commodity trade, and the determination of the exchange rate. For simplicity, consumer utility is assumed to be separable between consumption and real money balances. For our purpose, the relevant utility-maximizing conditions include an intratemporal condition for the choice of labor supply of type j: vh (h t ( j); j t ) w t ( j) ]]]] 5 ]] (2) u c (Ct ; j t ) Pt and an intertemporal condition for the consumption-saving choice: u c (Ct ; j t ) ]]]]] 5 b (1 1 r*) (3) u c (Ct11 ; j t11 ) where r* is the world real rate of interest, assumed for simplicity to be time-invariant. This latter equality is a consequence of the covered interest parity and the Fisher equation. As in the Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) model, demand for good j satisfies S D pt ( j) c t ( j) 5 Ct ]] Pt 2u (4) The production function assumes the form y t ( j) 5 A t f(h t ( j)) 21 where A is a random productivity shock. The variable cost of supplying y t ( j) is w t ( j)f ( y t ( j) /A t ), which implies a (real) marginal cost of w t ( j) s t ( j) 5 ]]]]]]] Pt A t f 9( f 21 ( y t ( j) /A t )) Using Eq. (2), we can replace the real wage above by the marginal rate of substitution. Imposing symmetry across firms (so that we can drop the index j), the above equation can be rewritten as vh ( f 21 ( y /A); j ) s( y, C; j , A) 5 ]]]]]]] (5) u c (C; j )Af 9( f 21 ( y /A))
  • 4. 4 A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9 Trade-wise, price-making firms face world demand for their products so that Eq. (4) implies S D pt ( j) y t ( j) 5 Y W ]] t Pt 2u (49) where y t ( j) is the quantity of good j supplied by the firm to meet the world demand and W H F H n Y t 5 Y t 1 Y t the index for all goods produced around the world, with Y t 5 e0 (( pt ( j)y t ( j)) /Pt ) dj F n and Y t 5 e0 ((´t p * ( j)y t ( j)) /Pt ) dj as corresponding production indices for home goods and foreign t goods. The goods markets are monopolistically competitive. A fraction g of the firms sets their prices flexibly at p1t , supplying y 1t ; whereas the remaining 1 2 g of firms sets their prices one period in advance (in period t 2 1) at p2t , supplying y 2t . In the former case, the price is marked up above the marginal cost by a factor of m ( 5 u /(u 2 1) . 1) so that p1t ] 2 m s( y 1t , Ct ; j t , A t ) 5 0 (6a) Pt In the latter case, p2t will be chosen to maximize expected discounted profit Et21FS]]]D( p y 2 w h )G 1 11i t 21 2t 2t t t 5 E HS]]]DfY P p 2 w f J 1 u 12u (Y tW P tu p 2u /A t )g W 21 11i t21 t21 t t 2t t 2t where we have used the inverse demand function from Eq. (4) for y 2t and the inverse production function for h t . One can show that p2t satisfies Et21 HS]]]DY 1 11i t 21 W t t F p2t P u 21 ] 2 m s( y 2t , Ct ; j t , A t ) Pt GJ 5 0 (6b) Given p1t and p2t , the aggregate price index (1) can be rewritten as: Pt 5hn[g p 1t u 1 (1 2 g )p 2t u ] 1 (1 2 n)(´t p t* )12uj 1 / (12u ) 12 12 (19) In the extreme case where all prices are fully flexible (i.e. g 5 1), output will attain its natural level, Y n , implicitly defined by t pt ]]]]]]]]]] 5 m s(Y n , C n ; j t , A t ) fnp t 1 (1 2 n)´t p t*12ug 1 / (12u ) 12u t t n n Among other things, Y t depends on the level of home consumption under flexible prices (C t ), domestic and foreign prices ( pt and p t* ), as well as the exchange rate (´t ). For later purpose, we can denote s(Y n , C n ; j t , A t ) as s n . t t t In the absence of capital flows, C n 5 Y n so that the natural output level is defined by t t pt ]]]]]]]]]] 5 m s(Y n , Y n ; j t , A t ) fnp t 1 (1 2 n)´t p t*12ug 1 / (12u ) 12u t t
  • 5. A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9 5 When the economy is completely closed in terms of both commodity trade and capital flows (n 5 1 and C n 5 Y n ), the equation above further simplifies to t t 1 5 m s(Y tn , Y tn ; j t , A t ) In this last case, equilibrium output is completely independent of monetary policy. 3. The Phillips curve This section derives the expectations-augmented Phillips curve of the kind hypothesized by Friedman (1968) and Phelps (1970) for both closed and economies [cf. Ball et al. (1988) and Roberts (1995)]. In order to obtain a tractable solution, we log-linearize the equilibrium conditions around the steady state. We assume that b (1 1 r*) 5 1, which is necessary for the existence of a steady state. In ] particular, we consider a deterministic steady state where j t 5 0 and A t 5A with ´t 5], p t* 5p*, and ´ ] ] ] . (x 2x) /x as the proportional deviation of any variable x from its ] ] ˆ Ct 5C. Define x t 5 log(x t /x) t t deterministic steady state value ] We can then log-linearize Eq. (5) around the deterministic steady x. state equilibrium to get ˆ ˆn ˆn 21 ˆ ˆn s t 2 s t 5 v (yt 2 Y t ) 1 s (Ct 2 C t ) ˆ (59) where v 5 vw 1 vp ] ] vhh (y /A) vw 5 ]]] vh f 9 ] ] f 0( f 21 (.))(y /A) vp 5 2 ]]]]] f 9( f 21 (.))f 9(.) and ] u ccc s 5 2 ]] uc Log-linearizing the two price-setting Eqs. (6a) and (6b) using Eq. (59), we obtain n ˆ log( p1t ) 5 log(Pt ) 1 v (y1t 2 Y t ) 1 s ˆ 21 ˆ ˆn (Ct 2 C t ) (6a9) and ˆn 21 ˆ ˆn log( p2t ) 5 Et 21flog(Pt ) 1 v (y2t 2 Y t ) 1 s (Ct 2 C t )g ˆ (6b9) From the definition of the aggregate price index (19), we can derive the following approximation log(Pt ) 5 n[g log( p1t ) 1 (1 2 g ) log( p2t )] 1 (1 2 n) log(´t p * ) t (10)
  • 6. 6 A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9 Define the inflation rate pt 5 ln(Pt /Pt21 ) so that pt 2 Et 21 (pt ) 5 log(Pt ) 2 Et 21 log(Pt ), and the real exchange rate as e t ; ´t P t* /Pt . We show in Appendix A how these price relations can be combined to obtain the open-economy Phillips curve as follows: g nv S pt 2 Et 21 (pt ) 5 ]] 12g DHS]]]D(Yˆ 2 Yˆ ) 1 1 uv H t n t 1F]]]G(Y 2 Y ) 1S]]]D(C 2 C )J 21 (1 2 n)v ˆ F s n n ˆ ˆ ˆ 1 1 uv t1 1 uv t t t 1S]]DHS]]D log(e ) 2 E [log(e )]J 12n 1 (7) n 12g t t21 t 3.1. Perfect capital mobility When capital is perfectly mobile, consumption smoothing can be achieved and, given the ˆ ˆn assumption that b (1 1 r*) 5 1, consumption will be trendless (see Eq. (3)). As a result, Ct 5 0 5 C t . The Phillips curve therefore simplifies to g nv S pt 2 Et 21 (pt ) 5 ]] 12g DHS]]]D(Yˆ 2 Yˆ ) 1 1 uv H t n t 1F]]]G(Y 2 Y )J (1 2 n)v ˆ F n ˆ 1 1 uv t t 1S]]DHS]]D log (e ) 2 E J 12n 1 [log (e t )] (79) n 12g t t 21 3.2. Closing the capital account In the absence of capital flows, consumption smoothing can no longer be achieved and consumption ˆ ˆH ˆn ˆn will fluctuate with domestic output (i.e. Ct 5 Y t and C t 5 Y t ). As a result, the Phillips curve assumes the form S DHS]]]D(Yˆ 2 Yˆ ) 21 g nv 1 s H n pt 2 Et 21 (pt ) 5 ]] 12g 1 1 uv t t 1F]]]]G(Y 2 Y )J 21 (1 2 n)s F n ˆ ˆ 1 1 uv t t 1S]]DHS]]D log(e ) 2 E [log(e )]J 12n 1 (70) n 12g t t21 t 3.3. Closed economy If we further close the trade account, the economy will be self-sufficient and n 5 1. In this case, the Phillips curve will take an even simpler form
  • 7. A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9 7 S DS]]]D(Yˆ 21 g v 1s H ˆ n pt 2 Et 21 (pt ) 5 ]] 2Yt ) (7-) 12g 1 1 uv t which is exactly identical to Eq. (1.23) in Woodford (2000). 3.4. A comparison The difference in the output-inflation tradeoff coefficients between (79) and (70) lies in gs 21 /(1 2 g )(1 1 uv ), which captures the sensitivity of inflation to consumption spending. This term will disappear in the presence of consumption smoothing, as will be achieved under perfect capital mobility. The difference in the same coefficients between (70) and (7-) is g (n 2 1)v /(1 2 g )(1 1 uv ), where n represents the fraction of world consumption that is produced domestically in the case of trade openness whereas 1 stands for the same fraction (i.e. 100%) in the case of a closed economy. Therefore, successive opening of the economy will flatten the Phillips curve.1 4. Short-run aggregate supply As a corollary to our analysis of the output-inflation tradeoff, we can also examine how exogenous shocks to nominal GDP, defined as n[g p1 t y 1t 1 (1 2 g )p2t y 2t ] 5 P tH Y tH ; Q t , would affect the relative responses of domestic output and producer prices. From the Phillips curve Eq. (7), we can show that the sensitivity of log(Y H ) 2 log(Y n ) with respect to innovations in the exogenous process, viz., t t log(Q t ) 2 Et21 [log(Q t )], in the case of perfect capital mobility is 1 output-elasticity open 5 ]]]]]]] g v S 1 1 ]] ]]] 1 2 g 1 1 uv DS D while the sensitivity of log(P H ) 2 Et21 log(P tH ) is t g v S]]DS]]]D 1 2 g 1 1 uv price-elasticity open 5 ]]]]]]]g v 1 1S]]DS]]]D 1 2 g 1 1 uv Similarly, the sensitivity parameters in the case of a closed economy are given by 1 output-elasticity closed 5 ]]]]]]]] g 12gS 1 1 ]] ]]] DS v 1 s 21 1 1 uv D and 1 Obviously, our conclusion here is valid only if the parameters involved in the various versions of the Phillips curve are stable and invariant to changes in trade and capital mobility regimes. The same condition applies to our results in the next section.
  • 8. 8 A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9 g S ]] ]]] 12g DS v 1 s 21 1 1 uv D price-elasticity closed 5 ]]]]]]]] 11 g S DS ]] ]]] 12g v 1 s 21 1 1 uv D As discussed in Woodford (2000), these sensitivity parameters are related to the degree of strategic complementarity among price setters. In turn, the latter depends on the organization of markets. For instance, strategic substitutability (complementarity) will prevail if all factor prices are (cannot be) instantaneously equalized across suppliers of different goods, the case of common (segmented) factor markets. In our case, we show another example where the organization of the world capital market matters — in particular, the integration or not of the domestic capital market into the world market. Consumption smoothing, which comes with the opening of the capital market, will increase the degree of strategic complementarity, thus rendering prices more sticky and magnifying output responses. Appendix A Let us start with the two price-setting equations: ˆn 21 ˆ ˆn log( p1t ) 5 log(Pt ) 1 v (y1t 2 Y t ) 1 s (Ct 2 C t ) ˆ (A.1a) and ˆn 21 ˆ ˆn log( p2t ) 5 Et 21flog(Pt ) 1 v (y2t 2 Y t ) 1 s (Ct 2 C t )g ˆ (A.1b) W Log-linearizing the demand functions facing the firm (Eq. 4) (where we can replace c t and C t by y t and Y tW , respectively), we get ˆ ˆW y jt 5 Y t 2 u [log( pjt ) 2 log(Pt )], j 5 1,2 (A.2) Substituting (A.2) into (A.1a) and (A.1b) and rearranging terms, we have Sv 1 1 uv ˆW ˆn D 1 1 1 uv ˆ ˆnS log( p1t ) 5 log(Pt ) 1 ]]] (Y t 2 Y t ) 1 s 21 ]]] (Ct 2 C t ) D (A.1a9) and F v S 1 1 uv ˆW ˆnD 1 1 1 uv ˆ S ˆn log( p2t ) 5 Et 21 log(Pt ) 1 ]]] (Y t 2 Y t ) 1 s 21 ]]] (Ct 2 C t ) D G (A.1b9) Together, (A.1a9) and (A.1b9) imply that log( p2t ) 5 Et 21 [log( p1t )] (A.3) From the aggregate price index Eq. (19), we have an approximate relation of the following kind log(Pt ) 5 n[g log( p1t ) 1 (1 2 g ) log( p2t )] 1 (1 2 n) log(´t p * ) t (A.4)
  • 9. A. Razin, C.-W. Yuen / Economics Letters 75 (2002) 1 – 9 9 From this and (A.3), the unanticipated rate of inflation is given by log(Pt ) 2 Et 21flog(Pt )g 5 ng [log( p1t ) 2 log( p2t )] 1 (1 2 n)hlog(´t p * ) 2 Et 21flog(´t p t* )gj t (A.49) (A.4) also implies that F 1 G log( p2t ) 5 ]]] [log(Pt ) 2 ng log( p1t ) 2 (1 2 n) log(´t p * )] n(1 2 g ) t Substituting this into (A.49) and defining the real exchange rate as e t ; ´t P * /Pt , we have t g S D log(Pt ) 2 Et 21 log(Pt ) 5 ]] [log( p1t ) 2 log(Pt )] 12g 12n 1 ]] n S 1 DHS D ]] log(e t ) 2 Et21 [log(e t )] 12g J Replacing log( p1t ) in the above expression by (A.1a9) yields an open-economy Phillips curve of the form g S log(Pt ) 2 Et 21 log(Pt ) 5 ]] 12g DFS D v ˆt ˆt s 21 ]]] (Y W 2 Y n ) 1 ]]] (Ct 2 C n ) 1 1 uv 1 1 uv ˆ S ˆt D G 12n 1 ]] n S DHS D 1 ]] log(e t ) 2 Et21 [log(e t )] 12g J ˆW ˆH ˆF Eq. (7) in the text can be obtained by noting that Y t 5 nY t 1 (1 2 n)Y t . References Ball, L., Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D., 1988. The new Keynesian economics and the output-inflation tradeoff. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 19, 1–65. Blanchard, O., Kiyotaki, N., 1987. Monopolistic competition and the effects of aggregate demand. American Economic Review 77, 647–666. Dixit, A., Stiglitz, J.E., 1977. Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review 67, 297–308. Friedman, M., 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58, 1–17. Lane, P.R., 2001. The new open economy macroeconomics: a survey. Journal of International Economics 54, 235–266. Loungani, P., Razin, A., Yuen, C.-W., 2001. Capital mobility and the output-inflation tradeoff. Journal of Development Economics 64, 255–274. Obstfeld, M., Rogoff, K., 1996. Foundations of International Macroeconomics. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, Chapter 10. Phelps, E.S., 1970. Microeconomic Foundations of Employment Theory. Norton, New York. Roberts, J.M., 1995. New Keynesian economics and the Phillips curve. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, 975–984. Woodford, M., 2000. Optimizing models with nominal rigidities, Chapter 3 of Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy, unpublished manuscript, Princeton University.